THOMAS, Chief Circuit Judge:
In these petitions for review, we consider whether the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission ("FERC" or "Commission") arbitrarily and capriciously determined that various energy companies committed tariff violations in California during the summer of 2000. We conclude that it did not, and we deny the petitions for review.
This case is part of a long-standing series of decisions arising out of California's energy crisis in 2000 and 2001. The relevant factual background was described in our prior opinions, so we need not describe it in detail here.
As part of the deregulation, California created two nonprofit entities: the California Power Exchange Corporation ("CalPX") and the California Independent System Operator Corporation ("Cal-ISO"). CPUC, 462 F.3d at 1037-39. CalPX was a wholesale clearinghouse created primarily to operate two spot markets: (1) the "day-ahead" trading market, in which the market clearing price was derived from the sellers' and buyers' price and quantity determinations for the next day's energy transactions, and (2) the "day of" or "hour-ahead" trading market, in which CalPX would determine, on an hourly basis, a single market clearing price which all suppliers would be paid. Id. at 1038. Cal-ISO managed California's electricity transmission grid and was responsible for all real-time operations, including balancing electrical supply and demand. Id. at 1038-39. Both entities were subject to FERC jurisdiction, with CalPX operating pursuant to a FERC-approved tariff and wholesale rate schedule. Pac. Gas & Elec. Co., 77 FERC ¶ 61,204 at 61,803-05 (1996), reh'g denied, 81 FERC ¶ 61,122 (1997).
The Cal-ISO tariff comprehensively regulated California's power markets. In relevant part, the tariff barred power marketers from buying electricity in the day-ahead market in order to resell that electricity in the real-time market. And the tariff incorporated a protocol — the Market Monitoring and Information Protocol ("MMIP") — which set forth rules for identifying and protecting against abuses of market power. See Am. Elec. Power Serv. Corp., 103 FERC ¶ 61,345 at para. 8 (2003).
Unlike most energy markets, 80% of the California transactions during the relevant period were conducted in the spot markets. See CPUC, 462 F.3d at 1039. Most electricity, by design, traded in CalPX's day-ahead market. After a summer 2000 spike in energy prices and a series of rolling blackouts, San Diego Gas & Electric Company ("SDG&E") filed a complaint with FERC under § 206 of the Federal Power Act, 16 U.S.C. § 824(e). See id. at 1040-41. SDG&E's complaint requested that the agency impose a price cap on sales into the CalPX and Cal-ISO markets. See id. at 1041. FERC denied the request, but then commenced an investigatory proceeding into the justness and reasonableness of the market rates. San Diego
Following our remand in CPUC, FERC instructed an administrative law judge ("ALJ") to determine for the period from May 1, 2000 to October 1, 2000 (the "Summer Period"): (1) which market practices and behaviors constituted a violation of the then-current Cal-ISO, CalPX, and individual seller's tariffs and Commission orders; (2) whether any of the respondents engaged in those tariff violations; and (3) whether any such tariff violations affected the market clearing price. San Diego Gas & Elec. Co., 135 FERC ¶ 61,183 at para. 31 (2011).
Months of hearings followed. The California Parties,
A False Export violation occurred when a marketer purchased electricity from the CalPX or other sources internal to California, scheduled that electricity in advance for export, and subsequently scheduled that electricity in real-time for import. See, e.g., San Diego Gas & Elec. Co., 149 FERC ¶ 61,116 at para. 108 (2014) ("Op. 536"); San Diego Gas & Elec. Co., 153 FERC ¶ 61,144 at para. 80 (2015) ("Op. 536-A"). The twin transactions "disguised [the] energy [as] sourced from outside," 142 FERC ¶ 63,011 at para. 36, even though the electricity never left California. See 149 FERC ¶ 61,116 at para. 122 (noting that electricity "scheduled from A ... to B ... and from B to C ... actually just went from A to C."). The False Export strategy let sellers "evade the [Cal-ISO] real time price caps," which did not apply to imported power. 142 FERC ¶ 63,011 at para. 26.
False Load Scheduling — or, "overscheduling" — occurred when sellers in California's day-ahead market submitted exaggerated demand schedules to Cal-ISO. See, e.g., 142 FERC ¶ 63,011 at para. 38. The so-called "uninstructed energy" would then flow on California's transmission grid. Cal-ISO would direct the energy to real-time shortages and, in exchange, pay the seller the real-time market's clearing price. 142 FERC ¶ 63,011 at para. 27. As an expert for the California Parties explained, "the objective of the transaction [was] to earn the [market-clearing price] in the [real-time] market on the power which was purchased from the PX at the [day-ahead] price, thus earning the difference between the two prices[.]" Both the False Load Scheduling and False Export strategies "in simple terms d[id] the same thing[:] They pull[ed] energy out of the day-ahead market ... and they dump[ed] it in the real-time market." The tactics relied on two Summer Period market realities: (1) real-time prices generally exceeded day-ahead prices, and (2) little real-time
The third tariff violation at issue is what the ALJ termed "Anomalous Bidding." See 149 FERC ¶ 61,116 at para. 3. The ALJ defined Anomalous Bidding as "bidding behavior that departs from normal competitive behavior in violation of the CAISO MMIP[.]" 142 FERC ¶ 63,011 at para. 16.
The ALJ went on to identify three types of Anomalous Bidding that violated the MMIP. The Initial Decision defined "Type I Anomalous Bidding" as "[b]ids that vary in output in ways that are unrelated to cost[.]" 142 FERC ¶ 63,011 at para. 18. This type of Anomalous Bidding forms no part of this appeal: the California Parties, the ALJ found, did not meet their prima facie burden of demonstrating that Type I Anomalous Bidding affected market clearing prices. See 142 FERC ¶ 63,011 at para. 33.
The Initial Decision defined "Type II Anomalous Bidding" as "bids with prices above marginal cost in combination with some other tariff violation[.]" 142 FERC ¶ 63,011 at para. 18 (emphasis added). And the Initial Decision defined "Type III Anomalous Bidding," also known as "Economic Withholding," as "[b]ids used to effectuate supply withholding[.]" 142 FERC ¶ 63,011 at para. 18. Those bids occurred whenever the bid price was greater than market-clearing price and the seller's marginal cost was less than the market-clearing price. Some Type III anomalous bids "were set so high above the market price that it was likely that they would not be accepted, thereby either diminishing the available supply to the Cal-ISO or increasing the market clearing price." 142 FERC ¶ 63,011 at para. 28.
As relevant to these petitions, the ALJ determined that False Export, False Load Scheduling, and Types II and III Anomalous Bidding violated the Cal-ISO tariff. See generally 142 FERC ¶ 63,011 at para. 1. False Load Scheduling and False Export, the ALJ concluded, required "the submission of false information" to Cal-ISO, see 142 FERC ¶ 63,011 at paras. 36, 42, and therefore violated "[t]he collective import" of several tariff provisions. See 142 FERC ¶ 63,011 at paras. 36, 43. Type II Anomalous Bidding "depart[ed] significantly" from competitive market behavior in violation of several MMIP provisions. See 142 FERC ¶ 63,011 at para. 24. And economic withholding, the ALJ explained, violated provisions in the MMIP that barred withholding and manipulation. See 142 FERC ¶ 63,011 at paras. 31-32. The ALJ found 34,020 Summer Period transactions that amounted to tariff violations. See 142 FERC ¶ 63,011 at para. 14. Of these, the ALJ found more than 20,000 that affected the market clearing price. Id.
Over the course of the agency proceedings, a number of entities settled with the California Parties and were dismissed from the case. The remaining entities in this petition for review are:
At the California Parties' request, FERC in February 2016 again clarified its Summer Period determinations. See generally San Diego Gas & Elec. Co., 154 FERC ¶ 61,063 (2016) ("Op.536-B"). The February order "clarif[ied] that the remaining Respondents ... are liable to disgorge overcharges and excess payments they received for all sales during all hours of the Summer Period during which the market prices were inflated by tariff violations committed by any of the Respondents." Id. at para. 8. The Commission left "[o]ther [pending] requests for rehearing" — notably, a request filed by MPS in December 2015 — for "a separate order." 154 FERC ¶ 61,063 at para. 1.
These consolidated petitions for review followed. The Federal Power Act provides us jurisdiction to review "order[s] issued by the Commission." See 16 U.S.C. § 825l(b). We have limited that jurisdictional grant to final orders, see Steamboaters v. FERC, 759 F.2d 1382, 1387-88 (9th Cir. 1985), and therefore lack appellate jurisdiction to consider the sellers' ongoing challenge to the remedy that FERC ordered for the violations that the agency identified. See 154 FERC ¶ 61,063 at para. 8. FERC and the sellers agree that order is not final. The evolving scope of the agency's remedy supports that conclusion. Compare 149 FERC ¶ 61,116 at para. 209, with 153 FERC ¶ 61,144 at para. 142, and 154 FERC ¶ 61,063 at para 8. Nevertheless, we have jurisdiction to review the final agency findings on liability. See Harris, 809 F.3d at 499-500.
We review decisions by FERC to determine whether its action was "arbitrary, capricious, an abuse of discretion, or otherwise not in accordance with law." 5 U.S.C. § 706(2); see also Fall River Rural Elec. Coop., Inc. v. FERC, 543 F.3d 519, 525 (9th Cir. 2008). We recognize that FERC's discretion "is at its zenith when... fashioning ... remedies and sanctions[.]" CPUC, 462 F.3d at 1053 (internal quotation omitted). We review FERC's interpretation of a tariff with a "two-step, Chevron-like analysis." PSEG Energy Res. & Trade LLC v. FERC, 665 F.3d 203, 208 (D.C. Cir. 2011) (internal quotation marks omitted). We review the agency's findings of fact for substantial evidence and will not disturb such findings even if "the evidence is susceptible of more than one rational interpretation." CPUC, 462 F.3d at 1045. Our review "is limited to ... the administrative record," Envtl. Coal. of Ojai v. Brown, 72 F.3d 1411, 1414 (9th Cir. 1995),
FERC's determination that Shell, MPS, and Illinova ("sellers") violated the Cal-ISO tariff and MMIP during the Summer Period was not arbitrary, capricious, or an abuse of discretion.
FERC reasonably interpreted the Cal-ISO tariff and MMIP to prohibit the practices of False Export, False Load Scheduling, and Types II and III Anomalous Bidding. FERC interpreted Cal-ISO Tariff §§ 2.2.11.1, 2.2.11.1.1-2 and MMIP §§ 2.1.1.1, 2.1.1.5 to prohibit False Export. The Commission interpreted Cal-ISO Tariff §§ 2.2.7.2, 2.2.11.1 and MMIP §§ 2.1.1.3, 2.1.1.5 to prohibit False Load Scheduling. Types II and III Anomalous Bidding, the Commission concluded, violated MMIP §§ 2.1.1 et seq.
The text of the tariff and MMIP provisions supports FERC's conclusions. Cal-ISO Tariff § 2.2.7.2 required sellers to "submit to the ISO only Balanced Schedules," which the tariff defined as schedules where "Generation, adjusted for Transmission Losses equal[ed] forecast Demand[.]" Cal-ISO Tariff §§ 2.2.11 et seq. required the submitted schedules to "include the name and identification number" of electricity customers, as well as customers' location and demand. The MMIP provisions called for "corrective action" in response to, respectively, "withholding of Generation capacity," "unusual trades or transactions," and "unusual activity or circumstances relating to imports ... or exports[.]"
FERC reasonably determined that False Export, False Load Scheduling and Anomalous Bidding violated these provisions. FERC explained that False Export required that sellers "submit[] [information that] did not correspond to actual load." 149 FERC ¶ 61,116 at para. 120. That falsification amounted to "unusual activity or circumstances relating to imports... or exports[.]" 149 FERC ¶ 61,116 at para. 120. Additionally, because the practice "effectively withheld capacity from day-ahead markets," 149 FERC ¶ 61,116 at para. 120. FERC determined that False Export violated MMIP § 2.1.1.1. As for False Load Scheduling, the Commission determined that sellers violated the balanced schedule requirement by "schedul[ing] fictitious load in anticipation of actual load." 149 FERC ¶ 61,116 at para. 170. Type II and III anomalous bids, the Commission concluded, relied on the above violations or on withholding strategies that departed from competitive market behavior. See 149 FERC ¶ 61,116 at paras. 94, 99.
These determinations comport with the plain text of the Cal-ISO Tariff, of which Summer Period electricity sellers were on notice. See Cal. ex rel. Brown, 139 FERC ¶ 61,210 at para. 26 (2012); see also 142 FERC ¶ 63,011 at para. 42. At minimum, we defer to FERC's reasonable constructions of ambiguous tariff language. See PSEG, 665 F.3d at 208. The sellers' contrary position on overscheduling — that sellers could inflate for California's grid operators the sellers' forecasts of how much electricity the sellers' customers would draw from California's grid — is self-refuting; renders superfluous much of the Cal-ISO tariff; and thwarts California's efforts to supply electricity efficiently and reliably through day-ahead markets. See 153 FERC ¶ 61,144 at para. 96.
In conclusion, FERC reasonably interpreted the Cal-ISO tariff and the MMIP according to the plain text of those documents. We therefore reject the sellers' claims that the tariff and MMIP did not proscribe the practices identified by the agency.
The sellers next contest the policy foundations of FERC's interpretations. The agency's interpretation of the Cal-ISO tariff and the MMIP, the sellers argue, unreasonably characterized permissible arbitrage as a False Export violation. See, e.g., 153 FERC ¶ 61,144 at para. 140. The sellers further claim that FERC's interpretations unreasonably punish False Load Scheduling, a practice which — the sellers contend — arose in response to underscheduling by California's investor-owned utilities. The sellers also argue that False Load Scheduling actually enhanced grid reliability. See 149 FERC ¶ 61,116 at para. 152.
The record evidence bears out FERC's view of these policy considerations. The record establishes that California and FERC intended Cal-ISO's real-time market as an exchange of last resort, not as a full-fledged alternative to the CalPX that would facilitate arbitrage and price convergence. See, e.g., 153 FERC ¶ 61,144 at para. 149; 103 FERC ¶ 61,345 at para. 32; see also Lockyer, 383 F.3d at 1009. The record supports FERC's finding that False Export and False Load Scheduling strategies forced California's investor-owned utilities increasingly to rely on the real-time market in order to serve load. See, e.g., 149 FERC ¶ 61,116 at paras. 163-64, 183. The record supports FERC's conclusion that the False Export and False Load Scheduling strategies threatened to compromise the reliability of California's electrical transmission grid. See, e.g., 149 FERC ¶ 61,116 at para. 142; 142 FERC ¶ 63,011 at paras. 49-50. Thus, FERC's interpretation of the Cal-ISO tariff and the MMIP finds support not only in text, but in policy as well.
Illinova asserts that a section of the Cal-ISO tariff provides the company a safe
Illinova contends that this section creates a de minimis exception for overscheduling liability. The exception shields Illinova, the company continues, because its overscheduling never exceeded 20 MW. Illinova claims that a definition of "Demand" contained in the Cal-ISO tariff support the company's reading of § 22.1.
FERC offers a competing interpretation. The agency construes § 22.1 as an "administrative threshold for Cal-ISO to accept a schedule from the CalPX market." FERC rejects the notion that § 22.1 was intended to — or did — create a de minimis exception to overscheduling liability.
FERC's interpretation of § 22.1 — albeit not incontrovertible — survives this court's review. In particular, the agency's interpretation squares with § 2 of the Cal-ISO tariff, which prescribes the duties of scheduling coordinators. That section provides that "[i]f a Scheduling Coordinator submits a schedule that is not a Balanced Schedule, the ISO shall reject that Schedule provided that Scheduling Coordinators shall have an opportunity to validate their Schedules prior to the deadline for submission to the ISO[.]" The section treats schedule validation — the process that § 22.1 purports to govern — as an ex ante condition that precedes the transmission of electricity, not as an ex post condition whose violation results in liability. Indeed, Illinova's claim that "the tolerance band in § 22.1 requires data on actual demand," cannot be reconciled with Cal-ISO's design, which required schedule submission prior to real-time.
Ultimately, we need not decide which reading of § 22.1 "is the best ... interpretation." See Nat'l Cable & Telecomms. Ass'n v. Brand X Internet Servs., 545 U.S. 967, 980, 125 S.Ct. 2688, 162 L.Ed.2d 820 (2005). Instead, we defer to FERC's construction "so long as that construction is reasonable," PSEG, 665 F.3d at 208, and allow the retroactive application of such a construction unless "manifest injustice" would result, Thorpe v. Hous. Auth. of the City of Durham, 393 U.S. 268, 282, 89 S.Ct. 518, 21 L.Ed.2d 474 (1969). Given the "sophistication of modern energy trading," CPUC, 462 F.3d at 1039, we see no such injustice or unfair surprise here. FERC's construction of Cal-ISO tariff § 22.1 was reasonable and foreseeable.
In short, FERC reasonably interpreted the Cal-ISO tariff and the MMIP to prohibit the practices of False Export, False Load Scheduling and Anomalous Bidding. In addition, the agency reasonably concluded that the tariff and MMIP sufficed to put sellers on notice that such practices were not permitted.
FERC reasonably concluded that the sellers engaged during the Summer Period in the practices deemed tariff violations by the orders on review.
FERC's conclusion that MPS overscheduled and thereby violated the Cal-ISO tariff, see 149 FERC ¶ 61,116 at para. 174, was not arbitrary, capricious, or an abuse of discretion.
We must reject such artificial formalism. FERC properly concluded in Op.536-A that "[t]he agreement with Azusa grant[ed] MPS the ability to make uninstructed sales ... [and] enabled MPS to engage in False Load Scheduling." 153 FERC ¶ 61,144 at para. 148. Specifically, the agreement between Azusa and MPS's predecessor-in-interest, Aquila, gave Aquila the right to provide a pre-schedule of energy deliveries to Azusa. The agreement then required Azusa to release that energy into Cal-ISO. The fact that MPS laundered its overschedules through a municipal utility does not render arbitrary and capricious FERC's liability determination. See id. Thus, substantial evidence supports FERC's finding that MPS engaged in False Load Scheduling in violation of the Cal-ISO tariff.
Substantial evidence supports FERC's finding that MPS and Shell engaged in False Export. FERC determined that the California Parties established a prima facie case of False Export (1) by matching day-ahead transactions that exported electricity from California to real-time transactions that imported electricity to California,
Substantial evidence supports FERC's findings that the sellers' tariff violations increased market-clearing prices for electricity. See 149 FERC ¶ 61,116 at paras. 132-33; 153 FERC ¶ 61,144 at paras. 79-82. The record supports FERC's reliance on a model proposed by the California Parties' expert, Peter Fox-Penner. Under that methodology, the actual market clearing price in each hour was compared to what the clearing price would have been had each individual tariff violation not occurred. The model reasonably considered the price effects of False Export and False Load Scheduling only in the day-ahead market. According to the expert, False Export and False Load Scheduling injected artificial demand into the day-ahead market, thereby increasing day-ahead prices. The expert's model incorporated all bid data submitted to CalPX during the Summer Period. That market operated simply: CalPX generated supply and demand curves by summing supply and demand bids at various prices. The market cleared at the price where the curves crossed. As a result, the expert's model closely tracked the market's operation and outcomes.
The California Parties' expert testimony therefore provides substantial evidence for FERC's finding that the sellers' tariff violations increased market-clearing prices for electricity in the CalPX. Indeed, substantial evidence supports FERC's finding that the expert's model understates the price effects of sellers' actions — even if the model does not quantify the magnitude of that understatement. See 153 FERC ¶ 61,144 at para. 81.
The sellers argue that the model ignores the electricity that False Export and False Load Scheduling moved into Cal-ISO's real-time market. That increased supply, the sellers continue, reduced real-time electricity prices. FERC rejected the argument, see 153 FERC ¶ 61,144 at para. 80, and substantial evidence supports that rejection. Because CalPX day-ahead volumes greatly exceeded Cal-ISO real-time volumes, the California Parties' expert explained that "a price change of a given magnitude in the PX market-clearing price had a much larger impact on the buyers of electricity than that same price change would have in the [real-time] market."
Finally, MPS and Illinova claim that modeled CalPX price effects of "less than 10 cents ... [or] less than one dollar ... were, in fact, smaller than the margin of
In sum, substantial evidence supports FERC's conclusion that the violations affected the CalPX market price. The sellers' attacks on the methodology employed are not persuasive.
FERC's findings on Type III Anomalous Bidding — economic withholding — are supported by the record, and neither Shell nor APX offers developed — let alone persuasive — arguments for disturbing those findings. See generally 153 FERC ¶ 61,144 at paras. 39-42, 46; 149 FERC ¶ 61,116 at paras. 84-86, 99-105. Indeed, the record indicates that Shell's Type III anomalous bids exceeded real-time market-clearing prices, not just the market's marginal cost. See 149 FERC ¶ 61,116 at para. 51; 142 FERC ¶ 63,011 at para. 29. FERC reasonably determined that such conduct contravened MMIP provisions §§ 2.1.1.1 and 2.1.3, which generally barred withholding and manipulation. See 149 FERC ¶ 61,116 at para. 99.
FERC's Summer Period determinations regarding APX and BP were not arbitrary, capricious, or an abuse of discretion.
FERC reasonably determined that APX engaged in economic withholding and overscheduling, and therefore violated the Cal-ISO tariff. See 153 FERC ¶ 61,144 at para. 16; 149 FERC ¶ 61,116 at para. 29. FERC reasonably argues that APX-scheduled sales required the combined actions of APX and its customers. See Automated Power Exch., Inc. v. FERC, 204 F.3d 1144, 1153 (D.C. Cir. 2000) (upholding FERC jurisdiction over APX in part because the market-maker was "an integral part of [electricity] transaction[s]"). Moreover, record evidence demonstrates that APX instructed its members — albeit after the Summer Period ended — on how to engage in tariff violations through APX's services.
APX disputes FERC's determination that the market-maker was jointly and severally liable for overscheduling and Type III Anomalous Bidding. But FERC's determination followed more than a decade of agency decisions establishing APX's joint and several liability for participant violations when liability cannot be apportioned to individual customers based on specific transactions. See, e.g., San Diego Gas & Elec. Co., 127 FERC ¶ 61,269 at para. 272 (2009); San Diego Gas & Elec. Co., 105 FERC ¶ 61,066 at para. 170 (2003). Those decisions acknowledge and reasonably respond to the idiosyncrasies that APX claims the agency ignores. See San Diego Gas & Elec. Co., 127 FERC ¶ 61,269 at para. 272 ("[T]he unique situation of the APX requires that the APX and its sellers be held jointly and severally liable for refunds where the refund liability
At heart, APX's objection boils down to a question of scienter: as a market-maker, it argues that it cannot be held liable for violations when it did not know that schedules reflected false load or economic withholding. However, FERC long and repeatedly has held that "[t]he language in Sections 205(b) and 206 does not contain any reference to intent.... [T]he Commission is to be concerned with anticompetitive effects, not motives." In re Missouri Power & Light Co., 5 FERC ¶ 61,086, 61,140 (1978); see also Transcon. Gas Pipe Line Corp., 26 FERC ¶ 61,029, 61,054 n.26 (1984) (same). Consistent with controlling authority, see Fed. Power Comm'n v. Conway Corp., 426 U.S. 271, 279, 96 S.Ct. 1999, 48 L.Ed.2d 626 (1976) (directing FERC to consider "anticompetitive effects" of conduct alleged to have violated § 205 of the Federal Power Act) (emphasis added), the agency may apply such strict liability to determinations pursuant to § 309. See 16 U.S.C. § 825h. Congress said nothing of scienter in that provision, and we see nothing unreasonable about FERC's interpretation. See Chevron, U.S.A., Inc. v. Nat. Res. Def. Council, Inc., 467 U.S. 837, 844, 104 S.Ct. 2778, 81 L.Ed.2d 694 (1984).
In sum, substantial evidence supports FERC's finding that APX engaged in overscheduling and economic withholding.
APX and BP finally contend that FERC should have found the market-maker a "net buyer" for the Summer Period. This argument is premature. FERC made no findings on this issue and, in fact, sought new evidence on the question.
To the extent that APX and BP argue that FERC's sequencing of apportionment proceedings alone constitutes capricious action, that argument fails. See, e.g., 153 FERC ¶ 61,144 at para. 13. The Supreme Court has long "emphasized that the formulation of procedures [is] basically to be left within the discretion of the agencies[.]" Vermont Yankee Nuclear Power Corp. v. Nat. Res. Def. Council, Inc., 435 U.S. 519, 524, 98 S.Ct. 1197, 55 L.Ed.2d 460 (1978).
In sum, FERC's interpretation of the Cal-ISO and MMIP Tariffs was reasonable and its determination of tariff violations was not arbitrary, capricious, or an abuse of discretion. Because the Commission's remedial order is not final, we lack appellate jurisdiction over it.