THOMAS, Chief Judge:
Petitioners, the people of the state of California through their Attorney General Kamala D. Harris, the California Public Utilities Commission, Pacific Gas & Electric Company, and Southern California Edison ("the California Parties"), seek review of a series of orders issued by the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission ("FERC" or "the Commission") on remand following our decision in California ex rel. Lockyer v. FERC ("Lockyer"), 383 F.3d 1006 (9th Cir.2004). There, we held that FERC may authorize market-based energy tariffs, so long as that regulatory framework incorporates both an ex ante market power analysis and enforceable post-approval transaction reporting. Id. at 1014. We remanded the case because FERC had not appropriately implemented the market-based tariff. Id. at 1015.
In this case, the California Parties petition for review of FERC's actions after our remand, claiming that FERC failed to follow Lockyer and violated the Federal Power Act ("FPA") by requiring proof of excessive market share as a necessary condition for relief for transaction reporting violations.
We conclude that FERC structured the remand proceedings in a manner contrary to the terms of our Lockyer decision. Enforceable transaction reporting is a necessary ingredient of a lawful market-based tariff. Id. By insisting on proof of market
The essence of the California Parties' complaint is presented in some detail at the outset of our Lockyer decision. See 383 F.3d at 1008-11. A summary of our Lockyer decision and an exposition of events that transpired before FERC on remand follows.
In Lockyer, we denied the California Parties' facial challenge to market-based ratemaking. Id. at 1013. We held that the agency's segmented approach, which requires an ex ante finding of an absence of market power coupled with regular transaction reports, does not per se violate the FPA. Id. at 1012-13. However, we granted the California Parties' as-applied challenge, holding that FERC's enforcement and review of market-based rates during the 2000-01 California energy crisis was unlawful. Id. at 1014. We held that FERC abdicated its regulatory responsibility by summarily dismissing electricity wholesalers' failure to comply with reporting requirements. Id. at 1014-15. "[B]ecause the reporting requirements [are] an integral part of a market-based tariff that... pass[es] legal muster, FERC cannot dismiss the requirements as mere punctilio." Id. at 1015. We remanded to FERC to reconsider the California Parties' claim for a refund of the amount sellers charged in excess of just and reasonable rates during the crisis. Id. at 1018.
On remand, FERC ordered
California ex rel. Lockyer v. B.C. Power Exch. Corp.
The California Parties urged FERC to reconsider its definition of the objective of the ALJ proceeding, claiming that the Commission's decision to focus on identifying sellers' market power based on market share levels stood contrary to the FPA, our remand instructions in Lockyer, and agency precedent. See Oct. 6, 2008 Order, 125 FERC ¶ 61,016, 61,040. The state claimed that FERC's initial order on remand unjustifiably collapsed the two-tiered approach approved in Lockyer by conflating the ex ante market power determination and the ex post reporting requirement. Id. It identified FERC decisions holding that the purpose of market-based rate quarterly transaction reporting is to meet the filed rate requirements of the FPA, evaluate the reasonableness of rates, and monitor sellers' market power on an ongoing basis. Id. Furthermore, the California Parties argued that the hub-and-spoke test prescribed by the agency was an inadequate screen for market power. Id.
FERC denied rehearing. Id. The Commission declared the state's claims an impermissible collateral attack on the market power analysis FERC used at the time of the transactions and explained that the purpose of market-based quarterly reports "is not to re-run the Commission's market power screens, but rather ... to monitor and evaluate market concentration on an ongoing basis." Id. at 61,040-41. FERC rejected the state's suggestion that the hub-and-spoke test was an inappropriate screen for market power, claiming that it must use only those standards in effect at the time of the reviewed transactions. Id. at 61,041-42.
The California Parties also argued that FERC erred in its March 21, 2008 Order by excluding evidence of other tariff violations and market manipulation from the ALJ proceeding. Id. at 61,042. The California Parties sought to introduce evidence of alternative analyses of market power and market function, based on information presented in sellers' reports, to show a nexus between deficient reporting, market function, and market power. Id. FERC denied rehearing on this issue because other potential seller misconduct, such as gaming and anomalous bidding, was the subject of another proceeding before the agency, which it determined should remain distinct and separate. Id.
Shortly thereafter, the California Parties again requested rehearing regarding the evidentiary basis for its reporting allegations. Dec. 28, 2009 Order, 129 FERC ¶ 61,276, 62,530. The California Parties again sought to introduce evidence of market manipulation and tariff violations, explaining that these concerns were not adequately addressed by other proceedings before FERC. Id. FERC denied the request as an impermissible request for rehearing of an order denying rehearing. Id. The Commission also reasoned that the California Parties' argument about the scope of evidence in the remand proceeding was incongruous with evidence of deficient reporting presented in the original complaint. Id. at 62,531. The Commission definitively limited the allegations to be considered in the ALJ proceedings to the California Parties' reporting and hub-and-spoke market power claims, not allegations of market manipulation or other measures of market power. Id.
After briefing and submission of written testimony, but without hearing argument, the ALJ granted sellers' motions for summary disposition in an Initial Decision issued March 18, 2010. 130 FERC ¶ 63,017, 66,159-62. After crediting the California Parties' evidence of reporting violations, the ALJ ruled in the sellers' favor because the state did not demonstrate that sellers accumulated market power under the hub-and-spoke test. Id. at 66,162. The ALJ reasoned that "[a]bsent a showing by the California Parties in their direct testimony that each [seller] possessed generation market power under the Commission's hub-and-spoke test, no material factual issues remain for hearing on the central issue in this proceeding." Id. at 66,195. The ALJ set aside the California Parties' seller misconduct and alternative market power analyses as outside the scope of the proceeding and contrary to sellers' due process right to notice. Id. at 66,194.
In a May 4, 2011 Order, the Commission affirmed the ALJ decision. 135 FERC ¶ 61,113. The Commission rested on its previous rulings on the California Parties' exceptions and objections. Id. at 61,655-56. FERC reasoned, "[g]iven that the issue of whether suppliers accumulated market power was the threshold issue in this proceeding, and given the California Parties' failure to offer any evidence to demonstrate the accumulation of market power under the hub-and-spoke standard, summary disposition was appropriate." Id. at 61,655. The Commission later denied the California Parties' request for rehearing. June 13, 2012 Order, 139 FERC ¶ 61,211. This petition followed shortly thereafter.
We have jurisdiction to hear this petition for judicial review pursuant to § 313(b) of the FPA. 16 U.S.C. § 825l(b). The California Parties timely filed this petition on June 20, 2012. See id. "Upon the filing of such petition such court shall have jurisdiction, which upon the filing of the record with it shall be exclusive, to affirm, modify, or set aside such order in whole or in part." Id.
We review FERC decisions to determine whether they are "arbitrary, capricious, an abuse of discretion, unsupported by substantial evidence, or not in accordance with the law." Cal. Dep't of Water Res. v. FERC, 341 F.3d 906, 910 (9th Cir.2003). "The finding of the Commission as to the facts, if supported by substantial evidence, shall be conclusive." 16 U.S.C. § 825l(b). Questions of law are subject to de novo review. Am. Rivers v. FERC, 201 F.3d 1186, 1194 (9th Cir.1999). FERC's interpretation of the FPA is reviewed under the deferential framework in Chevron U.S.A. Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc., 467 U.S. 837, 842, 104 S.Ct. 2778, 81 L.Ed.2d 694 (1984). Port of Seattle, Wash. v. FERC, 499 F.3d 1016, 1026 (9th Cir.2007). However, "Chevron does not require blind deference; the Supreme Court has articulated a more thorough and nuanced approach." Lockyer, 383 F.3d at 1016. When considering "whether Congress has directly spoken to the precise question at issue," Chevron, 467 U.S. at 842, 104 S.Ct. 2778, this court is guided by statutory context and "common sense as to the manner in which Congress is likely to delegate a policy decision." Lockyer, 383 F.3d at 1016-17 (citation and internal quotation marks omitted).
Adjudication of the petition turns on interpretation of § 205 of the FPA, which commands that "any ... rate or charge that is not just and reasonable is hereby declared to be unlawful." 16 U.S.C. § 824d(a). Although "[o]ur role in determining
FERC held that the California Parties' "failure to offer any evidence to demonstrate the accumulation of market power under the hub-and-spoke standard" foreclosed relief. May 4, 2011 Order, 135 FERC ¶ 61,113, 61,655. By granting summary disposition to the sellers, the Commission denied the California Parties' claims that reporting deficiencies violated the FPA and justified refunds of amounts sellers charged in excess of the just and reasonable rates. By structuring the remand proceedings in this manner, predicating the "just and reasonable" inquiry required under § 205 on accumulation of market power under the hub-and-spoke test, FERC insulated sellers from liability for reporting violations and thereby ran afoul of the FPA. FERC casts market power identified solely through excessive market share as a necessary condition to conclude that a seller's rate is unjust or unreasonable. This view undercuts the essential importance of transaction reporting and the distinct purpose of each prong of a viable market-based tariff system. In Lockyer, when we deemed FERC's market-based ratemaking approach a viable extension of the agency's authority under the FPA, we went to great lengths to distinguish market-based regulatory schemes rejected by the Supreme Court in MCI Telecommunications Corp. v. AT & T, 512 U.S. 218, 114 S.Ct. 2223, 129 L.Ed.2d 182 (1994), and Maislin Industries U.S., Inc. v. Primary Steel, Inc., 497 U.S. 116, 110 S.Ct. 2759, 111 L.Ed.2d 94 (1990). See Lockyer, 383 F.3d at 1013. "The structure of the tariff complied with the FPA, so long as it was coupled with enforceable post-approval reporting that would enable FERC to determine whether the rates were `just and reasonable' and whether market forces were truly determining the price." Id. at 1014. "[T]he crucial difference between MCI/Maislin and the present circumstances is the dual requirement of an ex ante finding of the absence of market power and sufficient post-approval reporting requirements." Id. at 1013 (emphasis in original).
Our discussion of the California Parties' as-applied challenge in Lockyer underscores the independence and import of each prong of the analysis. In testing FERC's claim that reporting violations were mere compliance issues, we observed that each prong of the framework serves a different purpose. Enforceable post-approval reporting is necessary to enable FERC to determine whether sellers' rates complied with § 205 and to investigate whether market forces truly determined the rate charged. Id. at 1014. Without "active ongoing review" brought about by an enforceable transaction reporting requirement, "the only arguably serious regulatory screening that exists is FERC's initial determination with respect to a seller's market power — a determination that may bear little or no relation to the realities
FERC erred by structuring the remand proceedings to focus exclusively on market-share evidence of market power. By doing so, FERC unlawfully administered the market-based tariff. "If the ability to monitor the market, or gauge the `just and reasonable' nature of the rates is eliminated, then effective federal regulation is removed altogether. Without the required filings, neither FERC nor any affected party may challenge the rate. Pragmatically, under such circumstances, there is no filed tariff in place at all." Id. at 1015-16.
In addition to ignoring our remand instructions, FERC's interpretation is at odds with the position it took in the initial appeal. There, "FERC ... affirmed ... that it is not contending that approval of a market-based tariff based on market forces alone would comply with the FPA or the filed rate doctrine." Id. at 1013. FERC argued that the presence of reporting requirements differentiated its market-based tariffs from those rejected by the Court in MCI and Maislin, and this court agreed. Id. In fact, even before Lockyer, in its initial order on the complaint FERC stated that "[a]fter-the-fact quarterly reports provide a means for spotting price trends, discriminatory patterns, or other indicia of the exercise of market power." May 31, 2002 Order, 99 FERC ¶ 61,247, 62,063. As we said once before, "FERC cannot have it both ways." Lockyer, 383 F.3d at 1016. "If the tariff is interpreted as FERC urges here, then the tariff runs afoul of Maislin, the filed rate doctrine, and the FPA." Id.
FERC argues that the reasonableness of market-based rates charged by sellers without market power, as measured by market share, cannot be challenged. It therefore claims that following an alleged reporting violation, analysis of a seller's market share alone is sufficient. For this proposition the Commission cites a paragraph in Lockyer that describes two D.C. Circuit decisions approving market-based ratemaking in the market for natural gas and wholesale electricity. See id. at 1012-13. However, FERC takes that passage out of context. Those cases involve a traditional bilateral transaction, that is, a bargained-for exchange between an interested buyer and willing seller. Id. That is not directly analogous to the factual circumstances here involving clearinghouse sales during the energy crisis. See id. at 1008-10.
FERC also cites Blumenthal v. FERC, 552 F.3d 875, 882 (D.C.Cir.2009), but makes no effort to explain its relevance to its claim that the rate charged by sellers without hub-and-spoke market power is per se "just and reasonable." Blumenthal concerns a different factual circumstance: Connecticut's challenge to FERC's approval of a "`hybrid' market, in which some electricity generators sell power at regulated rates and others at market rates." Id. at 878. Even so, the D.C. Circuit relied on FERC's requirement of "quarterly and annual reports assessing the competitiveness of the market based on transactional data reflecting the behavior of each market participant." Id. at 882. The court explained that its holding approving of the "hybrid" market structure comports with Lockyer by requiring "[r]egular reports based on `transaction-specific data[.]'" Id. "FERC violates its oversight duty when it imposes no reporting requirements
The record on remand demonstrates that FERC did not "examine the relevant data and articulate a satisfactory explanation for its action" and thereby did not meet its burden to engage in reasoned decisionmaking. Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Ass'n v. State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co., 463 U.S. 29, 43, 103 S.Ct. 2856, 77 L.Ed.2d 443 (1983). The manner in which FERC structured the proceedings on remand is arbitrary, capricious, and otherwise not in accordance with law. The agency collapsed a lawful two-step market-based tariff to an impermissible one-step inquiry focused solely on whether a seller controlled 20 percent of the generation market in its hub-and-spoke area. FERC may not limit its review of the reporting deficiencies to the hub-and-spoke market power screen. To fully consider whether a reported rate was just and reasonable, the agency must consider claims and evidence beyond the hub-and-spoke analysis.
FERC attempts to justify its position by claiming that the California Parties' claims have been addressed in other proceedings. For example, FERC stated that "this proceeding focuses solely on violations of our quarterly transaction reports as a basis for potential refund liability ... this is not a proceeding to address other potential tariff violations (such as gaming and anomalous bidding behavior), which is the subject of the CPUC proceeding."
An agency errs when it "entirely fail[s] to consider an important aspect of the problem." Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Ass'n, 463 U.S. at 43, 103 S.Ct. 2856. FERC framed the issue in this appeal as whether deficient reporting masked an accumulation of market power such that the market rates charged were unjust and unreasonable. By requiring the California Parties to demonstrate that a seller exercised market power solely by reference to the hub-and-spoke test, FERC ignored other important aspects of the problem of market power masked by deficient reporting. This is so regardless of the Commission's consideration of manipulation claims in CPUC. FERC entered a final order authorizing refunds for manipulative tariff violations in the CPUC remand proceedings on November
Whether the California Parties' claims have been resolved in other proceedings is also a merits question that must be resolved by the agency. The Commission has recognized its capacity to "be cognizant of the factual scope of each proceeding and the ramifications of [its] actions here on other, related proceedings." Oct. 6, 2008 Order, 125 FERC ¶ 61,016, 61,042. That awareness does not translate into authority to sidestep due process and reasoned analysis for claims the agency believes have been litigated and decided in other proceedings. Obviously, parties are not entitled to double recovery, but that is an analysis that the agency can undertake on remand. This opinion does not address the question of potential refunds from sellers who were not themselves responsible for any manipulation that FERC may determine occurred, but who may have benefitted from it. This issue is appropriately within FERC's province in the first instance.
In summary, FERC's response to Lockyer, that refunds are unavailable because no seller exercised market power under the hub-and-spoke test, falls short. When we approved market-based ratemaking in Lockyer we repeatedly emphasized the importance of "the dual requirement of an ex ante finding of the absence of market power and sufficient post-approval reporting requirements." Lockyer, 383 F.3d at 1013. After FERC dismissed sellers' widespread reporting deficiencies as a mere compliance issue, we granted the state's petition for judicial review and remanded this case to correct the oversight. On remand,
We therefore remand to the agency once again for adjudication of the complaint in a manner that respects the Lockyer mandate and the FPA. To remedy reporting violations, FERC must review the transaction reports to determine whether a just and reasonable price was charged by each seller, with specific attention to whether reporting deficiencies masked manipulation or accumulation of market power. If so, FERC may then elect to exercise its remedial discretion as appropriate. "The FPA cannot be construed to immunize those who overcharge and manipulate markets in violation of the FPA." Id. at 1017.