ROBIE, J. —
This appeal arises out of an application Mercury Casualty Company (Mercury) filed in 2009 to increase its homeowners insurance rates. In denying the increase Mercury requested, the Insurance Commissioner (the commissioner) made two decisions that are at issue on appeal. First, the commissioner determined that under section subdivision (f) of 2644.10 of title 10 of the California Code of Regulations, which disallows, for ratemaking purposes, all "[i]nstitutional advertising expenses," Mercury's entire advertising budget had to be excluded from the calculation of the maximum permitted earned premium because "Mercury[] aims its entire advertising budget at promoting the Mercury Group as a whole" rather than "seek[ing] to obtain business for a specific insurer and also provid[ing] customers with pertinent information" about that specific insurer.
Finding no merit in these arguments, or any of the other arguments offered to overturn the judgment, we affirm.
We begin with some brief background on the area of the law involved here. "At the November 8, 1988, General Election, the voters approved an initiative statute that was designated on the ballot as Proposition 103. The measure made numerous fundamental changes in the regulation of automobile and other forms of insurance in California. Formerly, the so-called `open competition' system of regulation had obtained, under which `rates [were] set by insurers without prior or subsequent approval by the Insurance Commissioner ....' [Citation.] Under that system, `California ha[d] less regulation of insurance than any other state, and in California automobile liability insurance [was] less regulated than most other forms of insurance.' [Citation.] The initiative contained, among others, provisions relating to the rollback of rates for insurance within its coverage for the period extending from November 8, 1988, through November 7, 1989. (For purposes here, a rate is the price or premium that an insurer charges its insureds for insurance.)" (20th Century Ins. Co. v. Garamendi, supra, 8 Cal.4th 216, 239-240 (20th Century).) "For the period extending from November 8, 1988, through November 7, 1989 (hereafter sometimes the rollback year or simply 1989), as a temporary regulatory regime of rate reduction and freeze evidently designed to allow the setting up of a permanent regulatory regime to follow, Proposition 103 itself sets a maximum rate for covered insurance at 80 percent of the rate for the same insurance in effect on November 8, 1987 (hereafter sometimes the 1987
"In Calfarm Ins. Co. v. Deukmejian (1989) 48 Cal.3d 805 [258 Cal.Rptr. 161, 771 P.2d 1247] (hereafter sometimes Calfarm), [the Supreme Court] upheld, inter alia, Proposition 103's provision requiring rate rollbacks." (20th Century, supra, 8 Cal.4th at p. 240.) The court "reviewed Proposition 103 against challenges under the United States and California Constitutions, including a claim that the rate rollback requirement provision was on its face invalid as confiscatory and arbitrary, discriminatory, or demonstrably irrelevant to legitimate policy in violation of the takings clause of the Fifth Amendment and article I, section 19 and the due process clause of the Fourteenth Amendment and article I, sections 7 and 15. In the course of [the court's] analysis, [the court] rejected the point." (20th Century, at pp. 243-244, fn. omitted.)
Five years after Calfarm, in 20th Century, the Supreme Court "review[ed] the implementation of Proposition 103's rate rollback requirement provision by the Insurance Commissioner." (20th Century, supra, 8 Cal.4th at p. 240.) The court ultimately upheld the commissioner's actions. (Id. at p. 329.)
With that background in mind, we turn to the facts of the present case. In May 2009, Mercury filed an application with the Department of Insurance to increase its rates on its homeowners multiperil line of insurance, which consists of policy form HO-3 (residential homeowners insurance), policy form HO-4 (renters and tenants insurance), and policy form HO-6 (insurance for condominium owners). Originally, Mercury sought an overall rate increase of 3.9 percent. As the administrative proceeding regarding Mercury's application continued, however, Mercury filed updated applications, so that Mercury ultimately sought an overall rate increase of either 8.8 percent or 6.9 percent. (The reason for the difference is not material here.)
In June 2009, Consumer Watchdog submitted a petition to intervene in the proceeding, combined with a petition for a hearing on Mercury's application. The commissioner granted the petition to intervene in July 2009 but deferred ruling on the petition for a hearing until two years later, when, in May 2011, the commissioner issued a notice of hearing on his own motion and on Consumer Watchdog's petition.
The commissioner and Consumer Watchdog filed motions to strike some of Mercury's prefiled direct testimony, including the testimony of Hamada and some of the testimony of Appel. In ruling on those motions, the administrative law judge (ALJ) explained that to qualify for the variance under section 2644.27(f)(9), Mercury had to "demonstrate [that] the maximum earned premium under the ratemaking formula results in an inability to operate successfully. Put differently Mercury is permitted to show the maximum rate will cause deep financial hardship to Mercury's enterprise as whole." Finding that neither Hamada nor Appel "provide[d] evidence that the regulatory rate, as applied to Mercury, prevents Mercury from operating successfully," the ALJ struck Hamada's "statements pertaining to confiscation" and those portions of Appel's testimony contending that the "regulatory rate of return is confiscatory." The ALJ later made similar rulings as Mercury tried several more times to offer testimony from Hamada and Appel concerning "fair return."
In its posthearing brief, Consumer Watchdog argued that all of Mercury's advertising expenses should be excluded from the rate calculation as institutional advertising expenses because the evidence showed that none of Mercury's advertising in California was aimed at obtaining business for a particular insurer; instead, "Mercury's ads and campaigns promote a fictional entity called `Mercury Insurance Group.'"
For its part, Mercury argued that under the language of section 2644.10(f), "advertising is not `institutional advertising' if it is aimed at obtaining business for an insurer
In its posthearing brief, the Department of Insurance argued that under 20th Century, "[c]onfiscation occurs when proposed regulatory action would
For its part, Mercury argued that under 20th Century, "in deciding whether rates produced by the formula are `confiscatory,' courts are required to determine if they would deny an insurer the opportunity to earn a `just, reasonable and fair return.'"
In January 2013, the ALJ submitted her proposed decision, which the commissioner adopted in full in February 2013. As relevant here, the commissioner found that "Mercury General Corporation is the parent company for Mercury Casualty and 21 other entities. Mercury General provides no services to customers and receives all its operating resources directly from its insurance affiliates, most notably Mercury Casualty." "In 2008, 2009 and 2010 Mercury General Corporation's advertising expenses totaled $26 million, $27 million, and $30 million respectively." "Mercury General and all its affiliates advertise under the name `Mercury Insurance Group,'" and "Mercury does not allocate advertising expenditures to specific insurance affiliates nor does the advertising department distinguish between insurance entities when generating advertising campaigns." Based on these findings, the commissioner determined that under section 2644.10(f), "Mercury's entire advertising budget must be excluded from the rate application" because "Mercury[] aims its entire advertising budget at promoting the Mercury Group as whole" rather than "seek[ing] to obtain business for a specific insurer and also provid[ing] customers with pertinent information" about that specific insurer. The commissioner also determined that Mercury did not qualify for the constitutional variance under section 2644.27(f)(9) because "Mercury failed to demonstrate the rate decrease results in deep financial hardship." Based on these (and other) determinations, the commissioner denied Mercury's application for an overall rate increase of 8.8 percent and instead approved an 8.18 percent rate decrease for policy form HO-3, a 4.32 percent rate increase for policy form HO-4, and a 29.44 percent rate increase for policy form HO-6.
In March 2013, Mercury filed a petition for writ of mandate and complaint for declaratory relief in the superior court seeking review of the commissioner's decision. Consumer Watchdog and the Trades successfully petitioned for leave to intervene.
In August 2014, Mercury appealed from the superior court's June ruling denying its writ petition, even though judgment had not yet been entered. In January 2015, the court issued a formal order denying Mercury's writ petition and dismissing Mercury's complaint for declaratory relief. The court also denied or dismissed all of the causes of action in the Trades' complaint in intervention. In doing so, the court addressed and rejected the Trades' argument that section 2644.10(f) violates the First Amendment.
In February 2015, the court entered judgment against Mercury and the Trades. Mercury and the Trades timely appealed from that judgment.
Section 2644.10(f) provides that "[i]nstitutional advertising expenses" "shall not be allowed for ratemaking purposes" and that "`[i]nstitutional advertising' means advertising not aimed at obtaining business for a specific insurer and not providing consumers with information pertinent to the decision whether to buy the insurer's product."
In disallowing all of Mercury's advertising expenses as institutional advertising expenses, the commissioner explained that "institutional advertising is image advertising which strives to enhance a company's reputation or improve corporate name recognition. Such advertising does not promote a specific product or service but instead attempts to obtain favorable attention to the company as whole." (Fns. omitted.) The commissioner then made the following findings regarding Mercury's advertising: "Mercury General and all its affiliates advertise under the name `Mercury Insurance Group.' The Mercury Insurance Group is not a legal entity in any state and not a licensed
The commissioner concluded that section 2644.10(f) "permits [in the context of ratemaking] only [expenses for] advertising that seeks to obtain business for a specific insurer and also provides customers with pertinent information. As Mercury[] aims its entire advertising budget at promoting the Mercury Group as a whole, ... Mercury's entire advertising expenditures must be removed from the ratemaking formula."
The superior court concluded that the commissioner's interpretation of section 2644.10(f) was "reasonable and consistent with Proposition 103's goals of consumer protection." "Thus, if Mercury wished to include its advertising expenses in the ratemaking calculation, it was required to show that (1) its advertising was aimed at obtaining business for a specific insurer and (2) provided consumers with information pertinent to the decision whether to buy the insurer's product." The court further concluded that the commissioner "properly concluded that Mercury's advertising was not directed at a `specific insurer'" and for that reason the commissioner correctly excluded all of Mercury's advertising expenses from the rate calculation.
On appeal, Mercury contends the commissioner erred in disallowing all of Mercury's advertising expenses because the commissioner erroneously held that advertising qualifies as institutional advertising if either of the two criteria in section 2644.10(f) is met, when the regulation requires that both criteria be met. According to Mercury, "[t]he [c]ommissioner ... improperly substituted the word `or' for the word `and' in the regulation."
That brings us to Mercury's argument that the commissioner erred in concluding that Mercury's advertising was not aimed at obtaining business for a specific insurer because "all of Mercury's advertising was conducted under the trade name `Mercury' rather than the technical corporate name `Mercury Casualty Company.'" Mercury contends the commissioner was wrong in this regard "for several reasons." Before addressing those reasons, however, we pause to more fully set forth the commissioner's exact ruling on this subject.
Contrary to Mercury's argument, the commissioner did not conclude that Mercury's advertising was not aimed at obtaining business for a specific insurer because all of that advertising was conducted under the trade name "Mercury" rather than the technical corporate name "Mercury Casualty Company." Instead, the commissioner's ruling was far more comprehensive and nuanced than Mercury's argument acknowledges. First, the commissioner found, by a preponderance of the evidence, "the following facts with regard to Mercury's advertising expenditures and methods":
Based on these findings, the commissioner reached the following conclusions: "Mercury defines institutional advertising as advertising that is not designed to generate business or provide customers with information. This definition of institutional advertising is both narrow and impracticable, and would render all advertising expenses chargeable to the ratepayer; a fact Mercury concedes. Instead, the Regulation permits only advertising that seeks to obtain business for a specific insurer and also provides customers with pertinent information. As Mercury[] aims its entire advertising budget at promoting the Mercury Group as a whole, the [commissioner] concludes that Mercury's entire advertising expenditures must be removed from the ratemaking formula. [¶] ... [¶]
"Mercury admits its advertising does not seek to obtain business for a specific insurer. In fact, Mr. Thompson acknowledges that all of Mercury's advertising is designed for the insurance group and
"Nor can Mercury argue that the `Mercury Insurance Group' is a specific insurer. The Mercury Insurance Group is not a legal entity, nor is there any consensus as to the makeup of the Mercury Insurance Group. Mr. Thompson testified the Mercury Insurance Group is comprised of Mercury Casualty, Mercury Insurance Company, and California Automobile. But Mr. Yeager testified the Mercury Insurance Group includes all 22 legal entities that make up the consolidated Mercury General Corporation. What is certain is that Mercury General does not advertise for its specific insurers and instead engages in advertising on behalf of the organization as a whole. [¶] ... [¶]
"Mercury urges the Commissioner to interpret `specific insurer' to mean `a specific group of affiliated insurers.' Yet such an interpretation is contrary to the clear regulatory intent and inconsistent with the purpose of [the] provision.
"Regulation 2644.10, subdivision (f) contains clear and unambiguous language. The Regulation defines institutional advertising as advertising not aimed at obtaining business for a
"Mercury also argues the Regulation is arbitrary. Mercury contends there is no logical reason to penalize an insurer for advertising under a group insurance name. But such an argument is defeated when one considers the Regulation's intent. Consumers are obligated to pay only expenses necessary in the offering of an insurance product or that in some way provide them benefit. Mercury may not charge consumers for advertising that promotes corporate identity, enhances public opinion, or increases name and brand awareness. Mercury chose to direct its advertising budget towards its entire group of affiliates. In so doing, Mercury does not distinguish between those expenses chargeable to Mercury Casualty customers and those chargeable to affiliated ratepayers. As such, Mercury cannot require its Mercury Casualty policyholders to fund its advertising for other Mercury companies. In addition, Mercury does not explain why Mercury Casualty policyholders, as opposed to shareholders, should shoulder the expense of advertising for Mercury General since that does not benefit them in any fairly discernible and direct way. This failure means Mercury's entire advertising budget must be excluded from the rate application." (Fns. omitted.)
With this more complete understanding of the commissioner's ruling, we turn back to Mercury's arguments. Eschewing even any pretense of arguing about the meaning of the term "specific insurer" in light of the various well-known rules of statutory construction, Mercury offers four ad hoc reasons why the commissioner's determination that the term "specific insurer" does not embrace "`a specific group of affiliated insurers'" should be deemed "wrong." First, Mercury contends the commissioner's ruling "unreasonably forces insurers to advertise under their technical corporate names" because it "would generate confusion as consumers shop for coverage among
Finally, Mercury contends that "[b]ecause the [c]ommissioner ... erroneously construed section 2644.10(f) in the disjunctive and then found that Mercury's trade name advertising did not meet the `specific insurer' requirement," the commissioner did not consider or weigh "the evidence to determine if Mercury's ads met the `pertinent information' requirement" of the second criterion in the regulation. This argument need not detain us long. We have concluded already that section 2644.10(f) does not set forth two criteria that are to be separately analyzed and applied. Instead, the regulation sets forth a singular, unified definition of what qualifies as "[i]nstitutional advertising." Having found that Mercury aims its entire advertising budget at promoting the Mercury Insurance Group as a whole and having concluded that the Mercury Insurance Group is not a specific insurer within the meaning
For their part, the Trades contend the commissioner's interpretation of section 2644.10(f), "endorsed by the trial court — is inconsistent with the language of the regulation, and is incorrect." The Trades also contend that the exclusion of institutional advertising expenses from the rate formula violates the First Amendment by imposing a content-based penalty on speech. We address these arguments in turn.
To fully understand the Trades' argument that the commissioner and the superior court erred in interpreting section 2644.10(f), further explanation of the regulatory scheme, and the superior court's decision, is required.
Expenses that are excluded from the rate calculation, including institutional advertising expenses, are entered on pages 13a and 13b of the rate application. These pages provide for calculation of a three-year average "[e]xcluded [e]xpense [f]actor," which is a percentage determined by dividing total excluded expenses by direct earned premiums. For example, Mercury's updated application showed a 0.20 percent excluded expense factor for 2008, which resulted from dividing total excluded expenses of $5,703,498 by direct earned premiums of $2,808,839,000.
In framing the issue regarding the commissioner's interpretation of section 2644.10(f), the superior court stated that "[t]he dispute is whether the term `specific insurer' means only the rate applicant (in this case, Mercury
Construing the superior court's conclusion to be that the term "specific insurer" in section 2644.10(f) "means the applicant," the Trades argue that "[t]his construction [of the regulation] is not acceptable" because it "does not match what is calculated as the excluded expense factor." Noting that the regulation calls for nationwide, or "groupwide," data to calculate the excluded expense factor, the Trades argue that "[i]f all advertising for other group affiliates is counted as an excluded expense in the numerator, the numerator and denominator do not contain like data." In other words, the Trades posit that under the superior court's construction of the regulation, the denominator will consist of the national direct earned premium from all insurers within the group but the numerator will consist of all advertising expenses except those relating to the applicant, including advertising expenses related to "specific insurers" other than the applicant. The Trades contend that "the result of such a mismatch is not a proper allocation to a California line of insurance of its proper share of countrywide group expense."
The commissioner responds that "advertising for specific affiliates [other than the applicant] is not excluded under [section] 2644.10[(f)]." "Advertising for a specific affiliate — any affiliate — is not considered institutional and therefore any such expenses are not excluded. So long as the advertising is targeted to a specific insurer, it does not matter what affiliate it is for." Moreover, the commissioner points out that "there [wa]s no evidence that any advertising expenses for any specific insurer were excluded" here.
This last point is dispositive of the Trades' argument. The commissioner specifically found that "Mercury[] aims its entire advertising budget at promoting the Mercury Group as a whole" and that "Mercury General does not advertise for its specific insurers and instead engages in advertising on behalf of the organization as a whole." The Trades point to no evidence to the contrary. Accordingly, it is apparent that here the numerator in the calculation of the excluded expense factor contained no expenses for advertising that related to any "specific insurer," whether the applicant (Mercury Casualty
The Trades next argue that the commissioner's interpretation of section 2644.10(f) "is inconsistent with the reality of consumer perception" because "[i]f an advertisement makes a point about homeowner's insurance, and says `Mercury', it is an advertisement `aimed at obtaining business for [the] specific insurer' writing Mercury homeowner's insurance." Even if this were true, however, the Trades point to no evidence that Mercury's excluded advertising expenses included expenses for any such advertisement. Accordingly, the Trades have failed to fully develop this argument, and we need not consider it further.
The Trades also argue that "an advertisement may be `aimed at obtaining business' for more than one affiliated `specific insurer[].'" This argument goes nowhere because the commissioner found that Mercury's advertising was not aimed at obtaining business for any specific insurer, and the Trades point to no evidence to the contrary.
In summary, none of the Trades' attacks on the commissioner's interpretation and application of section 2644.10(f) has any merit.
The Trades contend that because expenses for advertising that is deemed "institutional" are excluded from the rate formula, thereby reducing the "permitted earned premium," and because the determination of whether advertising qualifies as "institutional" is based on the content of the advertisements, the institutional advertising regulation amounts to a constitutionally impermissible content-based penalty on speech. We are not persuaded.
For its part, Consumer Watchdog contends section 2644.10(f) does not place any financial burden on speech, but we disagree. Here, the regulation burdened Mercury financially because its effect was to exclude all of Mercury's advertising expenses from the rate formula, which necessarily resulted in a lesser maximum premium rate than Mercury would have been allowed if its advertising expenses had been included in the formula. As Mercury points out, "[i]f advertising expense is excluded from the dollars permitted in the rate, there is no revenue source from which it can be paid. The insurer can either pay for such advertising out of profit, or stop the advertising." Thus, assuming two otherwise identically situated insurers, one of which engaged solely in institutional advertising and the other of which engaged solely in noninstitutional advertising, the advertiser that engaged only in noninstitutional advertising would reap a greater profit because of section 2644.10(f) than the advertiser that engaged only in institutional advertising. For this reason, as the Trades contend, "the regulation burdens... speech" based on the content of that speech and thus implicates the First Amendment.
For the foregoing reasons, the Trades' constitutional challenge to section 2644.10(f) is without merit.
On appeal, Mercury and the Trades assert various errors in this aspect of the commissioner's and superior court's rulings. First, Mercury asserts that the commissioner and superior court erred in holding that rates are constitutionally confiscatory only if they result in financial distress, rather than simply in the inability to earn a fair return. The Trades make a similar argument. Second, Mercury asserts that the commissioner and the superior court erred in determining that "the relevant enterprise" "in assessing confiscation" "was not Mercury's homeowners' insurance line, but Mercury as a whole." Again, the Trades make a similar argument. Mercury and the Trades also make some other arguments we will identify more fully below. And the
The last argument by the Trades can be disposed of briefly. Inasmuch as section 2644.27(f)(9) expressly incorporates principles of constitutional law, and because "where the action of an administrative agency infringes constitutionally granted rights, independent judicial review must be invoked" (Kerrigan v. Fair Employment Practice Com. (1979) 91 Cal.App.3d 43, 51 [154 Cal.Rptr. 29]), it does not matter for our purposes whether, as the Trades argue, the superior court improperly deferred to the commissioner in construing and applying section 2644.27(f)(9). Engaging in our own independent judicial review, as we must, we will not defer to either the commissioner or the superior court. Thus, any error the superior court might have made in this regard was necessarily harmless.
With that out of the way, we turn to the remaining arguments presented on the constitutional variance in section 2644.27(f)(9).
Because section 2644.27(f)(9) expressly refers to 20th Century, it is appropriate to begin there. As we have noted, in 20th Century the California Supreme Court "review[ed] the implementation of Proposition 103's rate rollback requirement provision by the Insurance Commissioner." (20th Century, supra, 8 Cal.4th at p. 240.) As relevant here, the superior court had "determined that the rate regulations as to rollbacks [we]re invalid on their face with respect to the ratemaking formula" (id. at p. 282) because, among other things, the ratemaking formula the commissioner adopted "preclude[d] a return covering the insurer's cost of service plus 10 percent of its capital base," and "through such preclusion, the formula [wa]s ... confiscatory" (id. at p. 288). In support of this latter conclusion, the superior court also determined that "confiscation does not require `deep financial hardship' within the meaning of Jersey Central [Power & Light Co. v. F.E.R.C. (D.C. Cir. 1987) 258 U.S. App.D.C. 189 [810 F.2d 1168]]." (20th Century, at p. 288.)
The Supreme Court concluded that "[i]n this regard ..., the superior court's conclusion is substantially erroneous." (20th Century, supra, 8 Cal.4th at p. 288.) In determining "the ratemaking formula ... [wa]s ... not confiscatory," the high court began by noting that it "would do well to
"... [T]he consumer has a legitimate interest in freedom from exploitation....
"... [F]or its part, the producer `has a legitimate concern with [its own] financial integrity .... From the investor or company point of view it is important that there be enough revenue not only for operating expenses but also for the capital costs of the business. These include service on the debt and dividends on the stock. [Citation.] By that standard the return to the equity owner should be commensurate with returns on investments in other enterprises having corresponding risks. That return, moreover, should be sufficient to assure confidence in the financial integrity of the enterprise, so as to maintain its credit and to attract capital.' [Citation.]
"It must be emphasized that the foregoing describes an interest that the producer may pursue and not a right that it can demand. That interest is `only
"In attempting to balance producer and consumer interests, one may of course arrive at a rate that disappoints one or even both parties. But a striking of the balance to the producer's detriment does not necessarily work confiscation. Indeed, it can threaten confiscation only when it prevents the producer from `operating successfully' — as that phrase is impliedly defined in prior opinions and is expressly used in this, viz., operating successfully during the period of the rate and subject to then-existing market conditions. [¶] ... [¶]
"Thus, a producer may complain of confiscation only if the rate in question does not allow it to operate successfully.... In a word, the inability to operate successfully is a necessary — but not a sufficient — condition of confiscation.
"... [T]he law under the due process clause of article I, sections 7 and 15 of the California Constitution and the takings clause of article I, section 19 of that same instrument is in accord with the foregoing principles." (20th Century, supra, 8 Cal.4th at pp. 292-297, fns. omitted.)
Turning back to the superior court's ruling, the California Supreme Court explained that the ratemaking formula could not be "deemed confiscatory" because the terms of the formula "do not themselves impose a rate ... that inflicts on insurers `... deep financial hardship ...'" (20th Century, supra, 8 Cal.4th at p. 297.) The court then continued as follows: "This point is crucial. It deserves special emphasis. The superior court committed fundamental error. At least in the general case, such as this, confiscation does indeed require `deep financial hardship' within the meaning of Jersey Central, i.e., the inability of the regulated firm to operate successfully — meaning, again, the inability of the regulated firm to operate successfully during the period of the rate and subject to then-existing market conditions. [Citation.] Hence, it does not arise, as the superior court erroneously believed, whenever a rate simply does not `produce[] a profit which an investor could reasonably expect to earn in other businesses with comparable investment risks and which is sufficient to attract capital.' Profit of that magnitude is, of course, an interest that the producer may pursue. But it is not a right that it can demand. It is `only one of the variables in the constitutional calculus of reasonableness.' [Citation.] ... [T]he `notion that [a regulator] is required to maintain, or even allowed to maintain to the exclusion of other considerations, the profit margin of any particular [regulated firm] is incompatible... with a basic precept of rate regulation. "The fixing of prices, like other applications of the police power, may reduce the value of the property which is being regulated. But the fact that the value is reduced does not mean that the regulation is invalid."'" (20th Century, supra, 8 Cal.4th at pp. 297-298.)
The Trades next argue that the superior court "placed undue reliance on 20th Century" because that case "(1) did not involve a separate due process analysis; (2) can and should be read consistently with Calfarm; and (3) is based on unique facts conclusively distinguishing the current context." None of these arguments is persuasive. The first argument depends on the Trades' assertion that Lingle foreclosed any continuing analysis of a price control under the takings clause and instead substituted a separate due process analysis. We have rejected that argument already; Lingle had nothing to do with price controls.
The Trades' second argument — that "20th Century can be harmonized with Calfarm" — is one with which we agree, but not in the way the Trades would like. We have already shown how our Supreme Court expressly stated that the extended discussion from 20th Century set forth above regarding the "deep financial hardship" standard was a "rehears[al of], and elaborat[ion] on, the
The Trades' third argument — that "20th Century's `deep financial hardship' test is inextricably tied to its retrospective context," e.g., examination of the regulations applying to the rollback period rather than those applying to the prior approval system that followed the rollback — does not carry the day either. Nothing in the Supreme Court's extended discussion of the "deep financial hardship" standard suggests that it would apply only to a retrospective price control rather than a prospective price control. Again, the Trades' argument is smoke and mirrors — nothing more.
For the foregoing reasons, we find no error in the application by the commissioner and the superior court of the "deep financial hardship" standard to determine whether a price control is constitutionally confiscatory.
Mercury next contends that "[h]aving adopted a constitutionally deficient `financial distress' test, the Commissioner and Superior Court compounded that error by applying that test to ... Mercury as a whole, including unregulated enterprises and activities." In Mercury's view, "the `enterprise' subject to the regulated rate" should have been "Mercury's homeowners' line." The problem with this argument is that it is inextricably intertwined with the argument we have rejected already — that the commissioner should have used a "fair rate of return" standard for determining confiscation. Mercury itself admits that the standard the commissioner used "dictated the use of data related to Mercury as a whole rather than to Mercury's homeowners' line," while use of a "fair rate of return" standard would have easily allowed the commissioner "to calculate the rate of return yielded by the homeowners' premium as determined under the formula." Because we have determined that the commissioner used the correct, "deep financial hardship" standard, and correctly eschewed the "fair rate of return" standard proffered by Mercury, it follows that there is no basis for us to further consider Mercury's argument that the commissioner did not consider the correct "enterprise."
The Trades also contend that allowing the commissioner to apply the standard of constitutional confiscation to Mercury as a whole necessarily allows him to consider "insurers' revenue generated outside his jurisdiction," which "unconstitutionally extends the powers of a single state." We do not agree. By considering whether the rate formula in California allows an insurer that operates nationwide to avoid "deep financial hardship," the commissioner is not exercising his power outside the bounds of the state, as his determination of the permissible range of rates in California has no bearing on what the insurer is permitted to charge in any other state.
The Trades also contend that allowing the commissioner to apply the standard of constitutional confiscation to Mercury as a whole wrongfully applies the standard "to all lines of insurance even though the prior-approval structure provides for rate regulation by line of insurance." In making this argument, however, the Trades merely return to their own "fair rate of return" standard, by arguing that "[t]he insurer ... will be deprived of the property devoted to the regulated line of business if not allowed the opportunity to earn a fair return" and thus, "the only sensible test is one that looks to the regulated property." As we have rejected the Trades' proffered standard already, we have no basis for accepting the "lines of insurance" argument based on that rejected standard.
To the extent either Mercury or the Trades can be understood to offer other reasons why the standard the commissioner applied is "[i]llogical" or "[u]nworkable," we simply say that it is not for us to question the logic or workability of our Supreme Court's decisions in Calfarm and 20th Century. We can only follow them. (See Auto Equity Sales, Inc. v. Superior Court (1962) 57 Cal.2d 450, 455 [20 Cal.Rptr. 321, 369 P.2d 937].)
Mercury contends the commissioner and the superior court erred by applying the standard for constitutional confiscation to "historical financial
Mercury and the Trades also both contend that the commissioner and/or the superior court erred in holding that the "re-litigation ban" in section 2646.4, subdivision (c) precluded Mercury from offering evidence showing that application of the rate formula would deny Mercury a fair return.
Finally, Mercury asserts that "[b]ased on its erroneous legal rulings, the Superior Court refused to exercise its independent judgment on the evidence establishing that [application of the rate formula] failed to yield a "`fair return.'" We have already concluded, however, that the superior court's rulings with respect to the applicable standard of constitutional confiscation were not erroneous. Consequently, the further assertion of error Mercury offers is necessarily without merit as well.
The judgment is affirmed. The commissioner and Consumer Watchdog shall recover their costs on appeal. (Cal. Rules of Court, rule 8.278(a)(1).)
Raye, P. J., and Mauro, J., concurred.
We will refer to this regulation as section 2644.10(f); other undesignated section references are also to title 10 of the California Code of Regulations.
We will refer to this regulation as section 2644.27(f)(9) and to the variance described therein as the constitutional variance or the confiscation variance.