NAOMI REICE BUCHWALD, District Judge.
This appeal arises from the insolvency proceedings of Lehman Brothers Holdings Inc. and its subsidiaries (collectively, "Lehman").
Long before Lehman filed for bankruptcy, plaintiff-appellant FirstBank Puerto Rico ("FirstBank") gave bonds to a Lehman entity as collateral for derivative transactions between FirstBank and Lehman. FirstBank's contract gave that counterparty license to sell those bonds free of FirstBank's interest. Once FirstBank's counterparty took advantage of that provision and sold all of FirstBank's collateral (as it happened, to a different Lehman entity), FirstBank retained nothing more than a contractual claim against its counterparty for return of the bonds at a later date. FirstBank, then, has no right to re-claim the collateral from the collateral's subsequent purchaser, Barclays Capital Inc. ("Barclays"), which bought the collateral at a bankruptcy sale. Therefore, we affirm the judgment of the United States Bankruptcy Court for the Southern District of New York (the "Bankruptcy Court") granting summary judgment to Barclays.
At the time of the bankruptcy sale, the Bankruptcy Court enjoined suits against Barclays related to assets that Barclays purchased from Lehman in bankruptcy. Because the Bankruptcy Court did not
Because this appeal requires us to discuss sophisticated transactions among the parties and various Lehman entities, we offer an overview of the securities, derivatives, and financing tools involved in this case.
A swap is, generically, an over-the-counter transaction in which two parties agree to exchange the returns of two cash flows.
Perhaps the most simple example is an interest-rate swap.
An interest-rate swap allows a party to gain or reduce exposure to interest rates. See id. at 1445. For example, suppose that a bank has loaned money to its customers at fixed interest rates, but that the bank borrows money at short-term rates that fluctuate. Then the bank faces a risk that its own borrowing costs will increase from rising interest rates, while the bank's income, from its fixed-rate loans, will remain constant. In such a circumstance, the bank can avoid this risk by entering into an interest rate swap with a swap dealer. The bank will deliver fixed payments to the dealer, and will receive floating payments in return. This effectively allows the bank to convert its fixed income into an income stream whose fluctuations will match the bank's borrowing costs.
Because swaps are traded directly between counterparties (rather than through an exchange), each party faces the risk that the other party will be unable to pay its net losses under the swap agreement. See id. at 1446-47, 1474-75; Christian J. Johnson, Derivatives & Rehypothecation Failure: It's 3:00 P.M., Do You Know Where Your Collateral Is?, 39 Ariz. L.Rev. 949, 958-59 (Fall 1997). Turning back to the example of an interest-rate swap, suppose prevailing interest rates fall, so that the bank (as the payer of a fixed rate and receiver of a floating rate) will expect to owe the swap dealer payments throughout the term of the swap. Until the bank successfully makes each payment, the swap dealer faces the risk that the bank will become unable to pay. Conversely, if prevailing interest rates rise, then the swap dealer will expect to owe the bank payments throughout the term of the
One partial solution to this credit risk is for one party (called the "pledgor") to give the other party (the "secured party") safe assets to hold as collateral. The pledgor retains the economic interest in its collateral. That is, when the pledged bonds pay interest, the secured party must deliver the interest to the pledgor, and the pledgor may re-claim and sell the pledged bonds upon proper notice (although the pledgor must then post other acceptable collateral in its place). See Jon Gregory, Counterparty Credit Risk 70-71 (2010).
Frequently, the swap parties will agree that, at certain intervals, the party with a net unrealized loss will deliver collateral to cover the unrealized loss. See id. at 60. If collateral is exchanged frequently enough, this exchange will prevent either side's counterparty credit exposure from becoming intolerably great.
The swap parties may also agree that one party (typically the party with weaker credit) will post some amount of collateral for each swap, called an "independent amount" or "initial margin," regardless of profit or loss on the swap. This decreases the secured party's risk; if the pledgor defaults before the pledgor has an opportunity to post collateral against a sudden loss, the secured party will (it hopes) have enough initial margin to cover the pledgor's loss. See id. at 67. Conversely, the use of initial margin increases the pledgor's counterparty risk; if the secured party defaults, then the pledgor will not be able to offset the loss of its initial margin against any payments owed to the secured party.
A swap dealer does not re-negotiate the terms of its relationship with a customer each time the customer executes a swap. Instead, a customer negotiates a single master agreement with a swap dealer, usually based on standard agreements published by the International Swaps and Derivatives Association, Inc. (ISDA). This master agreement will include terms regarding the overall credit relationship between the parties — representations and warranties, events of default, termination procedures, procedures for offsetting debts between different trades, and so forth. Once a master agreement is in place, each trade requires only a short confirmation to record essential details of the particular transaction, such as the notional principal, the fixed rate, the definition of the floating rate, and the term of the swap. See generally Harding, supra, at 9-16; Johnson, supra, at 957-58.
The standard ISDA Agreements do not govern the exchange of collateral. Instead, parties who wish to collateralize their swap agreement will agree to collateralization terms in a separate document, such as a "Credit Support Annex" or a "Credit Support Deed."
In particular, some credit support documents allow the secured party to use or dispose of the collateral. This is known as rehypothecation. See generally Johnson, supra, passim.
Just as the pledgor retains the economic interest in bonds that are posted as collateral, see supra at 484-85, the pledgor continues to retain that economic interest after the secured party has rehypothecated the bonds. This is because the secured party must still deliver any interest payments to the pledgor as though the secured party still held the collateral, and the pledgor may still re-claim and sell the pledged bonds upon proper notice. See Paul C. Harding & Christian A. Johnson,
The main advantage of rehypothecation is to allow the secured party to finance its own operations; in exchange, the secured party offers the pledgor cheaper funding, or, at the margin, the secured party offers a swap line to a customer who would not otherwise qualify. Before 2007, at least some commentators believed that rehypothecation was "critical to the entire financial system." Gregory, supra, at 71 (citing M. Segoviano Basurto & M. Singh, Counterparty Risk in the Over-the-counter Derivatives Market 1-19, IMF Working Papers (2008), available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1316726).
The main disadvantage (at least to the pledgor) is that, as in this case, "the secured party could become insolvent and therefore be unable to return the posted collateral...." Harding & Johnson, supra, at 66. This risk is especially great when the pledgor has posted collateral whose value exceeds the pledgor's unrealized losses (for example, when the pledgor posts an "independent amount"), because then the pledgor cannot set off the whole value of its collateral against its own unrealized losses. See id. at 67; ISDA, Independent Amounts 6-7 (release 2.0, Mar. 1, 2010), available at http://www2.isda.org/attachment/MTY3MA==/Independent-Amount-WhitePaper-Final.pdf. Because of this risk to the pledgor, "[r]ehypothecation rights are often heavily negotiated." Harding & Johnson, supra, at 279; cf. Credit Support Annex between FirstBank and Bank of Montreal, Mar. 15, 2004, J.A. 1810-27 at ¶ 13(g)(ii) (forbidding rehypothecation).
A repurchase agreement (or repo) is, legally, a pair of bond sales: A seller sells a bond to a buyer, and the parties agree that the buyer will re-sell the bond back to the seller at a later date for a slightly higher price.
Although a repo is structured as a pair of sales, the economic substance is that the "seller" borrows money from the "buyer" and provides the bond as collateral. See Fabozzi & Mann, Financing Positions, supra, at 1357. A repo resembles a secured loan in that the borrower (or seller and repurchaser) retains the economic interest in the bonds. When the bonds pay interest, the lender of cash must deliver the interest to the borrower. See Frank J. Fabozzi & Steven V. Mann, Repurchase & Reverse Repurchase Agreements, in Securities Finance: Securities Lending & Repurchase Agreements 221, 237 (Frank J. Fabozzi & Steven V. Mann eds. 2005) (contrasting a repo to a "buy/sell back" transaction, in which the lender of cash obtains beneficial ownership of the bond).
The most important use of a repo is to secure financing. Suppose a bullish trader wants to have economic exposure to $300 of bonds, but has only $100 of cash. See Fabozzi & Mann, Financing Positions, supra, at 1356. The trader can accomplish this by combining two transactions: (1) an
A trader might also wish to lend cash and borrow bonds. See id. at 1357. Suppose a bearish trader wants to have negative or short exposure to $100 of bonds. The trader can accomplish this by combining two transactions: (1) an outright sale of $100 in bonds to a bond dealer, and (2) a repo in which the trader lends $100 to a repo dealer, takes $100 of bonds, and commits to resell the bonds in the future. After these transactions, the trader has negative economic exposure to the $100 in bonds that the trader has committed to resell to the repo dealer at a fixed price.
As with swaps, traders do not re-negotiate their legal relationship for each new repo. Instead, a single master agreement (usually the Bond Market Association's Master Repurchase Agreement) governs the terms of repo trading, and short trade confirmations to document the details of each trade. See Fabozzi & Mann, Repurchase and Reverse Repurchase Agreements, supra at 225-26.
In 1997, FirstBank and Lehman Brothers Special Financing Inc.
FirstBank was required to post significant amounts of collateral to Lehman Swaps before FirstBank ever incurred losses on its swaps. The Credit Support Annex defined FirstBank's "Credit Support Amount" (or the amount of collateral that FirstBank was required to post) to be no less than the sum of all "Independent Amounts" applicable to FirstBank. See CSA ¶ 13(b)(i)(C)(x). These "Independent Amounts" were defined as 1% of the notional principal of each swap transaction, see J.A. 1374-78 ("Statement of Sept. 1, 2008") at 4-5.
The Swap Agreement itself allowed FirstBank to hold Lehman Swaps in default upon the occurrence of any of several events, including a voluntary bankruptcy filing of Lehman Swaps or Lehman Holdings and a failure to make any required payments. See Swap Agr. ¶¶ 5(a)(I), (vii)(4), 6(a); Swap Agr., Sched., pt. 4, ¶ (g) (listing Lehman Holdings as a "Credit Support Provider," whose bankruptcy was to constitute a default event). Upon proper notice of early termination following a default, Lehman Swaps was no longer allowed to rehypothecate FirstBank's collateral, and was required to return all collateral immediately to FirstBank. See CSA ¶¶ 6(c), 8(b)(iii). If Lehman Swaps failed to return FirstBank's collateral, then FirstBank was entitled to set off the value of the collateral against any losses that FirstBank owed Lehman Swaps on the underlying swaps. See CSA ¶ 8(b)(iv).
Over time, FirstBank traded dozens of interest-rate swaps with Lehman Swaps. Stip. of Facts ¶ 5. To support this trading, FirstBank provided Lehman Swaps with investment-grade bonds issued by the Federal National Mortgage Association and the Government National Mortgage Association (the "Posted Bonds" or the "Posted Collateral"). See Stip. of Facts ¶ 8. Lehman Brokerage took possession as Lehman Swaps' agent. See Stip. of Facts ¶ 10.
Between February and September 2008 (but before the bankruptcy of any Lehman entity), Lehman Swaps sold some of the Posted Bonds to Lehman Brokerage in a series of repos (the "Intra-Lehman Repos"). See Stip. of Facts ¶ 12. As the Posted Bonds had previously been held by Lehman Brokerage as agent for Lehman Swaps, employees of Lehman Brokerage acted on both sides of this transaction. See Stip. of Facts ¶ 13. Lehman Swaps received approximately $51.9 million cash in exchange for approximately $53.4 million of the Posted Bonds (the "Bonds" or "Collateral").
On Monday, September 15, 2008, Lehman Holdings voluntarily petitioned for bankruptcy. See Stip. of Facts ¶ 17; Voluntary Petition, In re Lehman Bros. Holdings Inc., No. 08-13555, 2008 WL 4200597 (Bankr.S.D.N.Y. Sept. 15, 2008), ECF No. 1. At various times from that Monday
The Federal Reserve un-wound these repos on Thursday, September 18, in anticipation that Barclays would take the Federal Reserve's place supplying emergency liquidity to Lehman. See Stip. of Facts ¶ 19. Simultaneously, Lehman Brokerage sold the Bonds to Barclays as part of a repo (the "Barclays Repo") to replace the Federal Reserve's repo. See Stip. of Facts ¶ 20.
On Friday, September 19, the Bankruptcy Court held a hearing (the "Sale Order Hearing") to review a proposed Asset Purchase Agreement (J.A. 1475-1523 ("APA")) and Sale Motion. See Tr., In re Lehman Bros. Holding Co., No. 08-13555 (Bankr. S.D.N.Y. Sept. 19, 2008), ECF No. 318 ("Sale Order Hr'g Tr."). Barclays agreed to purchase certain "Purchased Assets," see APA § 2.1, including, with exceptions, all assets "used in connection with" the "U.S. and Canadian investment banking and capital markets businesses of [LBHI and LBI]." APA § 1.1. These assets included Lehman Brokerage's "Long Positions," meaning "government securities... and collateralized short-term agreements with a book value as of the date hereof of approximately $70 billion." APA § 1.1, definition of "Purchased Assets," clause (d). Barclays also assumed many of Lehman Holdings' and Lehman Brokerage's liabilities, including "`repos' relating to any securities or interests of the type included in the definition of `Long Positions.'" APA § 2.3(i).
Following the Sale Order Hearing, the Bankruptcy Court issued a Sale Order to approve the purchase. See Order Authorizing and Approving (A) the Sale of Purchased Assets Free and Clear of Liens and Other Interests and (B) Assumption and Assignment of Executory Contracts and Unexpired Leases, In re Lehman Bros. Holding Inc., No. 08-13555 (Bankr. S.D.N.Y. Sept. 19, 2008), ECF No. 258, J.A. 1332-55 ("Sale Order"). In this order, the approved "Purchase Agreement" was defined to include both the APA that was before the Bankruptcy Court at the Sale Order Hearing and a forthcoming letter to clarify and supplement the APA (later known as the "Clarification Letter"). See Sale Order at 1. Further amendments were also permitted without court order, so long as any such amendment did not have a material adverse effect on the Lehman debtors' estates. See Sale Order at 21. The Sale Order enjoined all persons from pursuing claims to the Purchased Assets against Barclays; instead, those with claims to the Purchased Assets could make their claims against the money that Barclays paid Lehman. See Sale Order at 14. The Sale Order also recited a finding that notice was sufficient under the circumstances to satisfy due process. See Sale Order at 2-3.
On Monday, September 22, Lehman and Barclays publicized the Clarification Letter that the Sale Order had referred to. See Notice of Filing of Purchase Agreement, In re Lehman Bros. Holding Inc., No. 08-13555 (Bankr.S.D.N.Y. Sept. 22, 2008), ECF No. 280 Ex. C, J.A. 1528-43 ("Clar. Letter"). The Clarification Letter stated that "all securities and other assets held by [Barclays] under the [Barclays Repo] shall be deemed to constitute part of the Purchased Assets," that Barclays and Lehman "shall be deemed to have no further obligations to each other under the
Lehman Holdings' bankruptcy petition constituted an "Event of Default" under FirstBank's Swap Agreement. See Swap Agr. ¶ 5(a)(vii)(4). Additionally, Lehman Swaps failed to make a required payment on Monday, September 15, constituting another Event of Default. See Swap Agr. ¶ 5(a)(i); Stip. of Facts ¶ 32.
FirstBank was not served with notice of the bankruptcy sale and did not participate in the proceedings leading up to the sale. See Aff. of Service, Exs. A, B, In re Lehman Bros. Holdings Inc., No. 08-13555 (Bankr.S.D.N.Y. Sept. 17, 2008), ECF No. 79 (service lists for Sale Motion); Notice of Hr'g, In re Lehman Bros. Holdings, No. 08-13555 (Bankr.S.D.N.Y. Sept. 18, 2008), ECF No. 108 (announcing Sale Order Hearing to all appearing parties through ECF); Sale Order Hr'g Tr. 3-40 (list of appearances at Sale Order Hearing); cf. Limited Obj'n, Lehman Bros. Holdings (Nov. 28, 2008) (first appearance of FirstBank).
FirstBank did, of course, have notice that its own counterparty, Lehman Swaps, had failed to make a required payment on September 15, 2008. Accordingly, FirstBank issued a valid Notice of Termination on or about September 24, 2008 (after Lehman Brokerage's bankruptcy sale, but before Lehman Swaps entered bankruptcy). See Stip. of Facts ¶¶ 26, 32, 33. Contrary to the requirements of the Credit Support Annex, Lehman Swaps did not return the Collateral to FirstBank after this termination. This was an obvious breach of the Credit Support Annex. See CSA ¶ 8(b)(3).
In response to Lehman Swaps' failure to return the Collateral, FirstBank offset a small portion of the unreturned Collateral by declining to pay approximately $2.6 million that FirstBank apparently owed Lehman Swaps as of the swaps' termination date.
At some point in the summer of 2009, FirstBank learned from JPMorgan Chase (the custodian of the account in which Lehman Brokerage had held the Bonds on behalf of Lehman Swaps) that at least some of the Bonds had been transferred to Barclays. See Rule 30(b)(6) Dep. of Victor Barreras for FirstBank at 40:23-42:8, Mar. 27, 2012, J.A. 3290-3365 ("Barreras Dep."). Following that discovery, FirstBank demanded that Barclays reveal whether Barclays held the Bonds, and that Barclays return the Bonds. See Letter, Sept. 17, 2009, J.A. 1359-61.
On December 21, 2009, FirstBank sued Barclays,
The District Court granted in part and denied in part Barclays's motion to dismiss. Order, FirstBank I, May 3, 2010, ECF No. 22. The surviving claims were a claim for conversion, a claim for unjust enrichment, and a claim to impose a constructive trust and compel an accounting. See id. The District Court then referred the case to the Bankruptcy Court for further proceedings. See Order, FirstBank I, Sept. 7, 2010, ECF No. 44. In so doing, Judge Daniels noted that the Clarification Letter at least purported to transfer the Bonds to Barclays, contrary to FirstBank's allegation that the Bonds had never passed to Barclays. See id. at 2.
After substantial discovery, the Bankruptcy Court
FirstBank timely appealed both the Summary Judgment Order and the Contempt Order, and we consolidated the appeals. See Order, FirstBank Puerto Rico v. Barclays Capital, Inc., No. 13-cv-4732 (NRB) (S.D.N.Y. Mar. 27, 2014), ECF No. 9.
We review the Summary Judgment Order de novo, drawing all factual inferences in favor of the non-moving party, FirstBank. See Hanover Direct, Inc. v. T.R. Acquisition Corp. (In re T.R. Acquisition Corp.), 309 B.R. 830, 835 (S.D.N.Y. 2003).
A rehypothecation clause, by its own terms, allows a secured party in possession of collateral to dispose of the collateral "free" of the pledgor's interest. See CSA ¶ 6(c). This means that, once the secured party transfers title over collateral to some other person, the pledgor has no rights to the collateral as against the transferee. Instead, the pledgor has a right in contract to demand that the secured party return the collateral under the terms of the parties' Credit Support Annex. See CSA ¶ 6(c) (reserving pledgor's rights under CSA ¶¶ 3(b) and 8(b)); Johnson, supra, at 981; cf. ISDA, User's Guide to the 1994 ISDA Credit Support Annex at 13 (1994) ("Parties should carefully consider the risks attendant to the rehypothecation or other disposition of Posted Collateral both to the Secured Party and to the Pledgor and consult with their legal advisors before documenting a Transaction ... under the Annex that permits ... rehypothecation....") (full sentence bolded in original).
It follows that, once Lehman Swaps sold the Collateral to Lehman Brokerage pursuant to FirstBank's Credit Support Annex, FirstBank lost all rights to the Collateral as against Lehman Brokerage (or any subsequent transferee). Instead, the Collateral became outright property of Lehman Brokerage and FirstBank retained only contractual rights against its own counterparties, including (1) the right to demand that Lehman Swaps return excess Collateral (CSA ¶ 3(b)); (2) the right to demand the return of all collateral upon an event of default (CSA ¶ 8(b)); (3) the right to withhold any swap payments to compensate for Lehman Swaps' failure to return collateral (CSA ¶ 8(c)); and (4) the right to sue Lehman Swaps or Lehman Holdings for breach of contract.
FirstBank is simply wrong to say that a repo does not transfer legal title to a bond. See In re Lehman Bros. Inc., 506 B.R. at 349 (S.D.N.Y.2014); Lehman MRA at ¶ 8 ("Title to all Purchased Securities shall pass to Buyer and, unless otherwise agreed by Buyer and Seller, nothing in this Agreement shall preclude Buyer from engaging in repurchase transactions with the Purchased Securities or otherwise pledging or hypothecating the Purchased Securities....").
FirstBank's more interesting argument is that FirstBank's interest in the Bonds survived the Intra-Lehman Repos. As FirstBank accurately describes, Lehman Brokerage employees acted on both sides of the Intra-Lehman Repos, Lehman Swaps was a wholly owned subsidiary of Lehman Brokerage, and Lehman Brokerage already managed the Bonds in its capacity as Lehman Swaps' agent.
However, none of this matters. FirstBank's Credit Support Annex is clear that any permitted sale of the Collateral is "free" of FirstBank's interest. This includes a sale between two Lehman entities, and a sale in which a different Lehman entity acts as Lehman Swaps' agent. Indeed, the Credit Support Annex contemplated that Lehman could unilaterally destroy FirstBank's interest in the Collateral without selling the Collateral in an arm's-length transaction. See CSA ¶ 6(c) (providing that "commingl[ing]" collateral would free the collateral from the pledgor's claims).
Nor did Lehman Swaps' default on September 15, 2008, restore FirstBank's property interest in the Bonds. Cf. Dep. of Christian Johnson, J.A. 2785-2857 ("Johnson Dep.") at 78:18-79:21 (conceding that the Intra-Lehman Repos were permitted uses of the Collateral, but with the caveat that Lehman Swaps' permission to use the Collateral terminated on September 15). The significance of Lehman Swaps' September 15 default was that (1) Lehman Swaps was no longer permitted to rehypothecate collateral that had not yet been rehypothecated, and (2) Lehman Swaps was obligated, as a matter of contract, to retrieve any rehypothecated collateral and to restore it to FirstBank. Nothing in the Credit Support Annex, however, supports the idea that the default somehow restored FirstBank to property rights against transferees of the Collateral (such as Lehman Brokerage).
Because the Intra-Lehman Repos cut off FirstBank's interest in the Bonds, the Bonds' later history is academic. Barclays owns the Bonds so long as (1) Lehman Brokerage transferred the Bonds to Barclays and (2) that transfer was enforceable as between Lehman Brokerage and Barclays. There is no question that Lehman Brokerage transferred the Bonds to Barclays through the Clarification Letter, or that the Clarification Letter is enforceable between Lehman Brokerage and Barclays.
Nevertheless, we will examine the Sale Order and the Clarification Letter because the meaning of the Sale Order is relevant to our affirmance of the Contempt Order.
The text of the Sale Order is undisputed. The Sale Order allowed Barclays to buy "Purchased Assets" of Lehman Brokerage, free and clear of third parties' interests. See Sale Order § 3. The Sale Order even allowed Barclays to buy "Purchased Assets" that were subject to bona fide disputes between Lehman and third parties. See Sale Order § 4 (authorizing sale pursuant to 11 U.S.C. § 363(f)); 11 U.S.C. § 363(f)(4) (authorizing sale "free and clear" of any interest in "bona fide dispute"). In such a case, the third party's claim was converted into a claim against the money that the Lehman trustee received from Barclays. See Sale Order § 4.
It is also undisputed that the Clarification Letter purported to transfer the Collateral. See Clar. Letter ¶¶ 1(a)(ii), 13.
Furthermore, the Sale Order incorporated the Clarification Letter. The Sale Order did so by defining the "Purchase Agreement" to include (1) the original Asset Purchase Agreement (with one amendment) that was presented to the Bankruptcy Court at the Sale Order Hearing; and (2) "that letter agreement clarifying and supplementing the Asset Purchase Agreement dated September 20, 2008". See Sale Order at 1; In re Lehman Bros. Inc., 478 B.R. 570, 577 (S.D.N.Y.2012), aff'd sub nom. In re Lehman Bros. Holding Inc., 761 F.3d at 303, supra. The Sale Order permitted Lehman and Barclays to make only "non-material modifications" to the "Purchase Agreement," § 25, but placed no "materiality" restriction on the Clarification Letter, which was itself defined to be part of the "Purchase Agreement." See In re Lehman Bros. Inc., 478 B.R. at 584.
We recognize that the Bankruptcy Court was disturbed that the Clarification Letter went beyond what the parties had presented to the Bankruptcy Court at the Sale Order Hearing. See In re Lehman Bros. Inc., 445 B.R. 143, 151 (Bankr.S.D.N.Y. 2011) ("The Clarification Letter includes any number of clarifications that are really more than that.... This is a document that should have been subjected to further judicial oversight...."), aff'd in part and rev'd in part, 478 B.R. at 570, supra. Nevertheless, the Bankruptcy Court was clearly not disturbed enough to modify the Sale Order at any time, or to deny Barclays's motions in this case. Indeed, if the Sale Order approved the entire Clarification Letter on the basis of mistake, inadvertence, or misrepresentation, then the proper remedy was for the Bankruptcy Court to amend the Sale Order to narrow the definition of "Purchase Agreement" or to reduce the scope of the anti-suit injunction. See Fed. R. Bankr.P. 9024 (incorporating most of Fed.R.Civ.P. 60); Fed. R.Civ.P. 60(b)(1), (3).
Because no party successfully moved for relief under Rule 60, we are bound to apply the Sale Order as written — even if the Bankruptcy Court has reason to regret its pre-approval of the Clarification Letter, and even if it was improper under section 363 of the Bankruptcy Code for the Sale
Turning to the Clarification Letter,
Finally, we consider FirstBank's argument that due process does not permit the Sale Order to be enforced against FirstBank because FirstBank lacked notice of the Sale Order. The fundamental problem with this argument is that FirstBank did not have a property interest in the Bonds before the bankruptcy sale. FirstBank had lost its property interest when Lehman Swaps sold the Collateral to Lehman Brokerage under the authority of the Credit Support Annex's Rehypothecation Clause, and so due process did not require FirstBank to receive any notice of the sale.
This is a narrow holding. We do not decide the question whether a person with a cognizable property interest may attack a final "free and clear" sale order in the absence of notice.
Although we may set aside the Contempt Order only for abuse of discretion, our review is "`more exacting than under the ordinary abuse-of-discretion standard because a [bankruptcy] court's contempt power is narrowly circumscribed.'" In re A.T. Reynolds & Sons, Inc., 452 B.R. 374, 380 (S.D.N.Y.2011) (alteration in original) (quoting Perez v. Danbury Hosp., 347 F.3d 419, 423 (2d Cir. 2003)). An abuse of discretion occurs when a decision relies on an erroneous view of the law, when a decision relies on a clearly erroneous assessment of evidence,
Contempt is appropriate when "(1) the order the contemnor failed to comply with is clear and unambiguous, (2) the proof of noncompliance is clear and convincing, and (3) the contemnor has not diligently attempted to comply in a reasonable manner." Paramedics Electromedicina Comercial, Ltda. v. GE Med. Sys. Info. Techs., Inc., 369 F.3d 645, 655 (2d Cir.2004). This is precisely the test that the Bankruptcy Court applied. See Contempt Order, 2013 WL 6283572 at *1.
The Sale Order is clear and unambiguous. The Sale Order clearly prohibits suits with respect to "Purchased Assets" as defined in the "Purchase Agreement," the Sale Order clearly incorporates the Clarification Letter into its definition of the "Purchase Agreement,"
Proof of non-compliance is clear and convincing. There is no question that FirstBank filed a suit against Barclays relating to securities that we have held to constitute "Purchased Assets." The "diligent attempt to comply" prong is not relevant to this case, as it was FirstBank's affirmative act that violated the Sale Order's anti-suit injunction.
The Bankruptcy Court also correctly held that subjective good faith is not a bar to contempt. "The violation need not be willful, but it must be demonstrated that the contemnor was not reasonably diligent in attempting to comply." City of New York v. Local 28, Sheet Metal Workers' Int'l Ass'n, 170 F.3d 279, 283 (2d Cir.1999) (internal quotation omitted); but cf. Vuitton et Fils S.A. v. Carousel Handbags, 592 F.2d 126, 130-31 (2d Cir.1979) (requiring a finding of willfulness before awarding costs of prosecuting contempt motion); N.Y. State Nat'l Org. for Women v. Terry, 952 F.Supp. 1033, 1044 (S.D.N.Y. 1997) (same).
Even so, FirstBank's contempt was willful, and, "while willfulness may not necessarily be a prerequisite to an award of fees and costs, a finding of willfulness strongly supports granting them." Weitzman v. Stein, 98 F.3d 717, 719 (2d Cir. 1996). Contempt is willful when the contemnor had actual notice of the order, could have complied, did not seek modification, and did not make a good-faith effort to comply. See, e.g., Bear U.S.A., Inc. v. Kim, 71 F.Supp.2d 237, 249 (S.D.N.Y. 1999).
According to this test, FirstBank's contempt was plainly willful. By the time that FirstBank brought its summary judgment
In the context of the automatic stay, the Second Circuit has held that a good-faith mistake does not preclude a finding of contempt. See Weber v. SEFCU (In re Weber), 719 F.3d 72, 82-83 (2d Cir.2013). Relying on Maritime Asbestosis Legal Clinic v. LTV Steel Co. (In re Chateaugay Corp.), 920 F.2d 183, 186-87 (2d Cir.1990), in which the court declined to enter a contempt order against a legal clinic that had violated the automatic stay with respect to a bankruptcy corporation, FirstBank argues that subjective good faith is a bar to contempt in a case involving nonnatural entities.
FirstBank misapprehends the distinction between individuals and entities in the context of an automatic stay violation. The distinction is that an individual who suffers a willful stay violation must be awarded at least actual damages, while an entity that suffers a willful stay violation will be awarded damages in the discretion of the bankruptcy court. See 11 U.S.C. § 362(k) (mandatory damages for individuals); In re Spookyworld, Inc., 346 F.3d 1, 8 (1st Cir.2003) (noting that debtor-corporations may move for contempt under section 105(a)). However, section 362(k) itself demonstrates that "good faith" and "willful" violations are not mutually exclusive concepts. Subsection 362(k) (1) allows a court to impose punitive damages for willful violations of the automatic stay, while subsection 362(k)(2) forbids punitive damages when the violation of section 362(k)(1) (i.e., a willful violation) was made in a good-faith belief that section 362(h) permitted the contemptuous act.
In short, we believe the better view is that subjective good faith is merely a factor that a bankruptcy court may consider in deciding whether to impose sanctions for the willful violation of an order.
We mention in passing FirstBank's argument that this Court's (per Judge Daniels) partial denial of Barclays's motion to dismiss was "law of the case" that barred the Bankruptcy Court from holding FirstBank in contempt. The Contempt Order and the motion to dismiss turned on different issues. The Contempt Order largely turned on whether the Bonds were "Purchased Assets." If so, then the Sale Order's anti-suit injunction applied and contempt was permissible; if not, then not. By contrast, the District Court's denial of the motion to dismiss assumed as true the assertion that the Bonds were not "Purchased Assets." With a post-discovery record available, there was no need for the Bankruptcy Court to make the same artificial assumption.
Under the circumstances of this case, it was not an abuse of discretion for
Strong policy reasons exist to protect a purchase of estate assets from future litigation costs. An injunction with teeth encourages more prospective buyers to participate in sales and auctions under section 363, and to offer higher prices for a debtor's assets, ultimately to the benefit of creditors. This is particularly important in the present case, in which the global financial system desperately needed a buyer such as Barclays to step forward to purchase Lehman's assets quickly, and in which, without a robust injunction, Barclays would otherwise have risked law suits from hundreds of thousands of Lehman creditors whose complex financial transactions were disrupted by the Lehman bankruptcy.
We note that the Bankruptcy Court did not impose sanctions for FirstBank's first contemptuous act.
We recognize, along with the Bankruptcy Court, that FirstBank acted in good faith. Nevertheless, FirstBank's good faith does not prevent sanctions as a matter of law, and we believe that sanctions were permissible in light of the need for protecting section 363 purchasers and the Bankruptcy Court's prudent handling of this case.
The judgments of the Bankruptcy Court are affirmed. The clerk is directed to enter judgment for appellee and to close the case.
TABLE 1 FirstBank Collateral (see text at note 7) CUSIP All collateral Repoed Collateral Approx. Market Approx. Market Quantity Value (8/29/08) Quantity Value (8/29/08) 31391JPY0 30,950,709 $5,509,517 30,950,709 $5,509,517 31391KYD3 2,000,000 $403,158 2,000,000 $403,158 31390MKJ2 7,000,000 $1,551,579 7,000,000 $1,551,579 31371KWF4 2,073,064 $388,146 2,073,064 $388,146 31401JVN5 24,000,915 $7,635,026 24,000,915 $7,635,026 31400CDE1 8,000,000 $2,227,662 8,000,000 $2,227,662 31401NW39 7,800,000 $1,646,913 7,800,000 $1,646,913 31402A4J2 6,193,841 $2,244,334 6,193,841 $2,244,334 31401AG84 15,181,749 $4,861,287 15,181,749 $4,861,287 31376J7J2 15,000,000 $5,775,107 12,100,000 $4,658,586 31400CAT1 15,000,000 $3,934,573 4,630,000 $1,214,472 31402D5A4 18,190,000 $6,732,383 18,090,000 $6,695,372 31391Y6N2 9,591,196 $2,827,724 6,543,000 $1,929,040 31402FBD6 6,711,261 $2,969,658 4,500,000 $1,991,200
31402BDE1 2,000,000 $757,947 2,000,000 $757,947 31401HJ45 8,302,184 $2,049,626 8,302,184 $2,049,626 31401NP29 10,838,817 $3,726,333 10,838,817 $3,726,333 31402HH61 10,201,592 $3,784,894 10,201,592 $3,784,894 31366LFL5 3,868,461 $20,132 3,868,461 $20,132 36202KAL9 4,500,000 $110,328 4,500,000 $110,328 31391Y3S4 1,000,000 $323,673 0 $0 31401C3G6 1,000,000 $314,507 0 $0 31401H7M8 10,205,000 $3,382,418 0 $0 Total $63,176,925 $53,405,551Source Sitp. ¶ 12 Sept. 1 Stmt. Stip ¶ 12 Calculated
FirstBank also points out that, according to Barclays's expert, FirstBank was entitled to treat the Collateral as FirstBank's own asset in FirstBank's books and records. See Dep. of David Maloy, J.A. 2926-3021 ("Maloy Dep.") at 97:10-20 ("they pledged their asset and the asset is still theirs."). The asset is "theirs" only in the sense that FirstBank retained its exposure to the Bonds after the Collateral was sold to Lehman Brokerage (see supra at 7), not in the sense that FirstBank retained legal title. It may well be the case that, for at least some accounting purposes, both FirstBank and Lehman treated the Collateral as belonging to FirstBank, but this accounting treatment simply reflected the economic reality that FirstBank had "reason to expect that [Lehman Swaps] w[ould] return [the] collateral." Maloy Dep. at 97:21-7.