SHIRA A. SCHEINDLIN, District Judge.
These cases challenge restraints in the market for baseball and hockey broadcasting. The essence of plaintiffs' argument is that the leagues — Major League Baseball ("MLB") and the National Hockey League ("NHL") — have conspired with regional sports networks ("RSNs"), who produce broadcasts for individual teams, as well as multichannel video programming distributors ("MVPDs"), who sell broadcasts to consumers, to maintain a system of "territorial exclusivity" that limits viewing options and inflates prices.
The details of that system are described in detail in a companion Opinion, also issued today, addressing the issue of class certification.
Plaintiffs believe that this arrangement reflects an unlawful restraint of trade, and that if the league-wide agreement preventing out-of-market RSN distribution were eliminated, fans of out-of-market teams would be able to subscribe to "a la carte channels," which would carry broadcasts only of the subscriber's preferred team — at a lower price than the OMP. For example, a Yankees fan living in Iowa now has to purchase an OMP if she wants to watch a season's worth of Yankees' games — whereas in the but-for world envisioned by plaintiffs ("BFW"), the same fan would have the option of purchasing an OMP or getting an a la carte subscription from the Yankees' RSN.
According to plaintiffs, the absence of a la carte options in the actual world has insulated the OMPs from competition, allowing the leagues, the RSNs, and the MVPDs to command super-competitive subscription fees — leading to overcharge. The purpose of Dr. Noll's model is to model the extent of that overcharge, by comparing the price of OMPs in the actual world to the projected price of OMPs in the BFW, once the territorial restraints are lifted, and the supply chain is reconfigured accordingly.
Defendants have moved pursuant to Rule 702 of the Federal Rules of Evidence ("FRE") to exclude Dr. Noll's expert opinions, alleging that his model suffers from numerous methodological flaws that render his opinions unreliable as a matter of law. For the foregoing reasons, defendants' motion is GRANTED in part and DENIED in part.
The proponent of expert evidence bears the initial burden of establishing admissibility by a "preponderance of the evidence."
To be admissible, the proposed expert testimony must be based "on a reliable foundation."
Although the Supreme Court has instructed district courts to focus "on [the] principles and methodology" employed by the expert and "not on the conclusions that they generate,"
District courts are charged with acting as "`gatekeeper[s] to exclude invalid and unreliable expert testimony,'"
Finally, it is often the case that some, but not all, of an expert's opinions will meet the criteria of FRE 702. Indeed, it is routine for a party to retain a single expert to opine on a variety of issues that, while related, can be analyzed independently under the Daubert standard. In such cases, the court, as gatekeeper, has discretion to decide which opinions are reliable and which are not, from which it follows that a court may exclude portions of an expert report while admitting other portions.
Dr. Noll, a nationally-recognized sports economist, has submitted an expert report explaining why the prices of baseball and hockey broadcasts would decrease in the BFW.
In broad strokes, both models are built on the interplay between consumer demand and preferences for content (the "Demand Side") and the supply chains that distribute that content (the "Supply Side"). In attempting to predict future outcomes in a hypothetical universe, the models depend both on existing data in the actual world and assumptions about how consumers and distributors will behave in the BFW.
Defendants attack Dr. Noll's methodological approach to constructing both the Demand Side and the Supply Side, arguing that design flaws in each constitute independent bases for rendering his model unreliable as a matter of law under FRE 702 and Daubert.
The price of the league bundles and a la carte channels in the BFW is driven by consumer demand.
At bottom, these estimates are predicated on the notion that consumers derive welfare, or utility, from spending time watching the live telecasts of their preferred teams, but only to a certain point — especially in light of price considerations and the corresponding utility of doing things other than watching televised sporting events.
Before delving into the technicalities of the statistical analysis underpinning the Demand Side, it is important to review the underlying consumer viewership statistics — the observed, real-world data buttressing the demand component of the model — in greater detail, as well as some corresponding assumptions Dr. Noll makes using that data. Because there is no observable data about consumer behavior in the BFW, utilizing real-world information is paramount in estimating otherwise unknown consumer preferences.
For its MLB OMP ("MLB Extra Innings"), DirecTV records the time and duration of a single session of viewing a channel for each subscriber.
Dr. Noll uses this viewing data and various assumptions stemming from it to build the foundation of the Demand Side. Notably, as defendants are quick to point out, this foundation lacks any significant additional information regarding consumer demand and preferences. For instance, in modeling demand, Dr. Noll admits that he (1) never sought to obtain demographic data or other personal characteristics about OMP subscribers or baseball and hockey fans more generally, (2) never conducted or attempted to conduct any type of survey of subscribers or non-subscribers regarding viewing preferences or tastes for new products (to wit, a la carte offerings), (3) never sought to obtain specific information regarding price sensitivities of consumers, and (4) that he ignores information regarding package price variation.
So, how does Dr. Noll use the observed data and his assumptions to estimate demand? This is where things get complicated. According to Dr. Noll, "[t]he goal of the econometric estimation is to recover the distribution of consumer preferences for live telecasts of the games of each team [] as well as consumer preferences for viewership and price sensitivity."
These parameters are ultimately determined using the Generalized Method of Moments ("GMM"), an estimation procedure commonly deployed by economists to study demand in markets with differentiated products. Without going into great mathematical detail — many pages of Dr. Noll's declarations consist almost entirely of complex equations beyond the comprehension of the Court or the lawyers in this case — GMM works by using an iterative process in which experimental values are assigned to these parameters with the goal of getting the sample equations to produce results as close as possible to the actual, observed data.
Dr. Noll's predicted moments come close to matching the actual moments drawn from the observed data in the existing world. Consequently, Dr. Noll concludes that "the explanatory power of the model to replicate the data from which it is estimated is high."
After recapturing the demand curve, Dr. Noll turns to the second step of the model — predicting prices in the BFW. To do so, Dr. Noll uses data about demand in the actual world to simulate demand in a market where out-of-market RSNs are available a la carte.
One of the realities of the BFW, assuming bundles continue to exist, is that fans will have the choice between purchasing one or more a la carte channels or a traditional OMP. To simulate this competition on the Demand Side, Dr. Noll's model sorts potential subscribers into one of three categories: (1) singleteam fans, (2) two-team fans, and (3) multi-team fans.
Single-team fans subscribe to a bundle for access to only one team. These are fans that "do relatively little viewing of any other team."
Dr. Noll relies on the mathematical estimation procedures driving the GMM to help him sort fans into various categories.
Dr. Noll insists that this type of viewing utility is accounted for by a mathematical component built into his model called the "logit error." The term logit error does not connote a mistake; rather, the error is a random component of the model that seeks to capture factors bearing on the utility a fan derives from watching a specific team beyond simply the time spent viewing that team.
Dr. Noll's model yields significantly reduced prices of bundles in the BFW. Specifically, the average monthly price of the MLB.tv package would decrease from $20.05 to $14.50.
Central to evaluating the reliability of those findings are the specific results Dr. Noll's model yields for fans' preferences between a la carte channels and bundles in the BFW. For both the MLB and the NHL, the following pattern holds true. Of the three fan types in Dr. Noll's model, the fans classified as "single-team fans" — the ones primarily interested in watching one and only one team — are the most likely to purchase the league package, and the least likely to purchase an a la carte channel.
Defendants insist that these results are absurd and counterintuitive, signaling that something is amiss about Dr. Noll's model. After all, common sense would suggest that the opposite of Dr. Noll's model should hold true — fans interested primarily in one team would buy an a la carte channel, and fans interested in several teams would buy a bundle. To that end, defendants rely on their own expert, economist Dr. Daniel McFadden, to highlight methodological flaws on the Demand Side.
To illustrate this problem, Dr. McFadden closely examines the process by which Dr. Noll simulates the behavior of consumers. As noted above, only four percent of all World Series watchers — Dr. Noll's assumed upper bound of the market — actually subscribed to an OMP.
As a result, while Dr. Noll is able to match predicted viewing times in the BFW to observed viewing times in the actual world with some precision through the GMM procedure, his model's estimates about viewer preferences are inaccurate.
This simple fitting test reveals major differences between viewers' tastes as defined by the actual, observed data and those predicted by the GMM.
As another example, Dr. McFadden runs a different test to show that Dr. Noll's model underpredicts the popularity of individual RSNs within league bundles across the board. The general pattern is that bundle subscribers "watch a lot more teams," and a "higher share of them watch every team [or] any team" than Dr. Noll's model predicts.
When asked how he would remedy this problem, Dr. McFadden testified that
He added that collecting surveys is "almost a standard in market research where this problem of estimating demand for new product" arises — "something that firms deal with all the time, and there is now a long tradition and a long history of using survey techniques to understand what's going on and [to] make predictions."
According to Dr. McFadden, the dearth of data in Dr. Noll's model culminates in nonsensical results — namely those reported in Table 1 — which are driven by the logit error. Specifically, Dr. McFadden contends that Dr. Noll's use of logit error in his model is "inappropriate" in this circumstance because of what is known as the "red bus/blue bus problem" — a function of the logit error that forces an overprediction of how many consumers will buy standalone RSNs instead of the bundle in the BFW.
Above all else, Dr. McFadden notes that this problem is exacerbated by Dr. Noll's heavy reliance on mathematical assumptions and equations to derive properties of avatars. Dr. McFadden concludes that, "from a scientific point of view," the red bus/blue bus problem shows that the Demand Side of Dr. Noll's model is "very badly specified."
Dr. Noll claims that his model does not suffer from data deficiencies, and moreover, that the seemingly counterintuitive results of his model make economic sense in that they reflect differing price sensitivities among categories of fans. According to Dr. Noll, "the parameters [] estimate[d] produce the result that the multi-team [fans] are the most price sensitive."
Therefore, Dr. Noll insists that his model produces the result that for multi-team fans price sensitivity outweighs preference for diversity.
During Dr. Noll's rebuttal testimony at the Daubert hearing I asked whether, in simply enjoying watching the game of baseball or hockey, multi-team fans would buy a package instead of one or two RSNs, which would heavily restrict the number of teams they could watch on any given day. Dr. Noll asserted that the "coefficient in the regression in the utility function" of his model — part of the logit error — accounts for that possibility.
Dr. Noll also attempts to rebut defendants' more pointed criticisms regarding the data on which he relied, or failed to rely, in designing the Demand Side. Mainly, he insists that it would have been impractical for him to do a survey.
Dr. Noll also attempts to show that Dr. Ariel Pakes, one of defendants' Supply Side experts, relied on similar quantities and types of data in constructing avatars for a 2004 study estimating the demand for automobiles.
Finally, in response to Dr. McFadden's observation that Dr. Noll's model underpredicts the number of channels bundle subscribers view, Dr. Noll insists that the time spent viewing a channel is more important than the number of overall channels a subscriber watches. According to Dr. Noll, "the ability of the model to predict should be evaluated on the basis of the ability to predict viewing time, not [on the basis of] whether a bunch of subscribers [] spent very little time watching that channel."
Calculating damages on the basis of predictions about hypothetical, counterfactual scenarios is not an easy task. Further, estimating damages in antitrust cases is especially challenging because "causes and effects in the realm of economics are not nearly as clear-cut as they are in other disciplines."
There is no question that this task is enormously challenging, even for the most seasoned and distinguished of experts. But it is not impossible — it has been done before in similar circumstances.
Dr. Noll's modeling of demand in the BFW is unreliable because the Demand Side is largely untethered from the actual facts of this case.
For these reasons, I conclude that Dr. Noll's expert opinions on forecasting demand in the BFW must be excluded. And because a structural model is only as reliable as its component parts, Dr. Noll's model cannot be admitted to calculate damages on plaintiffs' theory of overcharge. As explained below, the actual data on which Dr. Noll relies to extrapolate consumer demand in the BFW is simply too sparse to survive defendants' challenge under FRE 702 and Daubert. In the antitrust context, economists are frequently asked to confront problems of extraordinary complexity. In such studies, it is standard operating procedure to rely on more data than Dr. Noll did here in attempting to measure consumer demand in a counterfactual world.
It is easy to detect the symptoms of Dr. Noll's over-reliance on mathematical assumptions, and under-reliance on actual data, in the initial demand curve he derives through the GMM procedure. Dr. Noll's approach to recapturing this demand curve is casual, at best. In fact, his benchmark for estimating demand is essentially a hodgepodge of data sets — varying in their levels of completeness and detail — from MLB Extra Innings, MLB.tv, and NHL GameCenter Live, combined with an assumption about the size of the market for OMPs.
This perfunctory approach impugns the overall reliability of the GMM estimation, on which his entire model is built. For instance, Dr. Noll offers no principled reason, and points to no actual data regarding fan preferences, for his important assumption that the total number of viewers of a sport's championship series should constitute the upper bound of the market for that sport's OMP. He may be right, and this one assumption on its own does not necessarily sink the model, but that is besides the point. For demand to be reliably estimated, Dr. Noll needs a data-driven basis for his underlying assumptions, including those pertaining to the important issue of market shares. If a swath of baseball fans had been surveyed in some form, Dr. Noll might have gained a helpful insight into whether setting the upper bound of the market at the total number of World Series viewers was an appropriate assumption. Such survey data could have corroborated his approach, or it could have caused him to refine it. Either way, without preference data, the reliability of an important assumption driving demand in the BFW remains in question. This type of unsupported assumption is all the more problematic when the actual data sets Dr. Noll relies on are not as robust as they could be. Some of these data sets contain subscriber location; others do not. Some contain information about exactly how much time a fan spent viewing each team; others do not. While Dr. Noll cannot be faulted for not being provided with certain information, in constructing a reliable model, he must do his best to fill the gaps.
Instead, Dr. Noll's lack of reliance on actual data compounds the potentially harmful impact of his unsupported assumptions. Consider Dr. Noll's sorting of consumers into single-team, two-team, and multi-team fans. Dr. Noll categorizes fans through a mathematical estimation procedure tied to viewing time. Acknowledging that fans may not distribute perfectly across these categories on the basis of viewing time alone, Dr. Noll relies on the logit error to provide "a shock that isn't measured by what is already in there."
Worse still, the logit error he relies on to compensate for his lack of preference data is susceptible to reliability issues because of the red bus/blue bus problem. While the Court is not nearly proficient enough in econometrics to evaluate the extent to which the red bus/blue bus problem might throw off Dr. Noll's predictions, this much is clear: if Dr. Noll had leaned more heavily on actual preference data, he could have reduced his reliance on logit error and enhanced the reliability of his model. And, at minimum, he could have tested his model more thoroughly to ensure that the logit error was not muddying his results.
Actual preference data would have enabled Dr. Noll to distribute fans into his three categories, and to evaluate the importance of viewing time as compared to other measures of potential bundle utility, in a much more reliable fashion. To prove that point, the Court need look no further than the questionable, hotly-debated results of his fan sorting experiment. For ease of reference, Chart 1, which illustrates those results, is reprinted below.
The parties thoroughly disagree over the meaning of these results, and the role the logit error plays in driving them. To a layperson — even one who does not watch sports — this distribution of results makes no sense: the more teams a fan is interested in watching, the more likely he would be to buy a package of the telecasts of all teams instead of the telecasts of only one team.
Dr. Noll has an explanation for this. Assuming his model's assumptions about viewing preferences by category are correct, then the model's results are economically sensible in that they are informed by the respective price sensitivities of the categories of fans.
But, as with so many other opinions Dr. Noll offers on the Demand Side, the real world data to support his price-sensitivity conclusion is nowhere to be found in the model. As Dr. McFadden points out, if an expert modeler lacked such information, "it would [be] common procedure [] to collect your own data, do your own survey, find out . . . who's a fan and who is not, and perhaps also find out more about what their tastes are, whether they would consider buying or not at various suggested prices."
By contrast, Dr. Noll's Demand Side model is so far removed from actual viewer preferences and tastes that a finder of fact could only speculate as to the reasons for the model's seemingly nonsensical results. Dr. Noll claims that multi-team fans are more price-sensitive because the "model of their demand behavior . . . kicks out that result."
For instance, with some extra legwork, Dr. Noll might have uncovered data that multi-team fans' supposed price sensitivity would actually tend to drive them out of the market altogether — after all, cable subscribers can watch a local baseball game almost every night during the season without paying extra for an out-of-market option.
Whether any of these possibilities are accurate is irrelevant — what matters is that Dr. Noll's failure to obtain information about consumer tastes and preferences and failure to study baseball and hockey viewing patterns more thoroughly create "too great an analytical gap between the data and the opinion proffered."
Because territorial restraints would no longer exist in the BFW, RSNs would be able to sell their content — in a la carte form — directly to out-of-market consumers. According to Noll, this change would spark a reconfiguration of the overall market for sports broadcasting, leading to greater consumer welfare.
The C&Y Model, as described earlier, is a framework for assessing the result of "unbundling" television distribution — i.e., of moving from (1) a distribution chain in which consumers are required to purchase bundled packages (of television channels) from MVPDs to (2) a distribution chain in which consumers may either purchase bundled packages or purchase a la carte channels. The C&Y Model examined the effects of unbundling on all broadcasting, not just sports broadcasting. They were interested in determining whether consumers would be better off in a world where they could pick and choose among individual networks — The History Channel, and Arts and Entertainment Network, and so on — instead of being forced to purchase a bundled cable package.
The C&Y Model documented two effects of unbundling. First, greater consumer choice, resulting from the existence of a la carte options, spurred competition, and tended to push prices down in the BFW. Second, the Supply Side bargaining that would transpire in response to unbundling introduced new costs into the supply chain, which tended to push prices up in the BFW.
In short, the C&Y Model concluded that the unbundling of television channels had two different effects, pulling in opposite directions, on the market for television distribution. The synthesis of these two effects is to restore consumers to essentially the same position as they were in before unbundling.
The crude way to summarize Dr. Noll's analysis — and the essence of defendants' criticism — is that he adopted the first half of the C&Y Model while ignoring the second. Following the C&Y Model, Dr. Noll posits that the "unbundling" of sports broadcasts — i.e., the availability of a la carte RSNs — would have a downward effect on prices. But from there, Dr. Noll parts ways with the C&Y Model. Dr. Noll's analysis does not include a Supply Side bargaining dynamic that results in MVPDs imposing mark-ups when distributing either a la carte channels or OMPs to consumers. Absent this bargaining dynamic, the second effect documented in the C&Y Model — the increased price of each particular RSN's content — does not occur in Dr. Noll's analysis. Accordingly, unlike in the C&Y Model, whose end result was neutral for consumers, Dr. Noll's analysis shows an obvious benefit to consumers — choices multiply, and prices drop.
Dr. Noll has a rationale for this deviation. According to Dr. Noll, there is no need to model bargaining between RSNs and MVPDs in the BFW, because "internet delivery [of RSN feeds] is a competitive substitute for delivery over an MVPD."
With respect to the bargaining issue, there is a notable mismatch between what Dr. Noll has done and what defendants have accused him of doing. Defendants' experts repeatedly argue that Dr. Noll's analysis ignores bargaining in the BFW.
In addition to the deviation from the C&Y Model, Dr. Noll's analysis also rests on three methodological assumptions — all contested by defendants — that propel the conclusion that consumers will be better off in the BFW. First, Dr. Noll assumes that RSN distribution in the BFW will not be subject to (or subject only to de minimus) "double marginalization," and therefore, that it is unnecessary to account for double marginalization in the projection of BFW prices. Second, Dr. Noll assumes that individual RSNs will pledge their content to the OMP in exchange for one-thirtieth of the overall profit from OMP subscriptions (in baseball) — i.e., Dr. Noll assumes that the RSNs will share in OMP profits equally, such that no individual RSN, regardless of its market power, will be able to negotiate for a higher share of the OMP profits vis-à-vis other RSNs. Third, Dr. Noll assumes that the prices of a la carte channels will be set independently from the price of the OMP, and vice versa. In other words, he assumes that the league and the teams will price their broadcasts competitively — at arm's length — not as a joint venture.
Defendants attack the exclusion of a bargaining dynamic from Dr. Noll's analysis on three grounds. First, defendants argue that bargaining was the "central innovation" of the C&Y Model,
Defendants' first argument is, in essence, an appeal to authority — because C&Y included a bargaining model, Dr. Noll should have as well. But plaintiffs have pointed to numerous reputable papers that use structural models but do not include a bargaining dynamic.
Here, the parties disagree about whether sports broadcasting is such an industry. The details of that disagreement are not material to defendants' Daubert challenge. Plaintiffs argue that "modeling bargaining is not called for where products are relatively similar."
When products are similar, it can be assumed that actors at different levels of a vertical supply-chain (such as RSNs and MVPDs) will negotiate fee-splitting arrangements that replicate acting in concert, which means from the perspective of consumers — and for the purpose of assessing consumer prices — no bargaining model is required. The real issue, then, is not whether it is sometimes permissible to jettison bargaining from a structural model, but rather, whether plaintiffs were right to do so in this case. And that is a question that deserves "[v]igorous cross-examination" at trial.
Defendants' second argument — while more promising — goes to the weight, not the reliability, of Dr. Noll's analysis of the Supply Side. For analytic purposes, Dr. Noll's rationale for jettisoning bargaining can be expressed in conditional form — if (1) the Internet distribution of baseball and hockey broadcasting is a competitive substitute for the television distribution of such broadcasting, then (2) MVPDs will lack bargaining power in the BFW.
Defendants dispute both steps of this logic. First, they argue that Dr. Noll has not proven his factual hypothesis — he has not shown that Internet distribution serves as a competitive substitute for television distribution. Furthermore, even if Dr. Noll has proven his hypothesis prospectively — that plaintiffs are correct that Internet distribution increasingly will serve as a competitive substitute for television distribution — it did not do so during much of the class period.
Second, defendants also take issue with the conclusion of Dr. Noll's argument regarding Internet distribution. Assuming, arguendo, that Internet distribution and television distribution would serve as competitive substitutes from the perspective of consumers, it does not follow, in defendants' view, that MVPDs would lack bargaining power. For support, defendants point to the fact that in the actual world, "the RSNs' [] business model is premised upon negotiating for carriage [of the content they produce] on MVPDs."
This argument is a red herring. The observation that RSNs currently derive much of their business from carriage on MVPDs, though true, sheds no light on the contours of the BFW. In the actual world, RSNs are effectively forced to derive business from carriage on MVPDs. The whole point of plaintiffs' legal theory is that in the BFW, RSNs would have another way of making profits — by selling directly to consumers via the Internet.
If RSNs made a greater share of their profits by selling directly to consumers, it follows logically that they would make a lesser share of their profits from carriage fees. But this observation, on its own, does not help defendants' position. They argue that "MVPDs will not pay [the same] carriage fees" they do in the actual world, if, in the BFW, "consumers can bypass the MVPDs and obtain the same programming [online]."
Finally, defendants argue that Dr. Noll has not justified his threshold assumption that RSNs would exist in the BFW. According to defendants, this is hardly a foregone conclusion, for "it is not clear what role, if any, [RSNs] would have in the BFW given that RSNs are by definition `regional' and fundamentally a byproduct of [territorial restraints]."
The problem with this argument is that the issue of who produces baseball and hockey broadcasts has no bearing on how those broadcasts are priced. When Dr. Noll describes the BFW in narrative form, defendants are correct that he identifies RSNs as the producers of baseball and hockey broadcasts. But Dr. Noll's invocation of RSNs is simply a holdover from the actual world, not an essential feature of his analysis. The point is that whoever produces the broadcasts, Dr. Noll's prediction is that the broadcasts will end up being distributed to consumers at lower prices than in the actual world — i.e., that the supply chain in the BFW, however it is precisely configured, will settle to a competitive, profit-maximizing equilibrium. That prediction may end up being wrong. But if so, it will be wrong for reasons that have nothing to do with what entity — RSNs, other production outfits, or the clubs themselves, producing broadcasts in-house — is responsible for creating content in the BFW. Not surprisingly, defendants have made no effort to connect their observation that clubs could bypass RSNs in the BFW to a claim about prices in the BFW. No such connection exists.
First, defendants fault Dr. Noll for failing to account for the phenomenon of "double marginalization," which, according to defendants, stems from "the fact that independent businesses in vertical supply relationships" — here, RSNs and MVPDs — "each set a price to earn a profit."
Plaintiffs have the better of this argument. Double marginalization refers to the adverse economic consequences that flow from a supply chain in which two monopolists command super-competitive prices in vertical sequence. When this occurs, the result is that prices rise so high, and output diminishes so much, that (1) consumers lose out, but also (2) both monopolists are worse off than they would be if they acted in concert. In this sense, double marginalization is bad for all parties involved — producers as well as consumers — because prices are marked up to super-competitive levels twice over, which causes demand to plummet, curbing overall profit. Accordingly, producers always have an incentive to avoid double marginalization whenever possible.
This observation alone disposes of defendants' argument. Given that producers have a natural incentive to avoid double marginalization whenever possible, the question is whether it is possible, in this particular market, for producers to avoid double marginalization. That is an issue of fact, not one of methodological integrity. As such, it does not support a Daubert challenge. Plaintiffs argue that in the BFW, RSNs and MVPDs would not tolerate any significant amount of double marginalization, and that they would use profit-sharing mechanisms — mechanisms already established in the industry — to circumvent double marginalization.
There is room for reasonable disagreement about which side has the more compelling view of the sports broadcasting industry.
Second, defendants believe Dr. Noll has made the implausible assumption that RSNs would pledge their broadcasts to the OMPs in exchange for one-thirtieth of the OMPs' overall profits (in baseball). According to defendants, more popular clubs — e.g., the Yankees — would have an incentive to demand more than one-thirtieth of the overall share, because their broadcasts are comparatively more valuable than other clubs' broadcasts. In short, why would clubs like the Yankees not simply withdraw from the bundle and sell their content exclusively a la carte?
To this, plaintiffs offer two responses. First, they point out that in the actual world, teams are prohibited — by league rules — from withdrawing from the bundle. In this sense, Dr. Noll is simply making the modest assumption that current league rules would stay intact. Second, plaintiffs argue that even granting defendants' premise — that the league rules could change in the BFW — there is no economic reason to think they would change.
Because plaintiffs' first response disposes of the Daubert question, it is unnecessary to address the second. Regardless of whether Dr. Noll was ultimately right to assume that league rules would stay constant in the BFW, the assumption is not an economic one. Rather, it is a factual assumption about the leagues as institutions. That this assumption has economic implications — potentially quite significant ones — does not change its nature. Assuming that current league rules will stay intact in the BFW is akin to assuming that in the BFW, the baseball season will continue to be one hundred and sixty-two games, or that baseball playoffs will continue to consist of three rounds (rather than — as is the case in hockey — four). In principle, there is nothing stopping the league from modifying the length of the season, or changing the format of playoffs; just as, in principle, there is nothing stopping the league from reforming its rules regarding RSN feeds. To hypothesize that the status quo will persist, however, is not an unreasonable factual assumption, even if it is a factual assumption that ends up being wrong.
The thrust of defendants' argument to the contrary is that economically, there are reasons to think that current league rules will not stay intact in the BFW — because it would be in the interest of many clubs to dissolve the rules and permit deviation from the bundle. Plaintiffs disagree.
In a sense, defendants' argument about league rules falls prey to the same problem as their argument about double marginalization. In each setting, Dr. Noll has made an assumption that, even if it proves unconvincing on the facts, is facially plausible — indeed, a good deal more plausible than the contrary assumption. First, Dr. Noll has assumed that RSNs and MVPDs will take steps to circumvent an outcome — double marginalization — that typically undermines the interests of all actors within the market. Second, Dr. Noll has assumed that current league rules will stay intact. For the reasons just discussed, this position may turn out to be wrong. But it strains credulity to suggest that this assumption is so unreliable as to merit discarding Dr. Noll's Supply Side analysis.
Third, and finally, defendants argue that Dr. Noll erred in assuming that in the BFW (1) the price of the OMPs and (2) the prices of a la carte channels would be set competitively — as though the league and its clubs operate at arm's length. According to defendants, the more accurate model of the leagues and its clubs would be that of a joint venture. If so, the proper framework for predicting prices would be a "multi-product pricing" model — a framework whose economic viability is "uncontested," and whose application "would result in higher prices for the two products" at issue here, the OMPs and the a la carte channels.
Plaintiffs' response is simple. If the league and the clubs were to set prices as a joint venture, according to a "multi-product pricing" model, that itself would be collusive. Put simply, the reason Dr. Noll assumed that prices would be set competitively in the BFW is that to assume otherwise would be, in effect, to allow "the leagues [to] replace the current anticompetitive prices (and inflated prices) with other anticompetitive prices in the BFW."
In response, defendants argue that Dr. Noll has overlooked the fact that in the BFW, each club would "have a unilateral incentive to take into account the effect on the related party" — i.e., the league — "when setting price[s]."
Dr. Noll decided that analyzing BFW prices this way would violate "legitimate" principles of economic modeling — in essence, because he thought it would reflect collusion. Defendants respond that Dr. Noll is wrong on the law; that in fact, multi-product pricing would occur in the BFW "without [] collusion."
The final question is whether the Supply Side analysis can be analytically severed from Dr. Noll's damages model. The answer is yes. Because the damages model lacks a solid foundation in existing data, it does not reliably demonstrate whether, and how much, class members were overcharged for OMPs. But nothing about that defect spills over to Dr. Noll's Supply Side analysis. The shortcoming of Dr. Noll's Demand Side analysis — and the unreliability of his damage calculations — holds true whether or not the Supply Side is properly configured. The admissibility of Dr. Noll's Supply Side analysis stands (or falls) on its own.
For the reasons set forth above, I conclude that Dr. Noll's Supply Side analysis, extracted from the damages model, survives scrutiny under Rule 702. Some or all of Dr. Noll's assumptions about the Supply Side may end up being unconvincing — which would weaken plaintiffs' case on the merits. But that issue must be resolved by a fact-finder. It would be inappropriate for the Court to exclude Dr. Noll's Supply Side analysis at this stage.
For the reasons set forth above, defendants' motion to exclude the opinions and testimony of Dr. Roger Noll is GRANTED in part and DENIED in part. The Clerk of the Court is directed to close this motion, Dkt. No. 277 in 12 Civ. 1817, and Dkt. No. 354 in 12 Civ. 3704.
SO ORDERED.