RONALD LEE GILMAN, Circuit Judge.
This is a purported class action brought by Erie County, Ohio on behalf of itself and other counties in northern Ohio against Morton Salt, Inc. and Cargill, Inc. Erie County claims that Morton and Cargill have conspired to fix the price of rock salt in northern Ohio by geographically dividing the market and excluding competition, in violation of Ohio's Valentine Act (Ohio Revised Code §§ 1331.01-1331.15), a state analogue to the federal antitrust statutes, including the Sherman Act (15 U.S.C. §§ 1-7). The district court granted the defendants' motion to dismiss, finding that the facts alleged in the complaint are just as consistent with lawful parallel conduct as they are with a conspiracy. On appeal, Morton and Cargill defend the court's dismissal of the complaint for failure to state a claim and argue that the court's decision may also be affirmed on the independent basis that Erie County lacks standing to sue. Although we disagree with the analysis of the district court, we
The following facts are taken from the Second Amended Class Action Complaint (the complaint) and the documents that it relies on, which documents both parties urge us to consider. See Bassett v. Nat'l. Coll. Athletic Ass'n., 528 F.3d 426, 430 (6th Cir.2008) (holding that, on a motion to dismiss, a court "may consider the Complaint and any exhibits attached thereto, public records, items appearing in the record of the case and exhibits attached to defendant's motion to dismiss so long as they are referred to in the Complaint and are central to the claims contained therein").
Rock salt, also known as road salt, is larger and heavier than table salt. Its size and weight keep it from being easily pushed off the road, and it is used to keep roads and bridges free of snow and ice during wintery weather. The market for rock salt in Ohio has two distinct segments: a market encompassing the 54 northern counties (known as the "Lake [Erie] market") and a market consisting of the southern 34 counties (known as the "[Ohio] River market"). Rock salt offered in the northern market comes primarily from mines near Lake Erie in Ohio, and rock salt offered in the southern market comes primarily from mines in Louisiana. The Ohio Department of Transportation (ODOT) is the largest purchaser of rock salt in Ohio. Members of the purported class — the northern Ohio counties — are, collectively, the second-largest in-state purchaser. ODOT is required to award contracts by soliciting sealed bids and choosing the lowest bid (subject to preferences for Ohio-mined salt, which will be discussed below). See generally Ohio Rev. Code § 125.11.
Morton and Cargill are the only two companies that operate salt mines located in Ohio. Morton is headquartered in Chicago and operates a salt mine in Fairport, Ohio. Cargill is headquartered in North Olmstead, Ohio and operates a salt mine in Cleveland. Together, the two companies supply at least 60 percent of the rock salt purchased in Ohio. Between 2001 and 2008, they supplied almost all of the rock salt purchased by government entities in northern Ohio.
During the fall and winter of 2008, the price of rock salt purchased by ODOT rose by as much as 300 percent compared to the previous year. (The Ohio Inspector General puts the price rise at between 19 and 236 percent; ODOT reports it as between 50 and 300 percent.) Ohio Governor Ted Strickland asked ODOT to investigate the causes of this dramatic price hike. ODOT responded by preparing a Bid Analysis and Review Team Report (the BART Report), which it submitted to the Governor in December 2008. The BART Report identified several potential causes for the price spike, including increased demand for salt due to a harsh winter; high transportation costs due to increased energy prices; and the structure of the state's contract system, which required suppliers to keep a large quantity of salt off the market and in reserve, thereby "suppress[ing] uncommitted supply" and increasing the price.
More to the point for purposes of the present case, the BART Report found that Morton and Cargill elected not to compete with each other, preferring instead to keep to their own turf. This in effect created "county-by-county monopolies" where higher prices prevailed. Each company "bid in a way that most easily segmented the Ohio market into two monopolies, preventing competition and ensuring that neither firm would end up over-committing its supplies."
Prompted by the BART Report, the Ohio Office of the Inspector General initiated its own investigation in February 2009 and issued a report in January 2011 (the OIG Report). The OIG interviewed 27 people in conducting its investigation, including employees of Morton and Cargill, employees of their competitors, and state governmental officials. It also issued 14 subpoenas and other record requests to Morton and Cargill, and received nearly 190,000 pages of documents containing "road salt bidding, pricing, mine sourcing, stockpiling and transportation data" in response. The OIG consulted Dr. James T. McClave, a statistician and founder of Info Tech Inc., a company that the OIG Report described as "one of the nation's premier bid-analysis consulting firms," to help review and analyze this data. Because the complaint is largely based on the OIG Report, the Report's key findings are set forth below.
The OIG Report found that the exclusion of out-of-state competitors was not due to the Buy Ohio law itself, but was caused by ODOT's erroneous interpretation of the law. Under this law, if two or more companies offering Ohio-mined salt submit a bid on a contract, ODOT is required to award the contract to one of them, even if other bidders offering non-Ohio-mined salt submit cheaper bids — but only if the lowest price for the Ohio-mined salt is no more than five percent above the lowest price for the non-Ohio-mined salt. See Ohio Rev.Code § 125.11(B); Ohio Admin. Code § 123:5-1-06(C)(3).
From 2001 to 2008, ODOT gave no effect to this "excessive price" caveat. It instead read the law to require awarding the contract to one of two or more companies offering Ohio-mined salt, regardless of the price. Under this reading, if both Morton and Cargill, the only two companies offering Ohio-mined salt, submitted a bid, then all other companies were locked out of the competition, even if their bids were more than five percent lower. This lockout interpretation of the Buy Ohio law helped give rise to a duopoly in which Morton and Cargill ruled the northern Ohio market for state-government contracts in rock salt. "By applying the lockout interpretation when awarding salt contracts instead of the excessive-price interpretation," concluded the OIG Report, "ODOT has been an enabler in its own victimization."
But the OIG Report did not lay all the blame for noncompetitive rock-salt prices at ODOT's doorstep. It also found that Morton and Cargill had "engaged in anti-competitive market allocation practices" by "carv[ing] up" the market into two zones, with each company ruling its own zone and failing to mount a competitive challenge in the other's zone.
The OIG Report relied on "five indicators" to support its market-allocation conclusion:
Based on these five indicators, the OIG Report concluded that Morton and Cargill had geographically divided the northern Ohio market for rock salt, which drove up the price and ended up costing Ohio taxpayers between $47 million and $59 million in ODOT overpayments. The Report noted, however, that the OIG had "failed to find evidence that the two companies communicated on salt bids."
Two weeks after the OIG Report was issued, Erie County sued Morton and Cargill. The complaint is essentially a summary of the OIG Report, so the foregoing account of the Report adequately sets forth the thrust of the complaint. In evaluating the allegations of the complaint, however, one must keep in mind that ODOT purchases salt in each of the 54 northern Ohio counties, including Erie County, but each of the 54 counties also makes separate purchases on its own behalf. The OIG Report was focused on ODOT's purchases; this action, brought as it is by Erie County on behalf of all northern Ohio counties, focuses on the counties' purchases. Accordingly, the complaint adds county-specific facts to those of the OIG Report. The complaint in essence alleges that the defendants carried over the same practices and pattern of anticompetitive market allocation from the ODOT market to the county market.
Relying on the OIG Report, supplemented by county-specific information, the complaint asserts three claims against Morton and Cargill. Erie County's first claim is that the defendants violated the Ohio Deceptive Trade Practices Act, Ohio Rev. Code § 4165.02, by misrepresenting the origin of their rock salt. Second, based on the OIG Report's five indicators, the complaint asserts that the defendants conspired to fix the price of rock salt in northern Ohio in violation of the Valentine Act. The final claim is that the defendants committed fraud by intentionally inflating the price of rock salt and by representing that they were engaged in fair and competitive bidding when in fact they had colluded.
Erie County filed this action in Ohio state court. The defendants removed the case to the United States District Court for the Northern District of Ohio. They subsequently filed a motion under Rule 12(b)(6) of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure to dismiss the complaint for failure to state a claim. The district court granted the defendants' motion to dismiss. With respect to the price-fixing claim, the court found the allegations to be just as consistent with lawful parallel conduct as with an unlawful conspiracy. The court held that the five indicators in the OIG Report "describe at length signs of an anticompetitive marketplace, but do not provide indicia of illegal collusion within that marketplace." And the defendants' duopoly and attendant high profits were found to be the result of the "marketplace's dysfunction" caused by ODOT's erroneous interpretation of the Buy Ohio law, not of any wrongdoing by the defendants. In sum, the court concluded that the "defendants' actions are at least as likely to be those of independent beneficiaries lawfully exploiting ODOT's erroneous anticompetitive interpretation as they are of unlawful conspirators in that same marketplace.
After the district court dismissed the complaint, Erie County filed a motion for reconsideration. The motion noted that Erie County had recently discovered — contrary to its previous "information and belief" — that the counties have never been bound by the Buy Ohio law, and argued that this newly discovered fact should change the district court's motion-to-dismiss ruling. But Erie County soon withdrew its motion for reconsideration and filed this appeal instead.
On appeal, Erie County challenges the district court's dismissal of the Valentine Act claim. It does not challenge the dismissal of the other two claims.
A district court's decision to grant a motion to dismiss for failure to state a claim is reviewed de novo. Lambert v. Hartman, 517 F.3d 433, 438-39 (6th Cir. 2008). When deciding such a motion, we must construe the complaint in the light most favorable to the plaintiff and accept all factual allegations as true. Id. at 439. We need not, however, accept conclusory allegations or conclusions of law dressed up as facts. Ashcroft v. Iqbal, 556 U.S. 662, 678, 129 S.Ct. 1937, 173 L.Ed.2d 868 (2009).
"To survive a motion to dismiss, a complaint must contain sufficient factual matter, accepted as true, to `state a claim to relief that is plausible on its face.'" Id. (quoting Bell Atl. Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544, 570, 127 S.Ct. 1955, 167 L.Ed.2d 929 (2007)). This standard demands that the factual allegations "raise a right to relief above the speculative level" and "nudge[] the[] claims across the line from conceivable to plausible." Twombly, 550 U.S. at 555, 570, 127 S.Ct. 1955. It does not demand, however, that recovery be probable. Rather, "a well-pleaded complaint may proceed even if it strikes a savvy judge that actual proof of those facts is improbable, and that a recovery is very remote and unlikely." Id. at 556, 127 S.Ct. 1955 (internal quotation marks omitted). In the final analysis, "[d]etermining whether a complaint states a plausible claim for relief will ... be a context-specific task that requires the reviewing court to draw on its judicial experience and common sense." Iqbal, 556 U.S. at 679, 129 S.Ct. 1937.
"Ohio has long followed federal law in interpreting the Valentine Act," Johnson v. Microsoft Corp., 106 Ohio St.3d 278, 834 N.E.2d 791, 795 (2005), and both parties have cited exclusively to federal jurisprudence interpreting the Sherman Act. We will therefore analyze Erie County's Valentine Act claims by reference to federal law.
Section One of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1, prohibits unreasonable contracts, combinations, and conspiracies in restraint of trade. Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, Inc., 551 U.S. 877, 885, 127 S.Ct. 2705, 168 L.Ed.2d 623 (2007). To state a Section One claim, a plaintiff must plead more than a restraint of trade; it must plead an agreement in restraint of trade. Twombly, 550 U.S. at 553, 127 S.Ct. 1955 ("[T]he crucial question is whether the challenged anticompetitive conduct stems from independent decision or from an agreement, tacit or express.") (brackets and internal quotation marks omitted). An agreement, either tacit or
Although an agreement may be inferred from circumstantial evidence, the bare fact that defendants engaged in parallel conduct is not sufficient to establish a Sherman Act violation:
Twombly, 550 U.S. at 553-54, 127 S.Ct. 1955 (brackets, citations, ellipsis, and internal quotation marks omitted).
Accordingly, "an allegation of parallel conduct and a bare assertion of conspiracy will not suffice" to state an antitrust claim. Id. at 556, 127 S.Ct. 1955. Rather, allegations of parallel conduct "must be placed in a context that raises a suggestion of a preceding agreement." Id. at 557, 127 S.Ct. 1955. Examples of allegations that go beyond simple parallel conduct and that plausibly raise an inference of agreement include "parallel behavior that would probably not result from chance, coincidence, independent responses to common stimuli, or mere interdependence unaided by an advance understanding among the parties"; "conduct that indicates the sort of restricted freedom of action and sense of obligation that one generally associates with agreement"; and "complex and historically unprecedented changes in pricing structure made at the very same time by multiple competitors, and made for no other discernible reason" than to conform to a prior agreement. Id. at 556 n. 4, 127 S.Ct. 1955 (brackets and internal quotation marks omitted).
Of course, a plaintiff who states a plausible conspiracy claim is not guaranteed to survive a motion for summary judgment later in the case. "To survive a motion for summary judgment or for a directed verdict, a plaintiff seeking damages for a violation of § 1 must present evidence that tends to exclude the possibility that the alleged conspirators acted independently." Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 588, 106 S.Ct. 1348, 89 L.Ed.2d 538 (1986) (internal quotation marks omitted).
The district court did not clearly distinguish between the antitrust standards applicable on summary judgment and those that apply to a motion to dismiss. Two points of clarification are in order.
First, at the pleading stage, the plaintiff is not required to allege facts showing that an unlawful agreement is more likely than lawful parallel conduct. The Supreme Court took pains to stress in both Twombly and Iqbal that what is required at the pleading stage is a plausible, not probable, entitlement to relief. See Twombly, 550 U.S. at 556, 127 S.Ct. 1955 ("Asking for plausible grounds to infer an agreement does not impose a probability requirement at the pleading stage; it simply calls for enough fact to raise a reasonable expectation that discovery will reveal evidence of illegal agreement.") (internal quotation marks omitted); Iqbal, 556 U.S. at 678, 129 S.Ct. 1937 ("The plausibility
Second, in order to state a Section One claim, a plaintiff need not allege a fact pattern that "tends to exclude the possibility" of lawful, independent conduct. The "tends to exclude" language traces its provenance to Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Service Corp., 465 U.S. 752, 764, 104 S.Ct. 1464, 79 L.Ed.2d 775 (1984), and Matsushita Electrical Industrial Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 588, 106 S.Ct. 1348, 89 L.Ed.2d 538 (1986), which were both decisions dealing with summary judgment and the standard of proof required to submit an issue to the jury. In restating the same language, the Supreme Court in Twombly was mindful of those decisions' procedural context, see 550 U.S. at 554, 127 S.Ct. 1955, and nowhere held that the same standard applies on a motion to dismiss. And there is no authority cited by either the parties or the district court for extending the same standard to the pleading stage.
To the contrary, the only circuit court of appeals that to our knowledge has considered such an extension has rejected it, and so has the leading treatise in the field. See Starr v. Sony BMG Music Entm't, 592 F.3d 314, 325 (2d Cir.2010) ("Defendants first argue that a plaintiff seeking damages under Section 1 of the Sherman act must allege facts that tend to exclude independent self-interested conduct as an explanation for defendants' parallel behavior. This is incorrect.") (brackets, citation, and internal quotation marks omitted); 2 Philip E. Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law 11307d1 at 118 (3d ed. 2010) (hereinafter Areeda & Hovenkamp) ("Observe that the Supreme Court [in Twombly] did not hold that the same standard applies to a complaint and a discovery record, with the only difference being that the former involves alleged facts while the latter involves facts in evidence. The `plausibly suggesting' threshold for a conspiracy complaint remains considerably less than the `tends to rule out the possibility' standard for summary judgment.") (emphasis in original).
The rationale for rejecting such an extension is clear: If a plaintiff were required to allege facts excluding the possibility of lawful conduct, almost no private plaintiff's complaint could state a Section One claim. Rational people, after all, do not conspire in the open, and a plaintiff is very unlikely to have factual information that would exclude the possibility of non-conspiratorial explanations before discovery. Accordingly, the regular motion-to-dismiss standard should apply.
Under this standard, the question before us is: Do the factual allegations point to nothing more than parallel conduct of the sort that is the product of independent action, or do they plausibly raise an inference of unlawful agreement? See Twombly, 550 U.S. at 553, 127 S.Ct. 1955. That is the question to which we will now turn.
As discussed above, Erie County claims that the five "indicators," copied from the OIG Report, nudge this case over the line from mere parallel conduct to conspiracy: (1) stable market shares; (2)
The first, second, and fifth factors are simply descriptions of the market, not allegations of anything that the defendants did. Standing alone, they indicate only that the market is a duopoly, and do not give rise to an inference of an unlawful agreement (though they might, when combined with the other factors, strengthen the plausibility of such an inference).
The third and fourth factors are the nub of the complaint. With respect to the third factor, Erie County faults the defendants for failing to grab allegedly plum business opportunities. As the complaint puts it, "[s]uspicious bidding patterns occurred when the Defendants failed to seek bids that would generate higher profit margins, i.e., when the Defendants would contract with a county that is farther from their mine or stockpile instead of a county that is closer to their salt source." The argument, in other words, is that because the product being sold is homogenous and fungible, and because all costs except for transportation are constant, the defendants' failure to aggressively compete and bid low for accounts that are closer to their respective mines signifies a "fail[ure] to seek bids that would generate higher profits."
But this is exactly the sort of failure-to-compete claim that Twombly rejected. In that case, the plaintiffs attacked the defendant telecommunications firms' "common failure meaningfully to pursue attractive business opportunities in contiguous markets where they possessed substantial competitive advantages." 550 U.S. at 551, 127 S.Ct. 1955 (brackets and internal quotation marks omitted). The plaintiffs in Twombly claimed that the defendants' decision to remain in their respective local telephone and Internet-services territories and to not encroach on each other's territories, which resulted in a market that remained "highly compartmentalized geographically, with minimal competition," was indicative of a prior agreement to restrain trade. Id. at 551, 567, 127 S.Ct. 1955. In holding that these allegations of failure to compete and geographical compartmentalization did not state a Section One claim, the Supreme Court reasoned:
Just as in Twombly, the failure to compete alleged in this case is indicative of no more than a natural and independent desire to avoid a turf war and preserve the profits guaranteed by regional dominance. Morton and Cargill presumably realize, like the defendants in Twombly, that their interests are best served by keeping to their own turf and charging oligopoly prices rather than stepping on each other's toes and provoking a bidding war that would lead to competitive prices and reduced profits. This is no more than an independent, self-interested failure to compete, which does not violate Section One. See, e.g., In re Text Messaging Antitrust Litig., 630 F.3d 622, 627 (7th Cir.2010) (Posner, J.) (explaining that Section One "does not require sellers to compete; it just forbids their agreeing or conspiring not to compete").
But the fourth factor that the complaint takes from the OIG Report alleges something more. The claim is not only that Morton and Cargill failed to enter each other's turf, but also that they helped each other rule their respective turf by submitting intentionally losing bids that served to exclude their out-of-state competitors. This is significant because, under the then-prevailing interpretation of the Buy Ohio law, all out-of-state bidders were locked out — their bids would not even be considered, no matter how much cheaper — if both Morton and Cargill submitted a bid for a particular contract. A crucial difference therefore existed between one of the two companies' submitting a losing bid and not submitting a bid at all: only in the former case was the other company guaranteed to win the contract. The intentional submission of a losing bid under these circumstances does not make sense if it merely signifies a lack of interest in winning the contract; if that were the motivation, the company would presumably not bid at all. The practice makes sense only as a device to help the other company rule its territory.
Not to compete with a fellow oligopolist is one thing; to actively assist the fellow oligopolist to preserve its oligopoly is quite another. Unlike the failure to compete, the submission of losing bids has no obvious independent justification. Why, after all, should Cargill care if Morton or some other company prevails in a county that is of no interest to Cargill anyway (and vice versa)? The most plausible explanation is the expectation of a "tit for tat"; i.e., that I will guarantee your dominance in your primary zone by submitting a high bid that is guaranteed to lose but will lock out your other competitors, and in return you will exclude my competitors by submitting a losing bid in my primary zone. This kind of tit-for-tat arrangement would be extremely difficult to sustain in the absence of at least a tacit agreement. See 6 Areeda & Hovenkamp ¶ 1420b at 154 ("A strong inference of coordinated behavior arises when a participant actively seeks to lose a bid. Deliberate sacrifice of a contract implies an unusual confidence that the winning party will return the favor. Moreover, spurious bidding indicates an awareness of wrongdoing coupled with a desire to hide it by simulating normal bidding. A spurious bid is almost always anticompetitive."); see also id. ¶ 1420d1 at 158 ("Interdependent sham bids are unlikely to endure without some facilitating mechanism....").
A sham-bidding conspiracy would therefore not be implausible. Its plausibility, however, hinges on the applicability of the Buy Ohio law. Without the Buy Ohio law, as then interpreted by ODOT, the incentive to collude evaporates because the
Although the complaint does not specifically allege that Erie County was bound by the Buy Ohio law, the district court and the defendants assumed that it was so bound, perhaps because the entire theory of the conspiracy laid out in the complaint rested on ODOT's lockout interpretation of the Buy Ohio law. But, after the district court dismissed the complaint, Erie County acknowledged for the first time that in fact it was never bound by the Buy Ohio law. In a subsequently withdrawn motion for reconsideration filed after the complaint was dismissed, Erie County stated:
Erie County reiterated in its opening appellate brief that "[l]ocal governments are free to participate in `Buy Ohio,' but are not required to." And counsel for Erie County assured us again at oral argument that "they weren't subject to the Buy Ohio" law.
Erie County's concession that it was not bound by the Buy Ohio law dooms its conspiracy claim. As explained above, the allegation of sham bidding is the only thing that could save the present case from dismissal under Twombly. And the theory of sham bidding makes sense only in a market subject to the lockout interpretation of the Buy Ohio law. If a purchaser of rock salt is not bound by the Buy Ohio law, then it is free to solicit and receive bids from out-of-state companies without having its choices limited to Morton and Cargill, and sham bidding would therefore be an exercise in futility. The conspiracy claim, in other words, would be implausible in a market that is not subject to the Buy Ohio law.
Erie County attempts to extricate itself from this predicament by arguing that, although it did not adopt ODOT's interpretation of the Buy Ohio law, it was "indirectly" harmed by the defendants' exploitation of that law because the defendants "were able to leverage the distortions created by Buy Ohio in state contracts into a similar allocation of county and municipal contracts." "The resulting environment of high and distorted price[] levels combined with limited competition allowed the suppliers to carry out much the same scheme on the county and municipal level."
Erie County's claim of indirect harm by "leveraging" is unpersuasive. Its arguments as to how this supposed leveraging worked are vague and do not spell out a meaningful theory. If the theory is that Morton and Cargill leveraged their monopoly power in segments of the ODOT market to create monopolies in segments of the county market, that would appear to be a Sherman Act Section Two (monopolization-type) claim, not a Section One claim. Such a claim would require elements that are not pleaded in the complaint, including "a dangerous probability of success in monopolizing a second market." See Verizon Commc'ns. Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 415 n. 4, 124 S.Ct. 872, 157 L.Ed.2d 823 (2004) (internal quotation marks omitted).
The complaint also advances the following claim of "indirect" harm:
But none of this adds up to a Section One claim. The complaint's theory that any sham bidding with respect to ODOT purchases made other markets (what Erie County calls "the remainder of the market") "less dense and therefore less susceptible to effective competition" simply does not follow. After all, how are other markets linked to the ODOT market? Erie County does not tell us, and its conclusory say-so does not satisfy the standard of plausible pleading. See Ashcroft v. Iqbal, 556 U.S. 662, 678, 129 S.Ct. 1937, 173 L.Ed.2d 868 (2009) (holding that plausible pleading "does not require detailed factual allegations, but it demands more than an unadorned, the-defendant-unlawfully-harmed-me accusation") (internal quotation marks omitted); Bell Atl. Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544, 555, 555 n. 3, 127 S.Ct. 1955, 167 L.Ed.2d 929 (2007) ("[A] plaintiff's obligation to provide the grounds of his entitlement to relief requires more than labels and conclusions, and a formulaic recitation of the elements of a cause of action will not do.... Rule 8(a)(2) still requires a `showing,' rather than a blanket assertion, of entitlement to relief.") (brackets and internal quotation marks omitted).
Nor is the complaint salvaged by the contention that sham bidding in the ODOT market "allowed Defendants to dishonestly cite to supra-competitive prices paid by ODOT as really being competitive prices." "Dishonestly citing" — better known as misrepresentation — is not an antitrust claim. See generally Brooke Grp., Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209, 225, 113 S.Ct. 2578, 125 L.Ed.2d 168 (1993) ("Even an act of pure malice by one business competitor against another does not, without more, state a claim under the federal antitrust laws; those laws do not create a federal law of unfair competition or purport to afford remedies for all torts committed by or against persons engaged in interstate commerce.") (internal quotation marks omitted). The fraud claim was dismissed below and never appealed, and is therefore not before us. In short, because it is not bound by the Buy Ohio law, Erie County has failed to state a plausible conspiracy claim.
Although both parties have characterized Erie County's not being bound by the Buy Ohio law as an issue of "standing," we have elected to treat it as an issue of failing to state a claim because the significance of Erie County's not being bound by the Buy Ohio law can be understood only after analysis of the complaint's substantive allegations of conspiracy. In any event, the analysis and its outcome would be no different if conducted under the rubric of standing. Cf. Rakas v. Illinois, 439 U.S. 128, 139, 99 S.Ct. 421, 58 L.Ed.2d 387 (1978) ("We can think of no decided cases of this Court that would have come out differently had we concluded, as we do now, that the type of standing requirement discussed [in this case] is more properly subsumed under substantive Fourth Amendment doctrine.... The inquiry under either approach is the same. But we think the better analysis forthrightly focuses on the extent of a particular defendant's rights under the Fourth Amendment, rather than on any theoretically separate, but invariably intertwined concept of standing.").
For all of the reasons set forth above, we