JAMES ORENSTEIN, Magistrate Judge.
The plaintiffs in this multi-district litigation — some acting on behalf of putative classes of millions of merchants, and others acting independently — have accused the corporate entities that operate the Visa and MasterCard payment card networks as well as several banks of violating federal and state antitrust laws. As a result of recent developments, both in this case and in the case law of this circuit, they now seek to amend their respective complaints in a number of ways. For the following reasons, I partially grant and partially deny the motions.
I assume the reader's familiarity with the factual and procedural history of this litigation, and in particular refer the reader to the detailed descriptions of the payment card industry set forth in the opinion of this court approving a class-wide settlement in —, and the opinion of the appellate court reversing that approval three years later. See In re Payment Card Interchange Fee & Merch. Disc. Antitrust Litig., 986 F.Supp.2d 207, 214-15 (E.D.N.Y. 2013) ("Interchange I"), rev'd, 827 F.3d 223 (2d Cir. 2016) ("Interchange II"), cert. denied, 137 S.Ct. 1374 (2017).
When a consumer uses a payment card to purchase goods or services from a merchant, the transaction is received by the merchant's acquiring bank, which in turn notifies that credit card's network provider (in this case Visa or MasterCard) of the intended purchase. The network reaches out to the cardholder's issuing bank, and assuming the needed funds are available, the issuing bank approves the transaction. The network then informs the acquiring bank that the transaction has been approved, and the issuing bank transfers the purchase price minus an interchange fee (set by the issuing bank) and a merchant discount fee (an amount retained by the acquiring bank).
Merchants that accept Visa or MasterCard cards are bound to the defendants' network rules. These rules include a default interchange fee that applies to every transaction on the network (unless the merchant and issuing bank enter into their own agreement); the Honor-All-Cards rule which requires merchants that choose to accept any of the Network Defendants' credit cards to accept all of them; and anti-steering rules that prevent merchants from charging different prices at the point of sale based on the shopper's form of payment (collectively, the "Network Rules").
On October 20, 2005, the Judicial Panel on Multidistrict Litigation consolidated fourteen actions asserting the antitrust claims described above and transferred them to this court for pretrial proceedings. Docket Entry ("DE") 1; DE 2. Since then, dozens more have been added, and there are currently over 90 cases associated with this action, some pleaded as class actions and some filed by plaintiffs suing only on behalf of themselves.
Following this court's appointment of interim co-lead class counsel, the Class Plaintiffs filed their First Consolidated Amended Class Complaint on April 24, 2006. DE 317 ("First Class Comp."). That pleading defined two putative classes: one seeking monetary damages and the other seeking equitable relief. Id. ¶ 97. The Class Plaintiffs asserted claims under Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1, 2, as well as state law claims, all predicated on a contention that the defendants' unlawful contracts, combinations, and conspiracies, harmed competition and caused merchants to pay supracompetitive prices in the market for network services. Id. ¶¶ 3-4, 213-347.
In defining the scope of the relevant market, the Class Plaintiffs relied on controlling case law arising from earlier litigation concerning the same networks' practices. See id. ¶¶ 198-212 (citing In re Visa Check/MasterMoney Antitrust Litig. ("Visa Check"), 2003 WL 1712568 (E.D.N.Y. Apr. 1, 2003); United States v. Visa ("Visa"), 163 F.Supp.2d 322, 335 (S.D.N.Y. 2001), aff'd, 344 F.3d 229 (2d Cir. 2003). As the circuit court had explained in Visa, and as the Class Plaintiffs alleged here, there exist two related but distinct markets relevant to the instant dispute. In the market for network services — the market in which the Class Plaintiffs alleged that the defendants had engaged in unlawful anticompetitive conduct — payment card networks are sellers that compete with one another to secure the business of the banks and merchants that purchase such services. In the separate market for general purpose payment cards, the sellers are the banks that issue the cards and the buyers are the consumers who obtain the cards and use them for purchases. See Visa, 344 F.3d at 238-39; First Class Comp. ¶¶ 198-212. More recently, however, the same appellate court has held that the relevant market for similar complaints by a nationwide class of merchants against another payment card network — American Express — is a single, two-sided market that encompasses the networks, the processing banks, the merchants who accept cards for payments, and the consumers who use those cards. See United States v. American Express, Co. ("AmEx"), 838 F.3d 179, 196-200 (2d Cir. 2016), petition for cert. filed, No. 16-1454 (U.S. June 6, 2017). That decision has been a significant factor in prompting the instant motions to amend.
On January 29, 2009, after filing further supplemental pleadings and litigating dismissal motions, the Class Plaintiffs filed their Second Consolidated Class Action Complaint, which, together with two supplemental complaints filed the same day, collectively comprise the Class Plaintiffs' currently operative pleading. See DE 1153 (the "Operative Class Complaint" or "Class Comp."); DE 1154 (the Second Supplemental Class Action Complaint); DE 1152 (the First Amended Supplemental Class Action Complaint).
On October 19, 2012, after extensive negotiations, the parties to the then-pending class claims executed a proposed settlement agreement. DE 1656. On November 27, 2012, the court preliminarily approved the proposed settlement, provisionally certified two classes (a class for damages claims, from which members could opt out, and a class for injunctive relief in which membership was mandatory), and enjoined all members of the provisionally certified settlement classes from litigating any claims covered by the settlement. DE 1745 (Order). On December 13, 2013, the court certified the two settlement classes and approved the proposed settlement over the objections of several named plaintiffs as well as several non-party class members. Interchange I, 986 F. Supp. 2d at 213, 217. Under the approved terms, the defendants were released from any claims arising from the Network Rules existing as of November 27, 2012, and the members of the certified classes received over seven billion dollars in damages and injunctive relief.
Following the court's preliminary approval of the proposed settlement, three groups of merchants that had not previously appeared as named parties — the Target, 7-Eleven, and Home Depot groups or, collectively, the "Direct Action Plaintiffs" — opted out of the settlement's damages class and filed their own complaints in other districts, all of which were ultimately transferred to this court and consolidated in the instant multidistrict litigation. See Target Corp., et al. v. Visa Inc., et al., 13-CV-5745 (MKB) (JO) ("Target"), DE 1 (complaint); id., DE 95 (transfer order); id., DE 107 (amended complaint) (the "Target Operative Complaint" or "Target Comp."); 7-Eleven, Inc., et al. v. Visa Inc., et al., 13-CV-5746 (MKB) (JO) ("7-Eleven"), DE 1 (complaint); id., DE 9 (transfer order); id., DE 80 (fourth amended complaint) (the "7-Eleven Operative Complaint" or "7-Eleven Comp."); The Home Depot, Inc., et al. v. Visa Inc., et al., 16-CV-5507 (MKB) (JO) ("Home Depot"), DE 1 (complaint) (the "Home Depot Operative Complaint" or "Home Depot Comp."); id., DE 34 (transfer order). All of the Direct Action Plaintiffs sought relief only for themselves; they did not seek to represent a putative class.
As relevant here, the operative pleadings of the three groups of Direct Action Plaintiffs assert claims under Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act and state antitrust laws. Specifically:
After the Direct Action Plaintiffs had filed their initial complaints, on June 30, 2016, the circuit court vacated this court's decision to certify the settlement classes and approve the proposed settlement. Interchange II, 827 F.3d 223 (2d Cir. 2016). The appellate court concluded that the Class Plaintiffs lacked adequate representation, in violation of the rule governing class actions and of their right to due process, and therefore remanded the litigation to this court for further proceedings.
On November 30, 2016, I appointed two groups of interim co-lead class counsel. One group was appointed to represent merchants seeking to certify a class pursuant to Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 23(b)(2) (the "Equitable Relief Class"). The second group represents those seeking to certify a class pursuant to Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 23(b)(3) (the "Damages Class"). DE 6754 (memorandum and order).
As discussed below, the ability of the Damages Class to file an updated pleading, as well as the Direct Action Plaintiffs' perceived need to further amend their complaints, has been affected by two recent circuit court decisions in other actions involving antitrust claims arising from interchange fees and network rules for merchants: AmEx and Salveson v. JP Morgan Chase & Co., 663 F. App'x 71, 75 (2d Cir. 2016), cert. denied, 137 S.Ct. 1826 (2017).
The AmEx decision, issued about three months after the opinion reversing the settlement in this case, affected the parties' understanding of the litigation risks attendant to their proposed definitions of the relevant market. As noted above, the initial complaints in this litigation relied on precedent such as Visa and Visa Check to assert claims that the defendants had harmed competition in a one-sided market for payment card network services — that is, a market in which merchants act solely as buyers of the products the networks sell. In AmEx, however, the circuit court rejected a district court's application of such a market definition because it failed to account for harm to the consumers who use payment cards for their purchases. See AmEx, 838 F.3d at 197; see also DE 7068 (transcript of oral argument dated Apr. 20, 2017) ("Tr.") at 44 (defendant JP Morgan Chase's counsel, opposing the motions to amend, describing the AmEx opinion as "the first time in a credit card case a court has expressly said it is a two-sided market").
Like the plaintiffs in this litigation, the AmEx plaintiffs challenged certain nondiscriminatory provisions ("NDPs") contained in American Express's regulations that prohibited merchants from discounting and steering at the point of sale. The appellate court in AmEx reasoned that the rules about which the merchant plaintiffs in Visa complained constituted horizontal restraints in a onesided market for network services, but that the NDPs constituted vertical restraints that affected competition in both the market for network services and the two-sided market for general purpose cards. AmEx, 838 F.3d at 197-98. The court, noting that the evidence in the record demonstrated "that the quality and output of credit cards across the entire industry continues to increase[,]" thus held that the plaintiffs in AmEx had failed to prove a "net harm to . . . both cardholders and merchants[.]" Id. at 206.
The Salveson case also turned on the role of payment card holders in the markets relevant to this litigation. In the Salveson complaint, originally filed in the Northern District of California on December 16, 2013, four individual plaintiffs acting on behalf of a putative class alleged that as consumers using payment cards for their purchases, they had directly paid to the defendant banks supracompetitive, price-fixed interchange fees. See Melvin Salveson, et al. v. JP Morgan Chase & Co., et al., 14-CV-3529 (MKB) (JO), DE 1. On June 4, 2014, the Judicial Panel on Multidistrict Litigation transferred the case to this court. Id., DE 61. On November 26, 2014, this court granted the Salveson defendants' motion to dismiss that action on the ground that the cardholder plaintiffs were, with respect to their payment of interchange fees, indirect purchasers of payment card network services who therefore lacked standing to complain of the antitrust violations that resulted in such fees. See id., DE 83 at 6 ("The markets for general purpose payment cards and for payment card network services are separate and distinct, and payment-card consumers are considered to participate only in the former.") (citing Visa, 344 F.3d at 239); see Illinois Brick Co. v. Illinois, 431 U.S. 720 (1977). On review of that decision, the same circuit court that had just weeks before issued the AmEx opinion affirmed the order of dismissal, explaining that cardholders like Salveson suffer no direct injury by paying interchange fees. See Salveson, 663 F. App'x at 75.
The various groups of plaintiffs now seek leave to amend their respective complaints in several ways for a number of reasons. See DE 6884 (fully-briefed 7-Eleven motion); DE 6881 (fullybriefed Target motion); DE 6890 (sealed version of Target's memorandum of law in support); DE 6887 (fully-briefed Home Depot motion); DE 6888 (sealed version of Home Depot's memorandum of law in support); DE 6880 (fully-briefed Damages Class motion).
At oral argument on April 20, 2016, see DE 6929 (minute entry), I discussed with the parties the effect of AmEx and the extent to which the parties' earlier pleadings had — or had not — asserted that the defendants had acted to harm competition in a two-sided market that included cardholders. I also asked the parties to address the effect on the analysis of the instant motions, if any, of the fact that the Salveson case, which was consolidated as part of the instant multidistrict litigation, had been resolved on the basis of the proposition that cardholders are not part of the relevant market for purposes of the claims being litigated here. See Tr. at 31-32, 56. Following oral argument, the parties submitted supplemental letters in support of their respective positions. See DE 6936 ("Damages Class Supp. Ltr."); DE 6937 ("Defs. Supp. Ltr."); DE 6939 ("Direct Action Plaintiffs' Supp. Ltr.").
A court should "freely" grant leave to amend a pleading in the absence of reasons to deny it such as "undue delay, bad faith or . . . futility[.]" Foman v. Davis, 371 U.S. 178, 182 (1962) (quoting Fed. R. Civ. P. 15(a)). "Mere delay, however, absent a showing of bad faith or undue prejudice, does not provide a basis for a district court to deny the right to amend." State Teachers Ret. Bd. v. Fluor Corp., 654 F.2d 843, 856 (2d Cir. 1981). The party seeking leave to amend bears the burden of satisfactorily explaining any delay. Franconero v. UMG Recordings, Inc., 542 F. App'x 14, 18 (2d Cir. 2013). Once it does so, the opposing party has to show more in terms of prejudice. Evans v. Syracuse City Sch. Dist., 704 F.2d 44, 46-47 (2d Cir. 1983). In determining prejudice, courts consider whether the proposed amendment would impose significant new discovery and trial preparation burdens on the opponent, whether it would significantly delay the dispute's resolution, and the movant's ability to bring a timely action in another forum. See Block v. First Blood Assocs., 988 F.2d 344, 350 (2d Cir. 1993). The decision to grant or deny a motion to amend rests within the sound discretion of the district court. Zahra v. Town of Southold, 48 F.3d 674, 685 (2d Cir. 1995).
"An amendment to a pleading relates back to the date of the original pleading when . . . the amendment asserts a claim or defense that arose out of the conduct, transaction, or occurrence set out — or attempted to be set out — in the original pleading." Fed. R. Civ. P. 15(c)(1)(B). For a newlyadded claim to relate back under Rule 15(c), the "basic claim must have arisen out of the conduct set forth in the original pleading[,]" and the central inquiry is "whether adequate notice of the matters raised in the amended pleading has been given to the opposing party." ASARCO LLC v. Goodwin, 756 F.3d 191, 202 (2d Cir. 2014).
Once a party files a class action complaint, the applicable limitations period for the asserted claim is tolled as to all members of the putative class. Am. Pipe & Constr. Co. v. Utah, 414 U.S. 538, 554 (1974) ("American Pipe") ("[T]he commencement of a class action suspends the applicable statute of limitations as to all asserted members of the class who would have been parties had the suit been permitted to continue as a class action."). The rationale for this American Pipe tolling is that "absent putative class members are expected and encouraged to remain passive . . . and to `rely on the named plaintiffs to press their claims.'" Cullen v. Margiotta, 811 F.2d 698, 719 (2d Cir. 1987) (quoting Crown, Cork & Seal Co. v. Parker, 462 U.S. 345, 350-51 (1983)), overruled on other grounds by Agency Holding Corp. v. Malley-Duff & Assocs., 483 U.S. 143 (1987). American Pipe tolling applies not only to wholly passive members of the putative class, but also to those "who later file their own independent actions." Police & Fire Ret. Sys. v. IndyMac MBS, 721 F.3d 95, 105 (2d Cir. 2013). The rule shadows "the functional operation of a statute of limitations. . . . The theory is that even if one has a just claim it is unjust not to put the adversary on notice to defend within the period of limitation and that the right to be free of stale claims in time comes to prevail over the right to prosecute them." American Pipe, 14 U.S. at 554 (quoting Order of R.R Telegraphers v. Ry. Express Agency, 321 U.S. 342, 348-49 (1944)). However, as the Supreme Court recently explained, "[t]he source of the tolling rule applied in American Pipe is the judicial power to promote equity, rather than to interpret and enforce statutory provisions. Nothing in the American Pipe opinion suggests that the tolling rule it created was mandated by the text of a statute or federal rule." Ca. Pub. Employees' Ret. Sys. v. ANZ Sec., Inc., 137 S.Ct. 2042, 2051-52 (2017) ("CalPERS").
The Damages Class Plaintiffs contend that they should be granted leave to amend over the defendants' objections, and that the amendment should relate back to their original complaint, because "the core of [their] allegations has been and continues to be that Defendants' collusive agreements and network rules inflate prices to supracompetitive levels." DE 6880-5 (Damages Class Reply) at 6. While I agree with that characterization of their factual allegations, I disagree that it resolves the dispute. Specifically, I conclude that the Damages Class Plaintiffs rely on a legal theory that is not only new, but fundamentally distinct from the legal violation that they previously asserted — indeed, it relies on the new authority of AmEx to posit a theory of liability that accounts for benefits to cardholders that they had affirmatively rejected earlier in the litigation. DE 1494-2 (redacted version of Class Plaintiffs' memorandum of law in support of summary judgment) at 61-67; 1494-4 (redacted reply) at 40-42; DE 1503 (sealed version of Class Plaintiffs' motion for summary judgment); see also Opp. at 3-4 (citing Class Plaintiffs' opposition to dismissal motion, DE 1226, at 17). Thus, while fairness requires that the Damages Class Plaintiffs be permitted to adapt to AmEx by asserting claims that they previously had reason to believe would be futile, fairness likewise precludes having those claims relate back to the start of the instant litigation.
The defendants fault the plaintiffs for delay, arguing that they have had the opportunity to assert claims based on a two-sided market at least since the defendants themselves raised it as a defense to the Class Plaintiffs' assertion that the defendants had harmed competition in a market defined to exclude cardholders as relevant actors. See Opp. at 15-17. Without more, however, such delay is not a reason to deny leave to amend. See Agerbrink v. Model Svc. LLC, 155 F.Supp.3d 448, 452 (S.D.N.Y. 2016) (citing cases).
What matters more than the delay itself is the reason for it. All of the parties appear to agree that the recent decision in AmEx has prompted the plaintiffs to seek to add to their pleadings the claims that the defendants oppose. See DE 6880-1 ("Damages Class Memo.") at 6; DE 6880-5 ("Damages Class Reply") at 8; Opp. at 1 (arguing that the plaintiffs seek to amend so as to avoid dismissal under AmEx); Defs. Supp. Ltr. at 2 (contending that without additional discovery, the plaintiffs' case would be dismissed under AmEx); Tr. 44 (agreeing that absent amendment and without further discovery, the defendants will likely seek dismissal on the basis of AmEx). That is no surprise, as the parties also appear to agree that AmEx significantly changed the legal landscape: the opinion is the first in which any court has expressly analyzed a payment card antitrust action in the context of a two-sided market. Tr. 33, 44-45; see also US Airways, Inc. v. Sabre Holdings Corp., 2017 WL 1064709, at *10 (S.D.N.Y. Mar. 21, 2017) (recognizing that AmEx "is one of the few cases that explicitly addresses two-sided markets").
To be sure, the court in AmEx took pains to distinguish the case before it from the circumstances of the Visa case (upon which the plaintiffs here previously relied in describing the market relevant to the instant litigation), and it would be premature to opine as to whether AmEx does or does not provide a basis for dismissing the claims previously asserted in these consolidated actions. At a minimum, the fact that the same court that decided AmEx went on just a few weeks later to affirm this court's dismissal of the claims in Salveson — a decision predicated on the assumption of a one-sided market that excludes cardholders as relevant actors — would at least support a colorable argument that the initial claims in this litigation asserting a one-sided market remain viable. But what cannot reasonably be disputed is that AmEx altered the parties' litigation risks in an important way. Simply put, the plaintiffs had no reason to add two-sided market claims before AmEx because they disagreed with the defendants that such a market definition was appropriate and the unequivocal case law of this circuit supported that view; once AmEx necessarily altered their analysis in that regard, they promptly moved to amend. The delay about which the defendants complain was therefore excusable.
The defendants also argue that allowing the disputed amendments now would be unduly prejudicial because it would require them to redo years of discovery, throughout all of which the parties on both sides had assumed that the plaintiffs would seek to prove that the defendants had harmed competition in a one-sided market. See Opp. at 17-20. There is no question that the parties have already borne substantial discovery burdens: by the time the court approved the settlement in Interchange I, the parties had completed fact and expert discovery, which included hundreds of depositions and voluminous document productions. Nor do I seriously question the proposition that the parties have a great deal of work ahead of them in preparing to litigate the newly asserted claims.
The ground has shifted under all of the parties. That does not mean that one side alone should suffer by being limited to the assertion of claims that may suddenly, and quite unexpectedly, have become untenable. Over the past dozen years, all of the parties to this litigation have invested heavily in their assumption that controlling law presumes the relevant market to be one-sided. Now that the circuit court has upset that assumption, both sides will have to invest still more to prepare for litigation of the newly asserted claims. But that in itself is not a reason to foreclose the claims entirely. See Monahan v. New York City Dep't of Corrections, 214 F.3d 275, 285 (2d Cir. 2000) (citing Block, 988 F.2d at 351) ("the fact that one party has spent time and money preparing for trial will usually not be deemed prejudice sufficient to warrant a deviation from the rule broadly allowing amendment to pleadings"); N.Y. State Elec. & Gas Corp. v. Sec'y of Labor, 88 F.3d 98, 104-05 (2d Cir. 1996) (prejudice does not arise from an amending party's change of legal theory, but rather from a resulting disadvantage to the opposing party in presenting its case). In the absence of any undue delay, bad faith, or futility of the newly asserted claims predicated on the existence of a two-sided market, I grant the Damages Class Plaintiffs' motion for leave to amend.
The Damages Class Plaintiffs argue that the new claims based on a two-sided market relate back to their original complaint because they rely on the same factual allegations about the defendants' conduct as before and that the defendants were on notice of the two-sided market theory because they themselves cited it in their own defense. See Damages Class Memo. at 6; Damages Class Reply at 9. As explained below, I respectfully disagree.
The proposition that the defendants could have put themselves on notice of the two-sided market theory by citing it as a refutation of the plaintiffs' initial one-sided market theory is untenable. The Damages Class Plaintiffs cite no authority supporting such a counter-intuitive theory, and it is at odds with prevailing case law. Rule 15 does not allow a wholly new legal theory to relate back to an earlier claim simply because both rest on the same factual assertions. Rather, those factual assertions, and the pleadings that surround them, must give fair notice of the possibility of the later claim. See Slatyon v. Am. Express Co., 460 F.3d 215, 228 (2d Cir. 2006) ("Under Rule 15, the `central inquiry is whether adequate notice of the matters raised in the amended pleading has been given to the opposing party within the statute of limitations by the general fact situation alleged in the original pleading.'") (quoting without internal quotations and citations Stevelman v. Alias Research, Inc., 174 F.3d 79, 86 (2d Cir. 1999)). The litigation of this case did not satisfy that requirement. Instead, the Class Plaintiffs pleaded claims predicated on certain conduct that they contended harmed competition in a one-sided market; the defendants sought to refute those claims in part by arguing that the conduct alleged had in fact promoted competition when viewed in the context of a twosided market; and the Class Plaintiffs replied that such a redefinition of the market was inapposite and therefore unavailing. That is the precise opposite of providing the defendants with fair notice that they might have to defend against a claim that the relevant market has two sides — it is an attempt to forestall the defendants' efforts to characterize the Class Plaintiffs' claims in a way the latter explicitly disavowed.
Such a reading of the record is particularly apt in the context of an antitrust case, where market definition is a critical aspect of the litigation. A plaintiff pleading a claim under Section 1 or 2 of the Sherman Act "must allege a plausible relevant market in which competition will be impaired." City of New York v. Group Health Inc., 649 F.3d 151, 155 (2d Cir. 2011). The Class Plaintiffs originally contended that the defendants were liable because they engaged in conduct that harmed the merchants who purchased their services in a one-sided market, and that any benefits to cardholders arising from that conduct could not avert that liability. Those same plaintiffs now seek to plead a wholly new alternative claim: that the defendants' conduct harmed competition in a different, twosided market. See Tr. at 54 (Damages Class counsel: "I am not going to run away from the fact that the two-sided market theory is different than the one-sided market theory").
The Direct Action Plaintiffs raise many of the same arguments in support of leave to amend as the Damages Class Plaintiffs, and I rely on the reasoning set forth above to grant their motions as well. I note, however, that the Direct Action Plaintiffs are in a different position with respect to some of their arguments. First, granting leave to amend does not have as great an impact on the discovery burdens facing the parties to the Direct Action Plaintiffs' claims: because those claims were filed only after the earlier class-wide settlement, discovery on those claims has not proceeded nearly as far as discovery on the Class Plaintiffs' claims; moreover, recent discovery productions have already begun to focus on the role of cardholders. See DE 6881-3 (Target Reply) at 2-4; DE 6884-6 (7-Eleven Reply) at 3-8; DE 6887-9 (Home Depot Reply) at 6-8 (noting that at the time of filing, depositions for Home Depot had not yet been scheduled).
Second, as the defendants acknowledge, the Direct Action Plaintiffs are entitled in any event to assert for the first time claims for injunctive relief that had previously been barred under the terms of the class-wide settlement. Because such claims can properly include allegations of harm to cardholders in a two-sided market, the discovery that the parties will inevitably conduct on the injunctive relief claims that the Direct Action Plaintiffs are plainly entitled to assert will in any event overlap significantly with the discovery burdens that the defendants fear would arise as a result of granting the contested motions to amend. See Tr. 45-46. I therefore grant the Direct Action Plaintiffs leave to amend.
Like the Damages Class Plaintiffs, the claims that the Direct Action Plaintiffs originally filed were predicated on allegations that the defendants' conduct harmed competition in a one-sided market. See, e.g., Tr. at 20 (acknowledgment by Target's counsel). Accordingly, as with the Damages Class Plaintiffs, I conclude that the Direct Action Plaintiffs' new claims relating to a two-sided market do not relate back to their original complaints.
The Direct Action Plaintiffs fare no better in seeking to take advantage of American Pipe tolling by characterizing their two-sided market claims as an "alternative" theory that supplements the Class Plaintiffs' original claims. Even before the Supreme Court made clear in CalPERS that the nature of American Pipe tolling is wholly equitable, courts in this circuit considering the availability of such tolling employed a notice-based analysis similar to that used to determine the availability of relation back under Rule 15(c). Thus, whether viewed through the prism of relation back or that of equitable tolling under American Pipe, the pertinent question is whether the original class complaint sufficed to put the defendants on fair notice of the plaintiffs' later claims. Cullen, 811 F.2d at 720 ("American Pipe tolling is properly extended to claims of absent class members that involve the same evidence, memories, and witnesses as were involved in the initial putative class action."), overruled on other grounds by Agency Holding Corp. v. Malley-Duff &Assocs., Inc., 483 U.S. 143 (1987); Escott v. Barchis Constr. Corp., 340 F.2d 731, 734 (2d Cir. 1965) (tolling the plaintiffs' claims because "[t]he defendants were thus made aware of the nature of the evidence that would be needed at the trial"); see also CalPERS, 137 S. Ct. at 2051 ("By filing a class complaint within the statutory period, the named plaintiff [in American Pipe] `notifie[d] the defendants not only of the substantive claims being brought against them, but also of the number and generic identities of the potential plaintiffs who may participate in the judgment.'") (quoting American Pipe, 414 U.S. at 555); Crown, Cork & Steal Co. 462 U.S. at 353 (notice required to make defendants aware of "the need to preserve evidence and witnesses respecting the claims of all the members of the class.").
Thus, for the same reasons that I conclude above that the newly pleaded claims asserting harm in a two-sided market do not relate back to earlier pleadings asserting harm in a different market, I also conclude that equity does not require applying equitable tolling under American Pipe to the Direct Action Plaintiffs' claims based on a two-sided market. In addition to relying on the same reasoning set forth above, however, I also take into account arguments that the Direct Action Plaintiffs offer specifically on the tolling issue.
First, the Direct Action Plaintiffs' reliance on the "same anticompetitive rules and conduct" alleged in the class complaint and their proposed amendments incorrectly narrows the scope of the notice required. See Target Reply at 9; 7-Eleven Reply at 10; Home Depot Reply at 9. To successfully plead and prove a violation of Section 1 or 2 of the Sherman Act, a plaintiff must identify not only the defendant's allegedly anticompetitive conduct, but also the relevant market and the resulting anticompetitive harm. Group Health, Inc., 649 F.3d at 155 (citing cases). But the Class Plaintiffs' original complaints identified only a one-sided market in which the effect of the defendants' conduct on cardholders was immaterial. See Tr. 23 (counsel for Damages Class Plaintiffs explaining that "if this case had gone to trial three years ago, we would have put in evidence that there is a one-sided market."). As a result, the defendants were never on sufficient notice that they needed to preserve and develop evidence relating to the effect of their conduct on cardholders who were actors in a two-sided market. See Crown, Cork & Steal Co., 462 U.S. at 353.
Second, Home Depot contends that declining to toll the "alternative" market allegations in this case will force absent plaintiffs to file separate actions if they disagree "even slightly" with any of class counsel's litigation decisions. Home Depot Reply at 9-10. I respectfully disagree: if Home Depot or any of the other Direct Action Plaintiffs had refrained from asserting a two-sided market theory only out of respect for American Pipe's preference to avoid a proliferation of lawsuits (and not because, like all of the other parties to this litigation, they assumed that the relevant market was the one-sided kind at issue in Visa that excludes cardholders), they would have asserted such claims as soon as they entered the fray rather than now. It thus does no violence to the rationale of American Pipe to observe that under the precise circumstances of this litigation, equity does not compel the tolling the Direct Action Plaintiffs seek. The goal of American Pipe tolling is "to prevent a `needless multiplicity of actions' which might result if putative class members were required to file separate actions to hedge against the possibility of the class action failing." Lawrence v. Phillip Morris Cos., 1999 WL 51845, at *3 (E.D.N.Y. Jan. 9, 1997) (citing Crown, Cork & Steal Co., 462 U.S. at 351)). But that goal is not served by tolling in this case because no putative class member ever had a reason to hedge against the failure of the Class Plaintiffs' original claims by asserting a separate claim predicated on allegations of competitive harm to a two-sided market — as the history of this litigation makes clear, the incentive for any party to do so arose only once the circuit court decided AmEx.
Finally, the Direct Action Plaintiffs cite the defendants' acknowledgement that the new twosided market claims will be consolidated with earlier causes of action as a basis to conclude that the two types of claims share sufficient common factual issues to support American Pipe tolling. Direct Action Plaintiffs' Supp. Ltr. at 3. Again, I respectfully disagree: the standard for consolidation in multidistrict litigation is wholly distinct from the analysis pertinent to a request for American Pipe tolling. See 28 U.S.C. § 1407(a) (requiring "one or more common questions of fact."). I therefore conclude that the Direct Action Plaintiffs' proposed two-sided market allegations are not entitled to American Pipe tolling.
For the reasons set forth above, I grant in part and deny in part the plaintiffs' contested motions for leave to file an amended complaint. Specifically, I grant the plaintiffs leave to amend their complaints to include allegations pertaining to a two-sided relevant market over the defendants' objections, but only to the extent that these claims are not time-barred: the two-sided market claims do not relate back to earlier pleadings and are not subject to equitable tolling. As to all other proposed amendments, I grant leave on consent. The plaintiffs are respectfully directed to amend their complaints in accordance with this order and to file the amended complaints as separate entries on the docket by October 27, 2017.
SO ORDERED.
Consistent with the general usage in this litigation: