Elawyers Elawyers
Washington| Change

Dupont v. Com. IRS, 94-7242 (1994)

Court: Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit Number: 94-7242 Visitors: 15
Filed: Dec. 02, 1994
Latest Update: Mar. 02, 2020
Summary: Opinions of the United 1994 Decisions States Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit 12-2-1994 Dupont v. Com. IRS Precedential or Non-Precedential: Docket 94-7242 Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_1994 Recommended Citation "Dupont v. Com. IRS" (1994). 1994 Decisions. Paper 206. http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_1994/206 This decision is brought to you for free and open access by the Opinions of the United States Court of A
More
                                                                                                                           Opinions of the United
1994 Decisions                                                                                                             States Court of Appeals
                                                                                                                              for the Third Circuit


12-2-1994

Dupont v. Com. IRS
Precedential or Non-Precedential:

Docket 94-7242




Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_1994

Recommended Citation
"Dupont v. Com. IRS" (1994). 1994 Decisions. Paper 206.
http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_1994/206


This decision is brought to you for free and open access by the Opinions of the United States Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit at Villanova
University School of Law Digital Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in 1994 Decisions by an authorized administrator of Villanova
University School of Law Digital Repository. For more information, please contact Benjamin.Carlson@law.villanova.edu.
           UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
               FOR THE THIRD CIRCUIT

                 ___________________

           Nos. 94-7242, 94-7243 & 94-7244
                 ___________________


          E.I. DU PONT DE NEMOURS & COMPANY,
             and Affiliated Corporations,
                                   Appellant in No. 94-7242

            REMINGTON ARMS COMPANY, INC.,
                                  Appellant in No. 94-7243

         E.I. DU PONT DE NEMOURS & COMPANY,
   Successor to New England Nuclear Corporation,
                                 Appellant in No. 94-7244

                         v.

     COMMISSIONER OF INTERNAL REVENUE SERVICE

__________________________________________________

    On Appeal from the United States Tax Court
                 Washington, D.C.
  (Tax Court Nos. 91-19950, 91-19952 & 91-19953)
             ________________________


              Argued September 29, 1994

Before:   SCIRICA, NYGAARD and McKEE, Circuit Judges

              (Filed December 2, 1994)


                       JOHN L. SNYDER, ESQUIRE (Argued)
                       MICHAEL R. SCHLESSINGER, ESQUIRE
                       BRADFORD L. FERGUSON, ESQUIRE
                       MARILYN D. FRANSON, ESQUIRE
                       Hopkins & Sutter
                       Three First National Plaza
                       Suite 4200
                       Chicago, Illinois 60602

                          Attorneys for Appellants
                               THOMAS J. CLARK, ESQUIRE (Argued)
                               GARY R. ALLEN, ESQUIRE
                               GILBERT S. ROTHENBERG, ESQUIRE
                               United States Department of Justice
                               Tax Division
                               P.O. Box 502
                               Washington, D.C. 20044

                                   Attorneys for Appellee


                          __________________

                      OPINION OF THE COURT
                       __________________


SCIRICA, Circuit Judge.


          In this appeal, we must determine the validity of

Treas. Reg. § 1.58-9 (1992).    Specifically, the issue is whether

the Department of the Treasury may implement a "suspended-tax"

approach instead of a "suspended-preference" method in

calculating minimum tax under the "tax benefit rule" of former

I.R.C. § 58(h), 26 U.S.C.    The first approach computes and

suspends tax liability until a benefit results while the latter

suspends items of tax preference.      Because we find the suspended-

tax approach to be a reasonable construction of § 58(h), in

accord with its language and purpose, we will uphold the

regulation.

                                  I.

          E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Company, Conoco, Inc.,

Remington Arms Company, and New England Nuclear Corp.1 filed

1
 .        New England Nuclear Corp. (NEN) merged into DuPont
after the 1981 taxable year, the year of the alleged deficiency
against NEN.
federal income tax returns for 1979, 1980, and 1981,2 claiming

reductions in tax liability through the use of income tax credits

carried back from the 1982 tax year.     Subsequently, the Internal

Revenue Service issued notices of deficiency to taxpayers for

$25,633,133.   Taxpayers responded by filing petitions in the Tax

Court, contending the regulation on which the deficiencies were

based exceeded the scope of the authorizing statute, I.R.C. §

58(h).3   The Tax Court sustained the regulation, E.I. Du Pont De

Nemours & Co. v. Commissioner, 
102 T.C. 1
(T.C. 1994), and

taxpayers appealed.4   We will affirm.

                                A.

           In 1969, Congress enacted I.R.C. § 56(a) out of concern

over the use of tax deductions and exemptions that enabled some

high-income taxpayers to pay little or no income tax.5    Section

2
 .        In 1982, DuPont filed a consolidated federal income tax
return on behalf of itself and its affiliates, including Conoco,
Remington, and E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Company, as successor to
NEN. Conoco, Remington, and NEN were not affiliates of DuPont
for the taxable years covered by the 1979-81 returns, however,
and each entity therefore filed its own return. Furthermore,
while DuPont and Conoco filed tax returns on behalf of their
affiliated corporations, we will refer to the tax returns as
having been filed by DuPont and Conoco.
3
 .        The law relevant to this appeal changed significantly
in 1986. See infra note 38. Unless otherwise noted, citations
to former I.R.C. §§ 56 and 58(h) will be to the 1982 version of
the Internal Revenue Code, 26 U.S.C.
4
 .        DuPont, for itself and as successor to NEN, and
Remington filed this appeal. Conoco, which has its principal
place of business in Texas, has an appeal pending before the
Court of Appeals for the Fifth Circuit. Conoco, Inc. v.
Commissioner, No. 94-40382.
5
 .        See H.R. Rep. No. 413, 91st Cong., 1st. Sess., pt. 1,
at 2 (1969), reprinted in 1969 U.S.C.C.A.N. 1645, 1646 ("Under
56(a) imposed a minimum tax, apart from the regular income tax,

on certain deductions and exemptions designated as "items of tax

preference."6   During the years relevant to this case, the

statute levied a minimum tax of 15% of the amount by which the


(..continued)
your committee's bill, virtually no individual with significant
amounts of income will be able to escape payment of all
tax. . . .    The second line of defense is to group remaining tax
preference items and impose a minimum tax or a limit on tax
preferences."); S. Rep. No. 552, 91st Cong., 1st Sess. 112
(1969), reprinted in 1969 U.S.C.C.A.N. 2027, 2143 ("the committee
believes that an overall minimum tax on tax preferences is also
needed to reduce the advantages derived from these preferences
and to make sure that those receiving such preferences also pay a
share of the tax burden"). See also First Chicago Corp. v.
Commissioner, 
842 F.2d 180
, 181 (7th Cir. 1988) ("The purpose of
minimum tax (original or alternative) is to make sure that the
aggregating of tax-preference items does not result in the
taxpayer's paying a shockingly low percentage of his income as
tax."); Occidental Petroleum Corp. v. United States, 
685 F.2d 1346
, 1350 (Cl. Ct. 1982) (Occidental I) ("The legislative
history, to us, reflects a Congressional concern for the way the
tax code is perceived by the general public. . . . In order to
prevent the system from seeming inequitable, individuals and
corporations with large incomes should not be able to avoid
entirely the payment of domestic taxes.").
6
 .        Items of tax preference, defined in I.R.C. § 57 (1982),
represented:

          income of a person which either is not
          subject to current taxation by reason of
          temporary exclusion (such as stock options)
          or by reason of an acceleration of deductions
          (such as accelerated depreciation) or is
          sheltered from full taxation by reason of
          certain deductions (such as percentage
          depletion) or by reason of a special rate of
          tax (such as the rate of tax on corporate
          capital gains).

T.D. 7564, 1978-2 C.B. 19, 23. Tax preferences continue to be
defined in the current Internal Revenue Code, albeit in modified
form. I.R.C. § 57 (1988 & Supp. 1994).
taxpayer's preferences exceeded its regular tax deduction7 or

$10,000, whichever was greater.

          In some situations, however, tax preferences did not

result in a current tax benefit for the taxpayer.    For example, a

taxpayer's tax liability could be completely offset by income tax

credits, which were not designated as preferences.   Yet, even in

those cases in which tax preferences did not result in an actual

benefit, such as when a taxpayer had enough tax credits to reduce

its tax liability to zero, the minimum tax still was imposed.

See Occidental Petroleum Corp. v. United States, 
685 F.2d 1346
(Cl. Ct. 1982) (Occidental I).

          To remedy this perceived unfairness, Congress enacted a

new provision, I.R.C. § 58(h), in the Tax Reform Act of 1976,

Pub. L. No. 94-455, § 301(d)(3), 90 Stat. 1520, 1553 (1976).8

I.R.C. § 58(h) provided:

7
 .        The "regular tax deduction" equaled income tax
liability, including investment tax credit recapture, reduced by
certain tax credits. I.R.C. § 56(c).
8
 .        The Joint Committee on Taxation explained the reason
for § 58(h):

               There are certain cases in which a
          person derives no tax benefit from an item of
          tax preference because, for example, the item
          is disallowed as a deduction under other
          provisions of the Code or because the
          taxpayer has sufficient deductions relating
          to nonpreference items to eliminate his
          taxable income. . . . To deal with this
          problem specifically, the Act instructs the
          Secretary of the Treasury to prescribe
          regulations under which items of tax
          preference (of both individuals and
          corporations) are to be properly adjusted
          when the taxpayer does not derive any tax
           Regulations to include tax benefit rule
                The Secretary shall prescribe
           regulations under which items of tax
           preference shall be properly adjusted where
           the tax treatment giving rise to such items
           will not result in the reduction of the
           taxpayer's tax under this subtitle for any
           taxable years.


Despite the express statutory directive, the Department of the

Treasury failed to propose implementing regulations for thirteen

years.9   In the meantime, Congress repealed § 58(h) in 1986 and

adopted an alternative minimum tax,10 although it later noted

(..continued)
          benefit from the preference. For this
          purpose, a tax benefit includes tax deferral,
          even if only for one year.

H.R. Rep. No. 10612, 94th Cong., 2d Sess., at 106-07 (1976)
(footnote omitted), reprinted in 1976-3 C.B. 118-19. See also
First Chicago 
Corp., 842 F.2d at 181
("[S]ection 56(a) would
impose minimum tax on tax-preference items even though the items
never conferred a tax benefit on the taxpayer. . . . The sparse
legislative history as well as the text of section 58(h)
indicates that this section was added in order to prevent these
anomalous consequences."); Occidental Petroleum Corp. v.
Commissioner, 
82 T.C. 819
, 824 (T.C. 1984) (Occidental II)
("Plainly, in enacting section 58(h), Congress was concerned
about not imposing the minimum tax on tax preferences where such
tax preferences did not result in a tax benefit.").
9
 .        Courts have noted the interpretative difficulties
caused by the Treasury's delay in issuing regulations under §
58(h). See First Chicago 
Corp., 842 F.2d at 182
("These and
other questions might have been answered if the Treasury
Department had ever gotten around to promulgating regulations
under section 58(h), as ordered to do by Congress, but it never
did, blaming its default on a staggering workload . . . .");
Occidental II, 
82 T.C. 829
("[T]he failure to promulgate the
required regulations can hardly render the new provisions of
section 58(h) inoperative. We must therefore do the best we can
with these new provisions.").
10
 .        The Tax Reform Act of 1986 replaced the remnants of the
add-on minimum tax with an alternative minimum tax for taxable
years after 1986. Tax Reform Act of 1986, Pub. L. No. 99-514, §
that § 58(h) would continue to apply to tax years preceding the

1986 statutory change.11

                                B.

           In 1989, the Treasury Department issued a temporary

regulation to implement § 58(h).12   Three years later, the

department promulgated a final version of the regulation, 26

C.F.R. § 1.58-9, applicable only to preferences arising in

taxable years from 1977 to 1986, when the statute was in effect.

Id. § 1.58-9(b).
  Under the regulation, as specified by § 58(h),

a taxpayer is not liable for the minimum tax on its preferences

when they result in no current tax benefit, such as when the

taxpayer has sufficient credits to offset tax liability for the

year without deducting any available preferences.

           Operation of the statute and regulation, however,

results in an unavoidable secondary effect.   When tax credits

exceed regular tax liability for a year, the taxpayer is deemed

to have received no current tax benefit and no minimum tax is

imposed.   Yet, the taxpayer still calculates regular tax

liability by deducting its preferences.   Because the resulting

regular tax liability is lower than it otherwise would be without
(..continued)
701, 100 Stat. 2085, 2320-45 (1986) (codified as amended at
I.R.C. §§ 55-59 (1988)).
11
 .        The Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1989, Pub. L.
No. 101-239, title VII, § 7811(d)(1)(B), 103 Stat. 2106, 2408
(1989), provided that: "The repeal of section 58(h) of the
Internal Revenue Code of 1954 by the Tax Reform Act of 1986 shall
be effective only with respect to items of tax preference arising
in taxable years beginning after December 31, 1986."
12
 .         Temp. Treas. Reg. § 1.58-9T (1989).
the inclusion of the preferences, fewer credits are necessary to

offset the taxpayer's tax liability for the year.    Because tax

credits may be carried over from year to year, the need for fewer

tax credits to offset tax liability in one year "frees up"

additional credits for use in other years.

           If the taxpayer does not use those "freed-up" tax

credits to reduce regular tax liability in any year, then it

never benefits from the preferences; thus, no minimum tax may be

imposed.   See Occidental Petroleum Corp. v. Commissioner, 
82 T.C. 819
(T.C. 1984) (Occidental II).   If the taxpayer later uses

those freed-up credits, however, then it has benefitted from the

preferences and must pay the minimum tax.    Treas. Reg. § 1.58-9.

All parties agree with this conclusion.   The dispute centers on

the method by which the minimum tax is calculated.
                                  C.

          For the 1982 tax year, DuPont filed a consolidated

federal income tax return for itself and its affiliates --

including Conoco, Remington, and NEN -- showing taxable income of

$629,112,639.   DuPont claimed tax preferences of $177,082,305,

which reduced its tax liability to $256,844,566.   Without the use

of preferences to compute taxable income, DuPont's tax liability

would have been $338,302,426.13   Because DuPont had $469,997,179

in credits -- more than enough to offset the potential tax

liability of $338,302,426 -- it was not subject to minimum tax

for the year, pursuant to I.R.C. § 58(h).   See First Chicago

Corp. v. Commissioner, 
842 F.2d 180
(7th Cir. 1988).

          Nevertheless, because DuPont claimed the preferences in

1982 to reduce its taxable income and subsequent tax liability,14

it saved $81,457,86015 in credits for use in other years.    DuPont

carried back those freed-up credits and applied them to its own

return for the 1979 tax year and to individual returns filed by




13
 .        The $338,302,426 in potential tax liability is
calculated by multiplying the $177,082,305 in preferences by the
marginal tax rate of 46 percent from I.R.C. § 11(b)(5) (1982).
The result, $81,457,860, is then added to the $256,844,566 in
regular tax liability computed after deducting the preferences
from taxable income.
14
 .        After being offset by its tax credits, DuPont's zero
tax liability actually increased to $5,626,409 because of the
recapture of investment tax credits, which could not be offset by
credits.
15
 .        See supra note 13.
Conoco, Remington, and NEN, which were not affiliated at the time

with DuPont.16

          Under Treas. Reg. § 1.58-9, the minimum tax constitutes

15% of the difference between the taxpayer's tax preferences and

its regular tax deduction for the year in which the preferences

arose, here 1982.    The regulation requires that credits freed up

by the preferences in one year must be reduced by the amount of

the minimum tax before being carried over to other tax years.

In this case, § 1.58-9 mandated that the freed-up DuPont credits

of $81,457,860 be reduced by $25,633,133, which was 15% of the

difference between the 1982 preferences of $177,082,305 and the

1982 regular tax deduction of $6,194,754.17

          Because DuPont had not reduced the credits pursuant to

the regulation, the Commissioner assessed the following

deficiencies:

          Taxpayer         Taxable Year Ended          Deficiency

          DuPont           December 31, 1979          $13,010,040
          Conoco           December 31, 1980           12,436,199
          Remington        January 31, 1980                78,698
          NEN              February 28, 1981              108,196

                                          Total       $25,633,133

16
 .        See supra note 2. DuPont used the tax credits for the
1979 tax year, Conoco and Remington used the credits for the 1980
tax year, and NEN used them for the 1981 tax year.
17
 .        The regular tax deduction in 1982 was $568,345 more
than the investment tax credit recapture amount of $5,626,409.
See supra note 14. The difference resulted from I.R.C. § 56(c),
which, in defining the regular tax deduction, excluded from
offsetting tax credits the Tax Reduction Act Stock Ownership Plan
(TRASOP) employee plan percentage, under I.R.C. § 46(a)(2)(E)
(1982).
           In contrast to the system mandated by the regulation,

which the Tax Court characterized as the "suspended-tax method,"

taxpayers advocate a "suspended-preference approach."     Du Pont,

102 T.C. 6
.     In essence, taxpayers' method would suspend the

preferences -- not the minimum tax -- and treat them as if they

had arisen during the carry-over year, i.e., the year the freed-

up credits are used.    Those suspended preferences would be

aggregated with other preferences arising in the carry-over year.

The minimum tax then would equal 15% of the difference between

the aggregated preferences and the regular tax deduction for the

carry-over year.    Under taxpayer's method, DuPont, Remington, and

NEN would have no minimum tax liability, and the deficiency

against Conoco would be reduced to $10,551,95618 -- instead of

the $25,633,133 total deficiency assessed under Treas. Reg. §

1.58-9.

           Accordingly, taxpayers filed petitions in the Tax Court

claiming the deficiencies were based on an invalid regulation.

The Commissioner of Internal Revenue disagreed, and all parties

submitted a fully stipulated record to the Tax Court, which

upheld Treas. Reg. § 1.58-9 as a reasonable interpretation of the

statute.   Du Pont, 
102 T.C. 20-21
.    Taxpayers then appealed.19

           The Tax Court had jurisdiction of the case under I.R.C.

§§ 6214(a) and 7442 (1988).     We have jurisdiction under I.R.C. §

18
 .        For detailed calculations of the minimum tax under
taxpayers' proposed system, see Du Pont, 
102 T.C. 7-8
.
19
 .         See supra note 4.
7482 (1988), and our review is plenary.    Pleasant Summit Land

Corp. v. Commissioner, 
863 F.2d 263
, 268 (3d Cir. 1988), cert.

denied, 
493 U.S. 901
(1989).

                                 II.

          As an initial matter, we consider the judicial

deference to which the regulation is entitled.    Under Chevron

U.S.A. Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc., 
467 U.S. 837
, 844 (1984), "legislative regulations are given controlling

weight unless they are arbitrary, capricious, or manifestly

contrary to the statute."    Taxpayers, however, contend that §

1.58-9 is not a "legislative" regulation entitled to deference

under Chevron.

             Because the Treasury proposed the regulation thirteen

years after the statute's enactment and three years after its

repeal, taxpayers argue that § 1.58-9 is not a "legislative"

regulation issued under I.R.C. § 58(h), but merely an

"interpretative" one20 under the department's general rule-making

authority.    See I.R.C. § 7805(a) (1988) ("the Secretary shall

prescribe all needful rules and regulations for the enforcement



20
 .        In this context, "legislative regulations" are those
issued pursuant to a specific grant of congressional authority
"'to define a statutory term or prescribe a method of executing a
statutory provision,'" while "interpretative regulations" are
issued under the general grant of authority of I.R.C. § 7805(a).
See Armstrong World Indus., Inc. v. Commissioner, 
974 F.2d 422
,
430-31 (3d Cir. 1992) (quoting Rowan Cos. v. United States, 
452 U.S. 247
, 253 (1981)). See also McKnight v. Commissioner, 
7 F.3d 447
, 450-51 (5th Cir. 1993); Gehl Co. v. Commissioner, 
795 F.2d 1324
, 1328 (7th Cir. 1986).
of this title").21    We cannot agree.   I.R.C. § 58(h) provided

that the "Secretary shall prescribe regulations . . .," which

appears to be precisely the type of "express delegation of

authority to the agency" that Chevron 
contemplates. 467 U.S. at 843-44
.   Although there may be situations in which substantial

and prejudicial delay in exercising rule-making authority might

alter the degree of deference accorded a regulation, we see no

express prejudice here nor do we discern any other factors that

would change the nature of our review.     In addition, even after

the repeal of § 58(h), Congress expressly stated that the statute

would remain effective for preferences arising in taxable years

before 1987.22   Therefore, the congressional directive for the

Treasury to "prescribe regulations" under § 58(h) remained in

force as to those taxable years.

          Furthermore, in the tax area, we are still required to

treat regulations issued under a general grant of authority with

broad deference, although to a somewhat lesser degree than when

Congress has made a specific delegation of authority in a

specific statute.23   As the Supreme Court has explained:
21
 .        The preamble to Treas. Reg. § 1.58-9 states it was
issued under the specific statute, I.R.C. § 58(h), and the
general grant of authority of § 7805. See T.D. 8416, 1992-1 C.B.
7, 7, 9.
22
 .        See supra note 11.
23
 .        See Polychrome Int'l Corp. v. Krigger, 
5 F.3d 1522
,
1544 n.53 (3d Cir. 1993) (noting, in discussing the Virgin
Islands tax code, that courts "owe less deference to an
interpretative regulation . . . than to one promulgated under a
specific grant of authority"); Armstrong World 
Indus., 974 F.2d at 430
("legislative regulations not promulgated under the
general authority to 'prescribe all needful rules and
"Because Congress has delegated to the Commissioner the power to

promulgate 'all needful rules and regulations for the enforcement

of [the Internal Revenue Code],' 26 U.S.C. §7805(a), we must

defer to his regulatory interpretations of the Code so long as

they are reasonable."   Cottage Sav. Ass'n v. Commissioner, 
499 U.S. 554
, 560-61 (1991) (quoting National Muffler Dealers Ass'n

v. United States, 
440 U.S. 472
, 476-77 (1979)).24

                               III.

                                A.
(..continued)
regulations,' 26 U.S.C. § 7805(a), but instead emanating from a
specific grant of Congressional authority 'to define a statutory
term or prescribe a method of executing a statutory provision,'
are owed an even greater deference") (quoting Rowan 
Cos., 452 U.S. at 253
). See also United States v. Vogel Fertilizer Co.,
455 U.S. 16
, 24 (1982); 
McKnight, 7 F.3d at 450-51
; Gehl 
Co., 795 F.2d at 1328
.

          Although this court and others have noted that
interpretative regulations issued under the Internal Revenue Code
are entitled to less deference than legislative regulations, it
is not clear whether this rule applies outside the Internal
Revenue Code. So far we have declined to decide whether Chevron
U.S.A. Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc., 
467 U.S. 837
(1984), which advises judicial deference to agency
regulations, overruled General Electric Co. v. Gilbert, 
429 U.S. 125
, 141-42 (1976), which held that an agency's interpretative
decisions required less judicial deference. See Sekula v.
Federal Deposit Ins. Corp., No. 93-3596, 
1994 WL 620836
, at *8
n.13 (3d Cir. Nov. 9, 1994); Reich v. Local 30, Int'l Bhd. of
Teamsters, 
6 F.3d 978
, 987 n.14 (3d Cir. 1993); International Raw
Materials, Ltd. v. Stauffer Chem. Co., 
978 F.2d 1318
, 1325 n.9
(3d Cir. 1992), cert. denied, 
113 S. Ct. 1588
(1993).
24
 .        See also Commissioner v. Portland Cement Co. of Utah,
450 U.S. 156
, 169 (1981) (citations omitted) ("Treasury
Regulations 'must be sustained unless unreasonable and plainly
inconsistent with the revenue statutes'"); Armstrong World
Indus., 974 F.2d at 430
(citations omitted) ("we defer to
treasury regulations that 'implement the congressional mandate in
some reasonable manner'").
            I.R.C. § 58(h) directs the Treasury to enact

regulations "under which items of tax preference shall be

properly adjusted where the tax treatment giving rise to such

items will not result in the reduction of the taxpayer's tax

under this subtitle for any taxable years."    On appeal,

taxpayers' principal contention is that the regulation adjusts

tax credits, not items of tax preference.

            Although § 58(h) requires that taxpayers be exempt from

the minimum tax for any year in which their preferences do not

result in a tax benefit, the regulation nevertheless computes the

minimum tax that otherwise would be due on those preferences for

the year.    The regulation then reduces the taxpayers' tax credits

by the amount of the minimum tax.    It is only when taxpayers

attempt to benefit from their preferences -- by using the freed-

up credits -- that they become subject to the tax.

            Taxpayers complain that the operation of § 1.58-9

results in adjustments to their tax credits, contrary to the

language of the statute.    Instead, taxpayers claim the tax should

be assessed by carrying the preference items from the "non-

benefit" year over to the "benefit" year and combining them with

the preferences that arose during the latter year.    The minimum

tax then would equal 15% of the total number of preferences from

both years subtracted by the benefit year's regular tax

deduction.    Taxpayers contend this method would adjust actual

"items of tax preference," as the statute required.

            Although taxpayers' proposal appears to be reasonable,

it is not the only permissible construction of the statute, nor
is it necessarily the most reasonable one.25   We believe Treas.

Reg. § 1.58-9 adjusts "items of tax preference" simply by

ignoring them -- for minimum tax purposes -- during the year when

no tax benefit is realized.    As we have noted, the purpose of the

statute was to ensure that no minimum tax be assessed on

preferences when they did not result in a tax benefit;26 Treas.

Reg. § 1.58-9 accomplishes this result.

                                 B.

           Taxpayers contend Congress intended a "suspended-

preference approach" be promulgated to implement I.R.C. § 58(h)

and claim the legislative history of the 1976 Tax Reform Act,

which adopted § 58(h), supports their construction of the

statute.   But none of the congressional committee reports on §

58(h) indicates the method by which the preferences were to be

adjusted.27   Nevertheless, taxpayers point to one committee

report discussing other provisions of the Code that specify a

type of suspension and reactivation of preferences somewhat


25
 .        The Commissioner claims the taxpayers' approach would
violate fundamental principles of the Internal Revenue Code by
permitting deductions to be shifted from one tax year to another.
Taxpayers respond that they would adjust preferences only for
minimum tax purposes, not under the regular tax, and thus the
integrity of the Code would remain intact. Because we find the
Treasury regulation to be a reasonable construction of the
statute, we need not resolve this issue.
26
 .         See supra note 8.
27
 .        See, e.g., S. Rep. No. 938, 94th Cong., 2d Sess., pt.
I, at 113-14 (1976), reprinted in 1976 U.S.C.C.A.N. 3439, 3548-
49; H.R. Rep. No. 658, 94th Cong., 2d Sess. 130-32 (1975),
reprinted in 1976 U.S.C.C.A.N. 2897, 3025-27.
similar to the system they advocate.28   That committee report,

however, does not explicitly support taxpayers' method of tax

computation.   Furthermore, as the Commissioner contends, the

cited Code provisions are not analogous because they suspend tax

deductions for other purposes,29 not just for minimum tax

purposes, as does § 58(h).30

28
 .        The Joint Committee on Taxation Staff General
Explanation of the Tax Reform Act of 1976 stated:

          There are certain cases in which a person
          derives no tax benefit from an item of tax
          preference because, for example, the item is
          disallowed as a deduction under other
          provisions of the Code or because the
          taxpayer has sufficient deductions relating
          to nonpreference items to eliminate his
          taxable income.1
          _______________

            1For example, preference items giving rise
          to losses which are suspended under at risk
          provisions (sec. 465 or sec. 704(d) of the
          Code) are not to be considered to give rise
          to a tax benefit until the year in which the
          suspended deduction is allowed. Similarly,
          investment interest which is disallowed
          (under sec. 163(d)) is to be treated as an
          itemized deduction for purposes of that
          preference only in the year in which it is
          allowed (under sec. 163(d)).

H.R. Rep. No. 10612, 94th Cong., 2d Sess., at 106-07 (1976)
(footnote omitted), reprinted in 1976-3 C.B. 118-19.
29
 .        See I.R.C. §§ 465, 704(d), 163(d) (1976).
30
 .        Taxpayers also contend the regulation is contrary to
legislative intent because it was issued after Congress failed to
include in a 1989 statute a proposal to permit the Treasury to
adjust items other than tax preferences, presumably including tax
credits. In excluding this language from the final bill,
however, the Conference Report noted the omission was not
intended to affect the pending temporary Treasury regulation,
which was later largely adopted as Treas. Reg. § 1.58-9:
          Taxpayers also assert that Treas. Reg. § 1.58-9

distorts congressional will by interfering with the operation of

other provisions of the Internal Revenue Code.   First, taxpayers

claim the regulation disregards the import of the regular tax

deduction in calculating and reducing minimum tax liability under

I.R.C. § 56(a), (c).   Because Treas. Reg. § 1.58-9 "transforms a

suspended minimum tax in the year the nonbeneficial preferences

arise into regular tax liability in the benefit year," Du Pont,

102 T.C. 15-16
, the preferences from the non-benefit year are

not being weighed against the regular tax deduction in the year

they result in a benefit.   Yet, under the regulation, the

preferences from the non-benefit year continue to be weighed

against the regular tax deduction in the non-benefit year in

calculating the amount of the suspended tax.   Furthermore, while

the regular tax deduction appears to be an integral part of the

minimum tax computation system of § 56, we can discern no



(..continued)

               The conferees do not intend any change
          in the scope of the authority provided in
          section 58(h) of prior law. Thus, only those
          regulations which would have been valid under
          section 58(h) of prior law are valid under
          the conference agreement. No inference is
          intended as to whether the regulations issued
          by the Treasury Department are valid under
          section 58(h) or prior law.

H.R. Conf. Rep. No. 386, 101st Cong., 1st Sess. 664-65 (1989),
reprinted in 1989 U.S.C.C.A.N. 3018, 3267-68. Thus, Congress's
failure to approve the language cited above should not affect our
determination as to the validity of the regulation.
authority or evidence the regular tax deduction was meant to play

a crucial role in the tax benefit rule of § 58(h).

          Second, because Treas. Reg. § 1.58-9 operates to reduce

tax credits available for use in other years, taxpayers contend

the regulation improperly interferes with Code provisions

governing tax credits and the regular income tax.    Although the

regulation does affect tax credits, it does so only in limited

circumstances to certain taxpayers, as the Tax Court noted.

Du Pont, 
102 T.C. 19
.   There is no authority suggesting the

minimal effects of the regulation will disrupt the entire system

of tax credits crafted by Congress or that Congress intended to

forbid all regulations that affect tax credits in any manner.31

          Taxpayers urge us to look to other provisions of the

Internal Revenue Code for guidance in considering the validity of

Treas. Reg. § 1.58-9.   Accordingly, we have examined I.R.C. §

56(b), which until 1987 provided for deferral of minimum tax

liability in situations involving net operating losses affected

by preferences.   Under § 56(b), if preferences served to increase

a net operating loss in one year, the minimum tax otherwise due

on the preferences under § 56(a) was suspended until the year the

preferences provided a tax benefit.   The amount of the minimum

31
 .        Taxpayers also complain that the regulation affects the
balance between the regular tax and minimum tax provisions
created by 1982 and 1984 congressional amendments to the Internal
Revenue Code that scaled back certain preferences by specified
percentages. See Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of
1982, Pub. L. No. 97-248, 1982 U.S.C.C.A.N. (96 Stat. 324);
Deficit Reduction Act of 1984, Pub. L. No. 98-369, § 68(a), 98
Stat. 494, 588 (1984). We do not believe § 1.58-9 will interfere
with the operation of these statutory changes.
tax imposed on the preferences in this situation was calculated

with reference to the minimum tax rate and the regular tax

deduction for the year in which the preferences originated --

similar to the manner in which § 1.58-9 operates.   Du Pont, 
102 T.C. 17-18
.   We agree with the Tax Court that § 56(b)

generally supports the rationale of Treas. Reg. § 1.58-9.     
Id. at 18.
          Therefore, we find nothing in the legislative history

or inferentially from other sections of the Internal Revenue Code

that would indicate the Treasury deviated from the language or

purpose of the statute.   What is clear is the language of § 58(h)

that directs the Secretary to "prescribe regulations under which

items of tax preference shall be properly adjusted."   Congress

made a specific delegation of authority to the Secretary to

promulgate regulations, and we may not substitute an alternative

construction of the statute unless the regulation contravenes the

language or purpose of the statute,32 which this regulation does

not do.




32
 .        See supra section II.
                                C.

          Since 1976, when I.R.C. § 58(h) was enacted, other

courts have considered its meaning and scope.33   Although no

prior cases directly confronted the validity of Treas. Reg. §

1.58-9, taxpayers contend their position here is bolstered by the

reasoning of First Chicago Corp. v. Commissioner, 
842 F.2d 180
(7th Cir. 1988).   In First Chicago, the taxpayer had credits

exceeding its tax liability for the 1980 and 1981 tax years.    The

Internal Revenue Service, however, decreed First Chicago should

pay the minimum tax for those years on the preferences it used to

reduce its tax liability, because those preferences freed up tax

credits that might have been used to reduce First Chicago's

33
 .        For example, in Occidental Petroleum Corp. v. United
States, 
685 F.2d 1346
(Cl. Ct. 1982) (Occidental I), the Court of
Claims considered the propriety of the minimum tax for the years
before Congress enacted the tax benefit rule of § 58(h). The
court held the minimum tax was imposed regardless of whether the
preferences actually resulted in a tax benefit. The court also
determined that the provisions of § 58(h) should not be applied
retroactively to cover the years 1970-71. In Occidental
Petroleum Corp. v. Commissioner, 
82 T.C. 819
(T.C. 1984)
(Occidental II), the taxpayer's tax credits exceeded its tax
liability for 1977, although it used its tax preferences to
reduce the number of credits needed to offset that tax liability
-- just as DuPont did in 1982. In Occidental II, however, the
taxpayer never used the tax credits freed up by the preferences;
instead, the credits expired unused. Nevertheless, the
Commissioner attempted to impose the minimum tax on the taxpayer
because, as in the present case, the taxpayer's use of the
preferences did provide a benefit in the form of increased
available credits for use in other years -- even if those credits
later expired unused. The court rejected the Commissioner's
argument and held that the provisions of § 58(h) meant "no
minimum tax is to be imposed where the tax preference does not
result in a decrease of tax not only for the year under
consideration (here 1977) but also for any other year." 
Id. at 828.
future tax liability.   The Court of Appeals for the Seventh

Circuit disagreed, affirming the Tax Court's holding that "there

is no minimum tax on tax-preference items until the items confer

an actual benefit on the taxpayer."   
Id. at 180.34
          In the course of its discussion, the Seventh Circuit

noted:
          It is true that, as a result of Congress's
          extreme restlessness in the area of tax law,
          by the time the benefit is obtained the
          structure of taxation may have changed and
          the taxpayer may escape part or even all of
          the tax. But this instability is built into
          tax law. If a taxpayer is able to defer
          income to a year when tax rates are lower, he
          obtains a tax savings analogous to what First
          Chicago may someday obtain if its tax-
          preference items yield a tax benefit which
          gives rise to a minimum-tax liability that it
          can offset with foreign or investment tax
          credits, thanks to the new alternative
          minimum tax. But the deferral may backfire,
          if the structure of taxation changes against
          the taxpayer.


Id. at 183.
  This language suggests the court may have assumed

that if the 1980-81 preferences generated a tax benefit after the
1986 statutory changes, then they would be treated as preferences

in that later year and be subject to the new alternative minimum

tax, a view of § 58(h) advocated by taxpayers here.

          But such assumptions, even if indicative of the court's

view, cannot be persuasive here.   At the time of the decision in

First Chicago, § 1.58-9 had not been promulgated.     In fact, the

34
 .        Although the Seventh Circuit rejected the Treasury's
position, the preamble to § 1.58-9 notes the regulation is
"[c]onsistent" with the holding of First Chicago Corp. See T.D.
8416, 1992-1 C.B. 7, 8.
court decried the absence of a regulation as contributing to the

difficulties in interpreting § 58(h).35    Once the Treasury

Department adopted the regulation pursuant to § 58(h), the

landscape changed.    Instead of choosing among alternative methods

of interpreting the statute, we must inquire whether the Treasury

regulation reasonably implements the statute.36    As we have

noted, we believe it does.

                                    D.

            Besides challenging the substance of Treas. Reg. §

1.58-9, taxpayers assert the regulation was enacted in "bad

faith" and thus not entitled to judicial deference.    In support,

taxpayers cite National Muffler Dealers Ass'n v. United States,

440 U.S. 472
(1979).    In National Muffler, the Supreme Court

stated, in assessing the validity of regulations, courts should

consider factors such as whether the regulation was issued

contemporaneously with the statute, the manner in which it

evolved, "the length of time the regulation has been in effect,

the reliance placed on it, the consistency of the Commissioner's

interpretation, and the degree of scrutiny Congress has devoted

to the regulation during subsequent re-enactments of the

statute."    
Id. at 477.
  Taxpayers argue the National Muffler

factors demonstrate the regulation should be set aside.    Although


35
 .        First Chicago 
Corp., 842 F.2d at 182
("These and other
questions might have been answered if the Treasury Department had
ever gotten around to promulgating regulations under section
58(h), as ordered to do by Congress, but it never did . . . .").
36
 .          See supra section II.
application of the National Muffler factors may not explicitly

validate § 1.58-9, we do not find that sufficient to warrant

striking down the regulation.37   In fact, we already have

determined the regulation implements the statute in a "reasonable

manner," which is all National Muffler ultimately requires and

which is what its factors were intended to ascertain.   
Id. at 476-77
(noting that courts should defer to regulations that

"implement the congressional mandate in some reasonable manner"

and listing factors to "determin[e] whether a particular

regulation carries out the congressional mandate in a proper

manner").

            Taxpayers also assert the regulation is not entitled to

deference because the Treasury Department promulgated it in an
37
 .        Indeed, in National Muffler, the Treasury waited six
years after the statute was enacted to issue any regulation and
then substantially changed its own regulation ten years after
that. 440 U.S. at 478-82
. Nevertheless, the Supreme Court
deferred to the regulation. 
Id. at 488-89.
          We are not persuaded that the National Muffler factors
favor taxpayers' position here. Although the regulation was not
issued contemporaneously with the statute nor been long in place,
taxpayers have not shown they detrimentally relied on any prior
understanding of the statute. The Commissioner's interpretation
of the statute apparently has changed primarily because of
judicial decisions such as Occidental II, 
82 T.C. 819
(T.C.
1984), and First Chicago 
Corp., 842 F.2d at 180
. See T.D. 8416,
1992-1 C.B. 7, 8 (noting that Treas. Reg. § 1.58-9 is
"[c]onsistent" with the holding of First Chicago). Furthermore,
although Congress may not have re-enacted the statute, it
expressly noted the statute would continue to apply to the years
preceding the repeal of § 58(h). See supra note 11. Finally,
National Muffler involved an interpretative regulation issued
under the general grant of authority of I.R.C. § 7805(a), rather
than a regulation issued pursuant to a specific statutory
mandate. In view of this, the National Muffler analysis is
somewhat less helpful.
attempt to circumvent the 1986 change in the revenue statutes

that permitted up to 90% of the minimum tax to be offset by

foreign tax credits.38    In addition, taxpayers claim the Treasury

adopted § 1.58-9 merely to enhance its litigating stance in cases

like this.

             As to the claim the regulation was enacted merely to

bolster the Treasury's litigating position, one court has ruled

that "the Commissioner may not take advantage of his power to

promulgate retroactive regulations during the course of a

litigation for the purpose of providing himself with a defense

based on the presumption of validity accorded to such

regulations."    Chock Full O' Nuts Corp. v. United States, 
453 F.2d 300
, 303 (2d Cir. 1971).     Yet, as the Court of Appeals for

the Fifth Circuit noted, "[n]o case has held that the Secretary

abused his discretion to promulgate retroactive regulations

merely because the regulation at issue affected a legal matter

pending before a court at the time the regulation was adopted."

Anderson, Clayton & Co. v. United States, 
562 F.2d 972
, 980 (5th

Cir. 1977), cert. denied, 
436 U.S. 944
(1978).     In the present

case, there is no claim that any specific case was pending at the

time the regulation was proposed.     Furthermore, taxpayers cite to

38
 .        The Tax Reform Act of 1986 replaced the add-on minimum
tax for corporations with an alternative minimum tax for taxable
years after 1986. Tax Reform Act of 1986, Pub. L. No. 99-514, §
701, 100 Stat. 2085, 2320-45 (1986) (codified as amended at
I.R.C. §§ 55-59 (1988)). Under the old system, foreign tax
credits could not be used to offset the minimum tax. Under the
new alternative minimum tax, foreign tax credits are permitted to
offset up to 90% of the tax. See First Chicago 
Corp., 842 F.2d at 182
; I.R.C. § 55, 59(a)(2) (1988 & Supp. 1994).
nothing in the record to support any of their suspicions

regarding the Treasury Department's motives in promulgating the

regulation, and the case was submitted to the Tax Court fully

stipulated.   DuPont, 
102 T.C. 2
.

                                 IV.

          In evaluating Treas. Reg. § 1.58-9, we are mindful of

the Supreme Court's admonition:    "The choice among reasonable

interpretations [of the Internal Revenue Code] is for the

Commissioner, not the courts."    Skinner v. Mid-America Pipeline,

490 U.S. 212
, 222 (1989) (quoting National Muffler Dealers Ass'n

v. United States, 
440 U.S. 472
, 488 (1979)).   After considering

the regulation in light of the language of I.R.C. § 58(h), and

the purpose behind it, we are satisfied § 1.58-9 constitutes a

reasonable interpretation of the statute.    Accordingly, we will

affirm the judgment of the Tax Court.

Source:  CourtListener

Can't find what you're looking for?

Post a free question on our public forum.
Ask a Question
Search for lawyers by practice areas.
Find a Lawyer