DUARTE, J. —
These two consolidated cases involve the California Global Warming Solutions Act of 2006 (the Act) (Health & Saf. Code, § 38500 et seq.; see Stats. 2006, ch. 488; § 1, p. 3419, enacting Assem. Bill No. 32 (2005-2006 Reg. Sess.), popularly known as "AB 32").
Plaintiffs and allied amici curiae do not quarrel with the Act or its goals, but attack one part of the implementing regulations adopted by the State Air Resources Board (Board). (§ 39003.) The Board created a "cap-and-trade" program that includes the auction sale of some — but not all — GHG emissions allowances. Covered entities — generally large emitters of GHGs — must either surrender sufficient compliance instruments (emissions allowances or offset credits) to cover the amount of pollutants they discharge, or face monetary penalties or other negative consequences. (See § 38580; Cal. Code Regs., tit. 17, §§ 96012-96014.) The Board distributes some emissions allowances for free, but sells others at quarterly auctions. A covered entity that cannot reduce its emissions below the amount authorized by its free allowances and any offset credits it has obtained must purchase more allowances at the Board's quarterly auctions, or on a secondary market where allowances are sold or traded without Board control.
As in the trial court, on appeal plaintiffs assert (1) the auction sales exceed the Legislature's delegation of authority to the Board to design a market-based emissions reduction system, and (2) the revenue generated by the auction sales amounts to a tax that violates the two-thirds supermajority vote requirement of Proposition 13. (Cal. Const., art. XIII A, § 3.) The trial court rejected these two claims in a thorough written decision.
As for the second question, although our reasoning differs from that of the trial court, we agree that the auction sales do not equate to a tax. As we shall explain, the hallmarks of a tax are: (1) that it is compulsory and (2) that the payor receives nothing of particular value for payment of the tax, that is, the payor receives nothing of specific value for the tax itself. Contrary to plaintiffs' view, the purchase of allowances is a voluntary decision driven by business judgments as to whether it is more beneficial to the company to make the purchase than to reduce emissions. Reducing emissions reduces air pollution, and no entity has a vested right to pollute. Further, once purchased, either from the Board or the secondary market, the allowances are valuable, tradable commodities, conferring on the holder the privilege to pollute. Indeed, speculators have bought allowances seeking to profit from their sale, and as one party puts it, taxes do not attract volunteers. These twin aspects of the auction system, voluntary participation and purchase of a specific thing of value, preclude a finding that the auction system has the hallmarks of a tax.
The bulk of the briefing in the trial court and on appeal discusses the test to determine whether a purported regulatory fee is instead a tax subject to Proposition 13. The key authority is Sinclair Paint Co. v. State Bd. of Equalization (1997) 15 Cal.4th 866 [64 Cal.Rptr.2d 447, 937 P.2d 1350] (Sinclair Paint) and its progeny. However, as we explain in more detail, post, the Sinclair Paint test is not applicable herein, because the auction system is unlike other governmental charges that may raise the "tax or fee" question resolved thereby. The system is the voluntary purchase of a valuable commodity and not a tax under any test.
Accordingly, we shall affirm the judgments denying the petitions in these consolidated cases.
In 2006 the Legislature passed and Governor Schwarzenegger signed the Act, which requires that covered entities reduce GHG emissions to 1990 levels by the year 2020. The Act did not pass by a two-thirds vote of each legislative house.
A decision by another appellate court summarized the Act as follows:
The Board promulgated regulations that created a cap-and-trade system which included an auction component. (Cal. Code Regs., tit. 17, § 95801 et seq.; see Association of Irritated Residents v. State Air Resources Bd. (2012) 206 Cal.App.4th 1487, 1498, fn. 6 [143 Cal.Rptr.3d 65] (Residents) [describing how a cap-and-trade system works generally].) Its purpose "is to reduce emissions of [GHG] associated with entities identified in this article through the establishment, administration, and enforcement of the California Greenhouse Gas Cap-and-Trade Program by applying an aggregate [GHG] allowance budget on covered entities and providing a trading mechanism for compliance instruments." (Cal. Code Regs., tit. 17, § 95801.) Covered entities must reduce their emissions below a threshold point, or obtain offset credits or emissions allowances, either from the Board or the open market. The Board distributes some allowances for free, retains some in a price containment reserve to buffer against unexpectedly high auction prices, and auctions the rest periodically. After each compliance period, an entity must surrender
The regulatory system has been summarized briefly as follows:
Over time, the number of allowances (the "cap") will decrease — to reduce the total GHG emissions — which in theory should increase the value of remaining allowances. The auctions are expected to generate a great deal of money over the life of the program. By 2020, the Board plans to auction about half of the total allowances. The Board, citing materials in its unopposed request for judicial notice, asserts (without dispute by any party) that as of January 1, 2015, about 500 million allowances have been distributed for free, about 75 million have been auctioned, and that the price containment reserve has not been tapped.
At auction, there is a single round of sealed bidding, and winning bidders pay the "settlement" or "clearing" price, that is, the lowest price that will
In 2012 the Legislature passed four bills specifying how auction proceeds would be used to effectuate the Act, and diverting $500 million to the General Fund for related purposes. None passed by a two-thirds vote of each house.
The first suit was then filed by the California Chamber of Commerce and taxpayer Larry Dicke (jointly, CalChamber) against the Board, its members, and its executive officer, seeking to invalidate the auctions. The Environmental Defense Fund and Natural Resources Defense Council (jointly, EDF) intervened on behalf of the Board, and NAM intervened against the Board. In a second suit, Morning Star Packing Company (Morning Star) and other entities sued the same defendants, attacking the same regulations on essentially the same grounds.
The trial court deemed the two cases to be related, heard a joint oral argument, and issued a joint written decision rejecting the petitions.
Plaintiffs timely appealed in each case, and we accepted a stipulation by the parties to consolidate the appeals.
The first question resolved by the trial court was whether the Legislature vested the Board with discretion to create a distribution system that included an auction. We agree with the trial court that the Legislature conferred on the Board extremely broad discretion to craft a distribution system, and the fact the Legislature did not explicitly refer to an auction of allowances does not mean such an auction falls outside the scope of the delegation. Moreover, by later specifying how the proceeds of the auctions would be used, the Legislature effectively ratified the auction system created by the Board.
We have set out the general standard for determining the validity of administrative regulations in a prior case as follows:
In reviewing the regulations in this case, "We keep in mind that `the burden is on the party challenging a regulation to show its invalidity.'" (California School Bds. Assn. v. State Bd. of Education (2010) 191 Cal.App.4th 530, 544 [119 Cal.Rptr.3d 596] (California School Bds.); see Association of California Ins. Companies v. Jones (2017) 2 Cal.5th 376, 389 [212 Cal.Rptr.3d 395, 386 P.3d 1188] (Jones).)
The Board contends authorization to "[d]esign the regulations, including distribution of emissions allowances where appropriate," as well as authority to "adopt ... a system of market-based declining annual aggregate emission limits," subject to specified criteria, vested it with authority to sell some allowances at auction. (§ 38562, subds. (b)(1), (c); see § 7.) For the Board to prevail, we need only find that the auction regulations are "`consistent and not in conflict with'" the organic statute (Morning Star, supra, 201 Cal.App.4th at p. 747); they are.
NFIB contends an auction is not "reasonably necessary" to the Act's purposes and, somewhat similarly, CMTA argues the Board did not properly balance the relevant statutory factors. The Board aptly replies that such "argument conflates two distinct parts of the analysis of quasi-legislative
Plaintiffs launch a number of challenges to the conclusion that the legislature gave the Board sufficient discretion to adopt an auction component if it adopted a cap-and-trade program. The trial court summarized plaintiffs' arguments as follows: "Petitioners do not dispute that the cap-and-trade program requires emission allowances to be distributed in some manner. However, Petitioners argue that the text, structure, and legislative history of AB 32 show that the Legislature did not intend to authorize the sale of allowances. According to Petitioners, [the Board's] discretion is limited to choosing a method for distributing the allowances free of charge (or at least in a `revenue-neutral' manner). Petitioners raise the following arguments in support of their position: (1) the statute does not explicitly authorize [the Board] to auction allowances; (2) the legislative history includes no discussion of the term `auction;' (3) at the time of AB 32's enactment, most cap-and-trade program allowances were distributed for free; (4) construing AB 32 as authorizing the sale of allowances renders the administrative fee provision of the Act ([§] 38597) surplusage; (5) the chief sponsor of AB 32 (ostensibly) assured his colleagues on the floor of the Legislature, just before the vote, that the only funds to be generated under AB 32 were those generated by the administrative fee provision; (6) there is no guidance in AB 32 as to how to spend any auction revenues; and (7) the Legislature failed to enact a bill in 2009 that would have expressly authorized [the Board] to auction the allowances."
Because the briefing on appeal largely replicates these seven points, for convenience we will discuss them in the order assigned by the trial court. We then address an eighth point briefed on appeal, regarding the doctrine of constitutional doubt.
Contrary to the view posited by plaintiffs, there was no requirement that the Legislature explicitly authorize or even discuss emissions auctions in the Act in order for the Board to adopt regulations calling for such auctions.
In particular, "In adopting regulations ..., to the extent feasible and in furtherance of achieving the statewide greenhouse gas emissions limit, the state board shall do all of the following: [¶] (1) Design the regulations, including distribution of emissions allowances where appropriate, in a manner that is equitable, seeks to minimize costs and maximize the total benefits
The petitions do not dispute that the Act permitted the Board to adopt a cap-and-trade system, as opposed to, for example, a more traditional regulatory enforcement system sometimes referred to as a "command-and-control" system. But once such a system was chosen, the Board had to decide who would capture the value of distributed allowances, the covered entities or the state. As the trial court explained, "Allowances can be allocated free of charge, sold by the regulating authority through an auction or direct sale, or allocated by some combination of these methods. If covered entities receive the allowances free of charge, they capture the value associated with the allowances. If allowances are sold or auctioned, the government captures the value created by the cap. Whatever the allocation, whoever receives the initial allocation of allowances will receive a `windfall' equal to the value created by the constraint."
The Legislature presumably knew that if the Board chose a cap-and-trade system, some entity would capture the constraint value, but did not specify the recipient. As Burtraw points out, the idea of auctioning some or all cap-and-trade allowances long had been debated by scholars. (See McAllister, The Overallocation Problem In Cap-And-Trade: Moving Toward Stringency
We agree. The Act itself references the climate action team. (See § 38501, subd. (i).) The team's report — provided to the Legislature before the Act was passed — explains that "[w]hen allowances are given to entities covered by the cap, those entities receive something of value: the emission allowances. When the allowances are auctioned, the government collects a portion of the value of the allowances in the amounts paid in the auction." (Climate Action Team, Report to Gov. Schwarzenegger and the Legislature (Mar. 2006) p. 74 <http://www.climatechange.ca.gov/climate_action_team/reports/2006report/ 2006-04-03_FINAL_CAT_REPORT.PDF> [as of Apr. 6, 2017].) It also explains a hybrid approach, where some allowances are sold and some are auctioned, the model ultimately adopted by the Board. Thus, the Legislature knew that an auction was a possible component of a cap-and-trade program. If the Legislature had wanted to direct who would receive the constraint
Plaintiffs assert that the power to create a program generating billions of dollars in revenue would not have been delegated to an agency without explicit discussion, and no such discussion appears in the legislative record. (See In re Christian S. (1994) 7 Cal.4th 768, 782 [30 Cal.Rptr.2d 33, 872 P.2d 574] ["We are not persuaded the Legislature would have silently, or at best obscurely, decided so important and controversial a public policy matter"]; Ailanto Properties, Inc. v. City of Half Moon Bay (2006) 142 Cal.App.4th 572, 589 [48 Cal.Rptr.3d 340] ["The Legislature `does not, one might say, hide elephants in mouseholes'"]; FDA v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp. (2000) 529 U.S. 120, 160 [146 L.Ed.2d 121, 151, 120 S.Ct. 1291] ["we are confident that Congress could not have intended to delegate a decision of such economic and political significance to an agency in so cryptic a fashion"].) Plaintiffs' point is that the statutory authority to create a "distribution" system could not encompass a multi-billion dollar administratively created program. NAM adds that the dearth of explicit discussion "is particularly stark because" of the Legislature's unique role in collecting and distributing state revenue. (See In re Attorney Discipline System (1998) 19 Cal.4th 582, 595 [79 Cal.Rptr.2d 836, 967 P.2d 49] ["`the power to collect and appropriate the revenue of the State is one peculiarly within the discretion of the Legislature'"].)
Second, the Act reflects the Legislature's desire for a massive, historic, and immediate change in behavior regarding GHG emissions. The Legislature could have spent many years considering, analyzing, and dictating the best way to achieve its ambitious goals. But that delay itself would have impeded the goals. Instead, the Legislature chose to pass a flexible bill, with the understanding that the Board, as the agency with expertise in air quality matters, was better equipped to study the problem and design a program to effectuate those goals. (See Jones, supra, 2 Cal.5th at p. 390.) Viewed in this light, the lack of explicit legislative discussion of one sub-component of one possible emissions reduction system (that is, adoption of a cap-and-trade program rather than a command-and-control program) is of no moment.
Plaintiffs contend that other cap-and-trade programs distribute all allowances for free, or are revenue neutral, or arose with explicit legislative authorization for auctions. We accept these asserted facts as true.
But the fact that other methods of distribution were possible is not compelling, or even noteworthy. As the trial court pointed out, our Legislature did not mandate a cap-and-trade program, therefore it had no need to detail the minutiae of such a program. While the Legislature knew how other jurisdictions tackled GHG emissions problems, it was not compelled to follow in lockstep. Neither was the Board.
Although the parties discuss at length an administrative fee provision in the Act, we find that provision irrelevant to the legislative delegation question.
Plaintiffs contend that the existence of this fee provision precluded the Board from generating any other revenue under the Act by any other mechanism. We disagree.
Section 38597 is a pedestrian measure to pay for the costs of implementing the Act. (See Cal. Code Regs., tit. 17, §§ 95200-95207.) This fee has no bearing on the delegation question. As the trial court put it: "It only proves the Legislature intended to ensure [the Board] could collect fees to pay for the administrative costs directly incurred in carrying out the provisions of [the Act]."
Plaintiffs attempt to bolster their contention regarding the administrative fee provision just discussed by referencing floor statements made by the author of the Act, former Assembly Speaker Fabian Nuñez.
The enrolled bill report prepared by the Board states: "Fee Authority. AB 32 grants [the Board] the authority to adopt a schedule of fees to be paid by regulated GHG emission sources for program administration. Republicans feel that the fee authority language provides [the Board] with carte blanche authority to collect fees on anything including imposing a tax on sport utility vehicles (SUV). To clear confusion, Speaker Nuñez added a letter to the file to clarify that the fee is limited to [the Board's] direct implementation costs only." (State Air Resources Bd., Enrolled Bill Rep. on Assem. Bill No. 32 (2005-2006 Reg. Sess.).) The referenced letter by Speaker Nuñez referred only to the administrative fee provision, section 38597.
A later portion of the enrolled bill report, discussing expected fiscal impact, states in part: "While [the Board] has the authority to adopt a schedule of fees to be paid by regulated GHG emitters, two matters need to be resolved before this authority can be exercised. First, the Governor made a policy commitment not to impose additional costs on industry beyond their own costs of compliance. Second, collection mechanisms need to be created (i.e. through mandatory reporting regulations which [come] in 2008). Similarly, regulatory development activity needs to get off the ground before the universe of regulated facilities and the appropriate schedule of fees can be determined." (State Air Resources Bd., Enrolled Bill Rep. on Assem. Bill No. 32 (2005-2006 Reg. Sess.).) But when this passage was drafted, it was not known whether or not the Board would create a cap-and-trade program at all, therefore the omission to discuss the then-hypothetical impact of auctioning allowances is understandable. Nor does the Governor's purported policy commitment change the Act.
CalChamber refers to the Governor's proposed signing statement, prepared by the Board. It provides in part: "I want to join the Speaker in assuring that any fees that may be collected from sources of global warming emissions will only be used to support the essential and direct program costs associated with the bill." This, too, appears to be reference to the administrative fee provision.
Further, as we explain in part II, post, the auction sales are not "fees," they are the purchase price of a valuable commodity, an emissions allowance, therefore discussion of limiting fees in the legislative record is unpersuasive.
In 2012 the Legislature passed four bills that specified how the auction proceeds would be used to effectuate the Act (see 618). In echo of their earlier argument, plaintiffs observe that the Act itself did not address the disposition of auction revenue. But there was no need for the Act to address the disposition of auction proceeds, because it was then unknown whether the Board would create a cap-and-trade program, rather than what the record calls a "command-and-control" program, that would have mandated emissions reductions by regulatory order. (See Alliance of Small Emitters/Metals Industry v. South Coast Air Quality Management Dist. (1997) 60 Cal.App.4th 55, 57-59 & fn. 1 [70 Cal.Rptr.2d 54] [describing an early "command and control" program converted to a market-based cap-and-trade program, and making reference to the theoretical use of an auction system, although that program did not use an auction].)
The limited circumstances under which an unenacted bill is relevant, such as where the Legislature has studied an issue or court ruling and thereafter declines to change the law or adopt a new proposal (see, e.g., Western Land Office, Inc. v. Cervantes (1985) 175 Cal.App.3d 724, 741 [220 Cal.Rptr. 784]; Seibert v. Sears, Roebuck & Co. (1975) 45 Cal.App.3d 1, 17-19 [120 Cal.Rptr. 233]), or passes a bill without a specific provision contained in a prior version of the bill (see, e.g., People v. Hunt (1999) 74 Cal.App.4th 939, 947-948 [88 Cal.Rptr.2d 524]), are not present here. Instead, as in the general run of cases, it may be said only that "the failure of the Legislature to enact the proposed bill, in one form or another, is some evidence that the Legislature does not consider it necessary or proper or expedient to enact such legislation." (Sterling v. City of Oakland (1962) 208 Cal.App.2d 1, 6, 24 Cal.Rptr. 696.)
Thus, we find that the proposed but unenacted 2009 bill does not assist plaintiffs.
But the canon has a narrow application, as we have recently reemphasized: "The constitutional doubt canon applies if and only if the statute is `realistically susceptible of two interpretations and the interpretation to be rejected must raise grave and doubtful constitutional questions.' [Citation.] It `is a tool for choosing between competing plausible interpretations of a statutory text, resting on the reasonable presumption that Congress [or, mutatis mutandis, the Legislature,] did not intend the alternative which raises serious constitutional doubts.'" (Siskiyou County Farm Bureau v. Department of Fish & Wildlife (2015) 237 Cal.App.4th 411, 445 [188 Cal.Rptr.3d 141] (Siskiyou).)
Under this standard, we find no basis to apply the interpretive canon herein, either as to the delegation question or the Proposition 13 question (see pt. II, post). We have not been offered alternative, plausible, statutory interpretations from which to choose.
For all of the above reasons, we agree with the trial court that plaintiffs have not carried their burden (see California School Bds., supra, 191 Cal.App.4th at p. 544) to show the auction portion of the regulations exceeds the scope of legislative delegation.
The four bills passed in 2012 (see 618) show that whatever the collective intention of the 2006 Legislature, the 2012 Legislature affirmatively ratified the Board's auction system.
Thus, even were we to find that the Act did not authorize the regulations adopted by the Board, the Legislature surely ratified them in 2012 by directing how the money is spent. (See Professional Engineers in California Government v. Schwarzenegger (2010) 50 Cal.4th 989, 1000 [116 Cal.Rptr.3d 480, 239 P.3d 1186] [although the Governor, at the time he acted, lacked legislative authority to furlough state employees, "the Legislature's 2009 enactment of the revisions to the 2008 Budget Act operated to ratify the use of the two-day-a-month furlough program"]; see also, e.g., Morning Star, supra, 201 Cal.App.4th at p. 748 ["there is strong evidence the Legislature knows full well" about a regulatory interpretation "and the Legislature is fine with that interpretation. This is strong evidence" the regulation does not conflict with statutory law].) The legislative will to ratify the Board's auction system by passage of the 2012 statutes is clear, and we need not discuss it further.
Morning Star — but not the other plaintiffs — contends that any reliance on the 2012 statutes to ratify the auction component of the regulations would be invalid under Proposition 26. We disagree.
Proposition 26 was passed by the People, in the exercise of their reserved initiative powers, in response to the perceived efforts of state and local governments to bypass the spirit of Proposition 13 and related measures, in particular by couching exactions as regulatory fees exempt from a supermajority vote. (See Schmeer v. County of Los Angeles (2013) 213 Cal.App.4th 1310, 1317-1326 [153 Cal.Rptr.3d 352] (Schmeer); Voter Information Guide, Gen. Elec. (Nov. 2, 2010) text of Prop. 26, § 1, p. 114.)
However, Proposition 26, passed in 2010, is not generally retrospective in operation. (See Brooktrails Township Community Services Dist. v. Board of Supervisors of Mendocino County (2013) 218 Cal.App.4th 195, 205-207 [159 Cal.Rptr.3d 424].) Thus, it cannot affect the Act itself, passed in 2006, and no party — not even Morning Star — contends otherwise.
The arguable relevance is the language broadening the definition of a tax and changing the burden of proof. Morning Star contends that Proposition 26 bars the use of the 2012 legislation to ratify the auction regulations, because the Board has not proven the auction charges are not taxes as defined by Proposition 26.
But the 2012 legislation did not change the cost of allowances, whether purchased at auction or on the secondary market; it specified how the proceeds of auctions sales would be handled. Thus, no "state statute" was changed in any way that could possibly increase "any ... charge ... of any kind imposed by the State" as provided by Proposition 26. (Cal. Const., art. XIII A, § 3; see Western States Petroleum Assn. v. Board of Equalization (2013) 57 Cal.4th 401, 423-424 [159 Cal.Rptr.3d 702, 304 P.3d 188] [regulation changing method of assessing certain property that resulted in a higher bill for some taxpayers was not a "state statute" within the meaning of Prop. 13]; Southern California Edison Co. v. Public Utilities Com. (2014) 227 Cal.App.4th 172, 198 [173 Cal.Rptr.3d 120] ["Proposition 26 plainly defines a tax as a `change in state statute which results in ... a higher tax' [citation], not [an agency's] decision" that resulted in a fee].)
Accordingly, Proposition 26 interposes no bar to using the 2012 statutes to evince a legislative ratification of the auction regulations adopted by the
The second question presented to the trial court by plaintiffs was whether the auction system is a tax subject to Proposition 13. The trial court found this to be a close question in part because of the novelty of "the charges at issue," but ruled the system was more like a regulatory fee than a tax, applying principles derived from Sinclair Paint and related cases, while acknowledging no prior case precisely governed this case.
Although we disagree with its method of analysis, we agree with the trial court's ultimate conclusion that the auction system does not equate to a tax subject to Proposition 13. This is so for two interrelated reasons: First, the purchase of emissions allowances, whether directly from the Board at auction or on the secondary market, is a business-driven decision, not a governmentally compelled decision; second, unlike any other tax to which we have been referred by the parties, the purchase of an emissions allowance conveys a valuable property interest — the privilege to pollute California's air — that may be freely sold or traded on the secondary market. Thus, the trial court correctly identified the two facts we find make the auction system unlike a tax, (1) participation is voluntary, and (2) entities receive a thing of value in exchange for obtaining allowances.
We discuss the trial court's thoughtful decision in some detail. Its reasoning drives much of the parties' briefing and accurately outlines several relevant points.
The language of Proposition 13 most relevant to this case is as follows: "[A]ny changes in State taxes enacted for the purpose of increasing rates or changes in methods of computation must be imposed by an Act passed by not less than two-thirds of all members elected to each of the two houses of the Legislature...." (Cal. Const., art. XIIIA, former § 3, italics added, added by initiative, Primary Elec. (June 6, 1978), popularly known as the "Jarvis-Gann initiative" see [Mills v. County of Trinity (1980) 108 Cal.App.3d 656, 658 [166 Cal.Rptr. 674] (Mills)], and sometimes referred to as the "People's Initiative to Limit Property Taxation," [see Farm Bureau, supra, 51 Cal.4th at p. 428, fn. 1].)
Proposition 13 was designed to provide tax relief, but purported loopholes were found, leading to later initiative measures to limit the use of regulatory fees in lieu of taxes. (See Schmeer, supra, 213 Cal.App.4th at pp. 1317-1326 [discussing history of various subsequent measures].) Sinclair Paint set forth rules to evaluate purported regulatory fees to determine if they were in reality taxes subject to Proposition 13.
Sinclair Paint involved a program to remediate the effects of lead, funded by fees imposed on entities who contributed to lead contamination. (Sinclair Paint, supra, 15 Cal.4th at p. 872.) The court held the act "imposes bona fide regulatory fees. It requires manufacturers and other persons whose products have exposed children to lead contamination to bear a fair share of the cost of mitigating the adverse health effects their products created in the community. Viewed as a `mitigating effects' measure, it is comparable in character to
"Sinclair Paint stated that regulatory fees that do not exceed the reasonable cost of providing the services for which the fees are charged and are not levied for any unrelated revenue purposes" were not subject to section 4 of Proposition 13, which defined "special taxes" and which the court viewed as bearing on the proper application of section 3 of Proposition 13, applicable to state taxes. (Schmeer, supra, 213 Cal.App.4th at pp. 1321-1322; see Sinclair Paint, supra, 15 Cal.4th at pp. 873-880.)
Acknowledging that the word "tax" has no fixed meaning (see Mills, supra, 108 Cal.App.3d at p. 660), Sinclair Paint found the lead paint fee should be analyzed as a regulatory fee imposed under the police power, which is not deemed a special tax provided that the fees (1) do not exceed the reasonable cost of accommodating the activity and (2) are not levied for unrelated revenue purposes. (Sinclair Paint, supra, 15 Cal.4th at pp. 875-876; see California Building Industry Assn. v. San Joaquin Valley Air Pollution Control Dist. (2009) 178 Cal.App.4th 120, 131 [100 Cal.Rptr.3d 204] (Building Industry).)
Sinclair Paint left open the possibility the challenger could show either that the amount of fees "exceeded the reasonable cost of providing the protective services for which the fees were charged, or that the fees were levied for unrelated revenue purposes" or "that no clear nexus exists between its products and childhood lead poisoning, or that the amount of the fees bore no reasonable relationship to the social or economic `burdens' its operations generated." (Sinclair Paint, supra, 15 Cal.4th at p. 881; see California Assn. of Prof. Scientists v. Department of Fish & Game (2000) 79 Cal.App.4th 935, 945 [94 Cal.Rptr.2d 535] (Scientists) [state must show "(1) the estimated costs of the service or regulatory activity, and (2) the basis for determining the manner in which the costs are apportioned, so that charges allocated to a payor bear a fair or reasonable relationship to the payor's burdens on or benefits from the regulatory activity"].)
The trial court correctly observed that, generally, taxes are compulsory, "enforced contributions ... for the support of the government." But, acknowledging that the term "tax" had no fixed meaning, the trial court found cases "distinguishing `taxes' from `fees' provide helpful guidance. The cases have recognized several general categories of compulsory fees or charges that are distinguishable from taxes.... These categories are: (1) special assessments and related business charges, (2) development fees, (3) user fees,
The trial court outlined four points militating in favor of finding a tax, as follows:
(1) The "charges are not entirely voluntary" because the "covered entity either must reduce its GHG emissions to zero — which, generally speaking, is impractical or impossible — or acquire allowances." Further, the court thought "the purchase of allowances is little different from an emissions tax."
(2) "[A]n allowance has no value independent of the regulatory scheme. While those who purchase allowances may be said to acquire a `benefit' vis-à-vis other covered entities, they do not acquire any `benefit' vis-à-vis other (non-covered) entities, which retain the right to freely emit GHGs without the need for acquiring any allowances."
(3) "[T]he amount charged is determined, at least in part, by government fiat. Although the auction relies on bidding, there is only one round of bidding, using sealed bids, and the auction operator will not accept bids that fall below a pre-set `auction reserve price.' The auction reserve price is a `price floor' set by `government fiat.' In addition, sales of allowances from the `containment reserve' are sold at prices fixed by the government. Moreover, by definition, the government has artificially constrained the supply of allowances — indeed, this is the very purpose of the `cap.' Thus, it is not factually accurate for [the Board] to claim that the price ... is determined by the `market.'"
Next, the trial court outlined four correlative points weighing against finding a tax:
(1) The allowances have "economic value and can be traded," and "[i]f the atmosphere's capacity to assimilate GHGs is viewed as a limited public resource, selling emissions allowances can be analogized to selling a right to use a public resource, similar to a hunting [or] fishing license, a mineral extraction permit, or a wireless electromagnetic spectrum license."
(2) "[T]he purchase of allowances is, in some respects, voluntary. Because covered entities receive a significant portion of the allowances for free, covered entities have some control over when, and perhaps if, they participate in sales of allowances. Covered entities may be able to reduce their GHG emissions to reduce or completely avoid their need to purchase ... allowances. Further, [they] are not compelled to purchase allowances from the [Board]." (Fn. omitted.)
(3) "[T]he price of allowances is determined at least in part by market forces."
(4) The proceeds will further the regulatory purposes of the Act "and the charges were imposed (ostensibly, at least) for regulatory purposes."
Ultimately, the trial court found (1) "the primary purpose of the charges is regulatory," (2) the "fees collected will not exceed the costs of the regulatory activities" because revenue will advance the Act's goals, and (3) given that "the charges are a byproduct of the implementation of a regulatory program"
We shall first explain why we are not bound to apply the Sinclair Paint test to assess the legality of the auction system. (Pt. IIC.1., post.) We then describe the twin traditional hallmarks of a tax; a tax is (1) a compulsory exaction that (2) confers nothing of particular benefit to the payor. (Pt. IIC.2., post.) We next explain why the purchase of allowance credits, either directly via Board auction or indirectly via the secondary market, is not compulsory. (Pt. IIC.3., post.) We then explain why the emissions allowances constitute valuable property rights — albeit only as between private parties. This valuable property right consists of the privilege to pollute California's air, a privilege no party has a vested right to continue doing. (Pt. IIC.4., post.) We conclude that the auction system created by the Board is part of the market-based distribution system the Board was charged with developing, and the choice to participate in that market does not equate to a tax payment. (Pt. IIC.5., post.) Finally, we briefly address the use of the auction revenue, discussed in detail in the briefing, and explain that we need not decide the propriety of any specific expenditure in this case. (Pt. IIC.6., post.)
Morning Star points to Senate Bill No. 957 (2011-2012 Reg. Sess.), a proposed budget act, which in part would have found "the funds generated by the [cap-and-trade] program are regulatory fees that conform with" Sinclair Paint. (Sen. Bill No. 957 (2011-2012 Reg. Sess.) as introduced Jan. 10, 2012, § 15.11, subd. (c).) But Senate Bill No. 957 died and therefore is meaningless. (See Order of Conductors v. Swan (1947) 329 U.S. 520, 529 [91 S.Ct. 471, 478, 67 S.Ct. 405].) Instead, the Budget Act of 2012 (Assem. Bill. No. 1464 (2011-2012 Reg. Sess.)) included language ensuring the money would be spent on projects to reduce GHG, and contains no reference to Sinclair Paint. (See Stats. 2012, ch. 21, § 15.11.)
In a related claim, CalChamber points to a Legislative Counsel opinion purportedly concluding any auction system would have to pass muster under Sinclair Paint. Although two Legislative Analyst reports in the record refer to such a Legislative Counsel opinion, the opinion is not in the record, and the Legislative Counsel's supervising librarian has advised this court that no publicly available opinion on that subject has been issued. Thus, although CalChamber seeks support in that purported opinion, because its reasoning is unknown, it lacks any persuasive value. (Cf. Pacific Gas & Electric Co. v. Zuckerman (1987) 189 Cal.App.3d 1113, 1135, 1136 [234 Cal.Rptr. 630] [the value of expert opinion rests "in the factors considered and the reasoning employed"].)
In short, we reject the claim that Sinclair Paint controls this case.
First, "The word tax, in its common acceptation, denotes some compulsory exaction, which a government makes upon persons or property within its
Such voluntariness concerns have arisen in development fee cases. One case involved a local scheme "referred to as indirect source review (ISR) ... intended to encourage developers to reduce indirect pollution, i.e., mobile source emissions, caused by new development projects. Under ISR, the developer can reduce emissions by incorporating pollution-reducing features in the project, or by paying a fee to fund offsite projects that will reduce emissions, or by a combination of the two." (Building Industry, supra, 178 Cal.App.4th at pp. 124-125.) "A developer can accomplish the required emission reductions onsite by incorporating measures to reduce vehicle miles traveled, vehicle trips and/or areawide sources of emissions such as fireplaces, wood stoves and landscape equipment. Alternatively, the emissions can be reduced through paying a fee to fund offsite emission reducing projects. Finally, the developer can use a combination of onsite emission reduction measures and a fee to fund offsite emission reduction projects." (Id. at p. 128, italics added.) It has also been held that "Whereas taxes are compulsory in nature, development fees are imposed only if a developer elects to develop." (California Bldg. Industry Assn. v. Governing Bd. (1988) 206 Cal.App.3d 212, 236 [253 Cal.Rptr. 497], italics added.) Similarly, "Regulatory fees are not compulsory. Rather, fee payers have some control both over when, and if, they pay any fee, i.e., when or if they elect to engage in a regulated activity, and/or the amount of the fee they are compelled to pay. For example, fee payers can modify their conduct to pollute less or consume less water." (Building Industry, supra, 178 Cal.App.4th at p. 132, italics added; see Scientists, supra, 79 Cal.App.4th at pp. 949-950 [describing a prior regulatory fee case, where it was important that "the payors had some control over the amount of the regulatory fee they were compelled to pay by the degree to which their respective activities impacted the environment. The more they polluted the air and consumed the water, the more they paid"].)
Second, as Witkin succinctly puts it, "no compensation is given to the taxpayer except by way of governmental protection and other general benefits." (9 Witkin, Summary of Cal. Law (10th ed. 2005) Taxation, § 1, p. 25, italics added.) Taxation "promises nothing to the person taxed beyond what may be anticipated from an administration of the laws for individual protection and the general public good." (71 Am.Jur.2d, supra, State and Local Taxation, § 6, p. 307; see 1 Cooley, supra, Taxes, Their Nature and Kinds, p. 3 [in exchange for enforced contributions, "the state is supposed to make adequate and full compensation, in the protection which it gives to his life, liberty and property, and in the increase to the value of his possessions, by the use to which the money contributed is applied" (fn. omitted)]; Arnold v.
Our Supreme Court has similarly characterized the general nature of taxation: "Ordinarily taxes are imposed for revenue purposes and not `in return for a specific benefit conferred or privilege granted.'" (Farm Bureau, supra, 51 Cal.4th at p. 437, quoting Sinclair Paint, supra, 15 Cal.4th at p. 874.)
Thus, in considering whether the auction system represents a tax of some sort, we first consider whether participation therein by covered entities is compulsory, and then consider whether and to what extent participants receive anything of particular value for their payment.
Plaintiffs and allied amici curiae posit the view that participation in the auction sales or secondary emissions allowances market is compulsory. We reject this view.
As intervener EDF points out, "Regulated entities can comply with the cap-and-trade rule without participating in the auction or reserve, including by reducing emissions, purchasing allowances from third parties, using banked allowances from prior years, and purchasing [or earning] emission offsets (credits generated from voluntary emission reductions made outside the capped sectors)."
As shown by materials in the Board's initial and unopposed request for judicial notice, noncovered entities buy allowances, either to speculate, or to retire them and reduce emissions. (See 1 New Palgrave Dict. of Economics & Law (1998) p. 127 ["The bids in the US pollution-rights auctions also revealed another kind of valuation. Environmental groups submitted bids; by winning the bidding they ensured that those [licenses] would not be utilized"].) NAM concedes that some nonemitters buy allowances "to retire them." That fact cuts sharply against the view that the auction is compulsory, because, as EDF notes, "Taxes do not attract volunteers."
It is not necessary to obtain extra allowances or offset credits unless an entity chooses to pollute beyond a certain level, something the government does not compel it to do. (See Building Industry, supra, 178 Cal.App.4th at p. 132 [entities "can modify their conduct to pollute less"].) Indeed, the whole point of the Act is to stop entities from polluting excessively.
Morning Star, echoed by other plaintiffs and allied amici curiae, argues that in order to stay in business in California it must obtain a sufficient number of
In support of its petition, Morning Star submitted a declaration by an employee, which we have referred to as the "Rabo" declaration in our request for supplemental briefing. Taking its contents as true, which we shall do for purposes of this opinion,
Janet Rabo is an economist employed by Morning Star, and her duties include analyzing data "in connection with domestic tomato processing plants and farming operations as well [as] international economics affecting Morning Star's businesses." A key responsibility is ensuring compliance with the Act, including bidding at auctions to obtain allowances. Morning Star has three tomato processing plants in California that account for 25 percent of California processed tomato production and 40 percent of the nationwide ingredients for tomato paste and diced tomatoes. Morning Star uses natural gas to process tomatoes, but does not receive enough free allowances, and Rabo knows of no "cost-effective" means to reduce emissions. In her view, purchasing allowances on the open market will "be far more expensive" than purchasing them at auction from the Board. In her ultimate view — which is in
The fact that some businesses may choose not to participate in the program and may instead choose to leave the state is a potential side effect which the Act itself contemplates. (See § 38562, subd. (b)(8).) But the possibility of leakage lends no weight to the argument that the cap-and-trade scheme amounts to a tax. A number of requirements for businesses, whether taxes, safety regulations, minimum wage statutes, or command-and-control pollution control regulations, might cause a particular business to become unprofitable. This unfortunate reality does not translate into a compelled purchase of auction credits.
Compliance instruments are "demanded only as often as a party of his own accord, chooses to perform certain acts." (People v. Naglee, supra, 1 Cal. at p. 253.) This is similar to the rationale supporting exaction of developer fees, which require a developer to dedicate land or pay impact fees for the privilege of new development, which exactions are not viewed as compulsory. (See Trent Meredith, Inc. v. City of Oxnard (1981) 114 Cal.App.3d 317, 328 [170 Cal.Rptr. 685] ["Even though the developer cannot legally develop without satisfying the condition precedent, he voluntarily decides whether to develop or not to develop"]; Kern County Farm Bureau v. County of Kern
Albeit not explicitly, plaintiffs seem to rely on the foundational premise that covered entities have some vested right to continue polluting California's air without paying for the privilege to do so. Therefore, in their view, compelling them to incur costs for engaging in "business as usual" is somehow compulsory. For example, Morning Star asserts that "the only `benefit' successful bidders receive here is the requirement to pay for what they had been doing before for free." Although this observation may well be accurate, Morning Star does not support its theory that bidders ever had the right to pollute for free. They did not. As EDF points out, the Board could instead have imposed a declining cap on Morning Star's emissions under a command-and-control system and ordered Morning Star to stop emitting GHGs beyond a certain amount.
As another court observed: "Here it appears the Oil Companies are asking us to determine they have a fundamental vested right to release gasoline vapors while dispensing fuel to their customers. How are we to answer the public, on the other hand, who assert a fundamental vested right to breathe clean air? If either exists, it must be the latter. We are not presented with the enforcement of a rule which effectively drives the Oil Companies out of business. At most it puts an economic burden on them increasing the cost of doing business." (Mobil Oil Corp. v. Superior Court (1976) 59 Cal.App.3d 293, 305 [130 Cal.Rptr. 814], italics added (Mobil Oil); see Building Industry, supra, 178 Cal.App.4th at p. 132.) As we explain more fully in the next section, the right to pollute is a valuable privilege for which a cost may properly be imposed.
Under the Board's regulatory definitions, "`Property Right' means any type of right to specific property whether it is personal or real property, tangible or intangible." (Cal. Code Regs., tit. 17, § 95802, subd. (a)(299).) A compliance instrument is an offset credit or emissions allowance. (Id., § 95802, subd. (a)(69).) A substantive regulation provides: "Each compliance instrument issued by the Executive Officer represents a limited authorization to emit up to one metric ton in CO
Although, when read in isolation, these regulations could be interpreted to mean that emissions allowances do not constitute property or a property right, when examined in context it becomes clear that this passage refers only to property rights as against the state, not rights as between private parties. A "property right" can mean different things in different contexts. For example, a winemaker received federal "COLAs" or certificates of label approval, which purported to allow the use of "Napa" on wine labels where the wine was produced from grapes not grown in Napa Valley. A California statute prohibited the use of misleading geographic names on wine labels. (See Bronco Wine Co. v. Jolly (2004) 33 Cal.4th 943, 950-956 [17 Cal.Rptr.3d 180, 95 P.3d 422] [holding state labeling statute was not preempted by federal law].) We upheld the state statute as against a claim that it effected a taking of a property right conferred by the federal COLAs. (Bronco Wine Co. v. Jolly (2005) 129 Cal.App.4th 988, 1029-1033 [29 Cal.Rptr.3d 462] (Bronco Wine).) In doing so, we distinguished between property rights for purposes of a takings analysis and property rights for purposes of a procedural due process analysis, finding that the latter embraces a broader conception of property rights:
This distinction between property rights for purposes of a takings analysis — that is, property rights as between the government and an individual — and property rights as between private individuals, has been articulated in cases analogous to this one.
We have previously held that: "In California, the right to pollute the air can be bought and sold. Air quality management districts have created a valuable commodity, the emission reduction credit (ERC). The ERC is evidenced by transferable certificates approved, banked, and issued by the districts. Simply put, a polluter who pollutes less can sell the ERC to allow the purchaser to pollute more." (Jopson v. Feather River Air Quality Management Dist. (2003) 108 Cal.App.4th 492, 494 [133 Cal.Rptr.2d 506], italics added (Jopson).) The regulatory system in Jopson follows the cap-and-trade model adopted by the Board, rather than a command-and-control model, and in that model, transferability of allowances conveyed value.
Similarly, by statute federal Clean Air Act (42 U.S.C. § 7401 et seq.) allowances — analogous to GHG allowances under the Board's regulations — are said to confer no property rights: "An allowance allocated under this subchapter is a limited authorization to emit sulfur dioxide in accordance with the provisions of this subchapter. Such allowance does not constitute a property right." (42 U.S.C.A. § 7651b(f), italics added.) However, despite this
Thus, the regulations declaring that the allowances confer no property rights preclude an allowance holder from asserting a takings claim against the State, but the free alienability of the allowances means they are of value to the holder. Indeed, that is the whole point of the "trade" part of the cap-and-trade system, the free alienability of the allowances as between private parties. (See Jopson, supra, 108 Cal.App.4th at p. 494.) That makes them property for due process purposes, because "[t]he right to exclude others, and to sell, assign or otherwise transfer ownership are traditional hallmarks of property." (Bronco Wine, supra, 129 Cal.App.4th at p. 1030; cf. Conti v. U.S. (Fed.Cir. 2002) 291 F.3d 1334, 1340-1341 [where holder could not transfer fishing permit, no property interest found].) It is difficult to see why any entity would be willing to trade in allowances in the first instance, if the allowances did not constitute property of any kind.
As discussed by the parties in their supplemental briefing, this point was addressed during the rulemaking process. The Board's initial statement of reasons states in part that "property rights cannot attach to the compliance instruments because, in the event of federal preemption in the cap-and-trade market or other conditions, California must have the ability to revoke the compliance instruments without creating a loss to the people of California." (Italics added.) The Board's final statement of reasons confirmed the need for the ability to revoke compliance instruments to protect the state.
As we have described, no covered entity is forced to buy emissions allowances, and such allowances are things of value to the owner. These two aspects of the auction system are alien to any reasonable conception of a "tax," as that term has been used at common law and through Sinclair Paint and beyond. As we have explained, the twin hallmarks of a tax are that it is compulsory, and that it conveys nothing of particular value to the payor. The auction system meets neither of these conditions, and therefore it is not a tax.
The parties offer hypotheticals which we find unpersuasive. Many Californians are compelled to pay income taxes, but despite this compulsion receive no particular thing of value. Similarly, a person may choose to buy a pencil, knowing sales tax will be added to the price, but the buyer receives nothing of particular value for the tax. Neither of these scenarios is akin to buying an emissions allowance, whereby a party chooses to purchase a valuable right to pollute. (Cf. 1 Cooley, supra, Taxes, Their Nature & Kinds, pp. 1-3; 9 Witkin Summary of Cal. Law, supra, Taxation, § 1, p, 25.)
Morning Star argues the payments are not voluntary because they merely allow it to do what it is already doing. That argument might have relevance if Morning Star had a vested legal right to continue polluting. As we have discussed ante, it does not. (See Communities, supra, 48 Cal.4th at p. 324 ["the boiler permits give ConocoPhillips no vested right to pollute the air at any particular level"]; Mobil Oil, supra, 59 Cal.App.3d at p. 305.) Thus, it is not accurate to liken the auction system to payment for the privilege to stay in business in California. It is a payment for the privilege to pollute the air in California.
Some plaintiffs posit that if we find the auction regulations are not a tax, the Legislature could construct similar ways to extract money from Californians and evade Proposition 13 (and perhaps other initiatives). For example, they hypothesize the state could create a cap-and-trade program for vehicle mileage: Each registered vehicle would be given a periodic allowance, and would have to obtain additional allowances to exceed the base allotment. This would reduce road decay and reduce GHG emissions. NAM, echoed by CalChamber, states: "No one would doubt that such a scheme would impose a tax on driving." Putting aside Proposition 26, which is not implicated by this case, we do doubt it. After all, the state could instead enact a command-and-control rationing system for drivers, but the hypothetical provides a
Plaintiffs and allied amici curiae contend that under various statutes the money — raised by "an unelected, politically-appointed state board" — is being used to support diverse programs that would otherwise be paid for from general fund sources. Their point is the Legislature has effectively adopted a cash cow sired by the Board and is milking it for a purportedly endless number of programs that have at best a tenuous connection to the discharge of GHGs by covered entities. At oral argument this was referred to pejoratively as a "slush fund."
We conclude this issue is not ripe, but we address it briefly to explain why it is important to decouple the issues of generation of revenue from the expenditure thereof, when evaluating whether a payment to the government equates to a tax.
In the trial court, Morning Star argued — without contradiction — that a bill "requires [a] set aside [of] 25% of [auction revenues] to projects benefitting disadvantaged communities, and at least 10% of that fund must go toward projects actually located in such communities.... Although it may be a good thing to benefit disadvantaged communities ... there is little if any relationship that has been established between reducing greenhouse gas emissions and benefitting disadvantaged communities." Plaintiffs also reference certain 2014 legislation allocating revenues to a wide variety of programs. We granted Morning Star's request for judicial notice of these bills, ante.
To the extent the proceeds' expenditure may seem inappropriate to some, those who seek to challenge it may do so. As demonstrated by the special fund cases, Californians have shown little hesitation in challenging alleged improper diversions by the Legislature. And the remedy in such cases is generally restoration of the money to its proper purpose, and preclusion of future unlawful diversions, not return of money to the payors. (See, e.g., Veterans, supra, 36 Cal.App.3d at p. 696-697; Shaw, supra, 175 Cal.App.4th at pp. 600-615 [invalidating legislative transfers of certain funds].) Therefore, we do not see how any hypothetical misappropriation of funds here would either nullify the program or transform the auction revenues into a tax.
The judgments are affirmed. In each case appellants shall pay the appellate costs of respondents. (See Cal. Rules of Court, rule 8.278.)
Butz, J., concurred.
HULL, J., Concurring and Dissenting. —
I concur in part I of the opinion; as to part II, I dissent.
The majority concludes the cap-and-trade auction program is not a tax because (1) the purchase of auction credits by businesses is voluntary, (2) the purchasing entities receive "a thing of value" in the nature of a commodity by their purchase, that is, the right to pollute the air and (3) we need not be concerned in this appeal about the use of the auction proceeds.
On this record, (1) the purchase of auction credits by Morning Star Packing Company (Morning Star) or other businesses similarly situated is not voluntary, (2) the auction credits do not confer property rights in the nature of a commodity or otherwise to Morning Star or businesses who are similarly situated, and (3) the use of the auction proceeds, a hallmark, if not the gold standard, for determining if a state exaction is a tax must be considered.
I conclude that the cap-and-trade auction program is a tax, therefore, I dissent.
Preliminarily, the majority begins its analysis by circumscribing for our purposes our Supreme Court's holding in Sinclair Paint Co. v. State Bd. of Equalization (1997) 15 Cal.4th 866 [64 Cal.Rptr.2d 447, 937 P.2d 1350]
Thus, the issue before the court is whether this "something else" is in fact a tax.
Turning then to the question of the "voluntariness" of participating in the auction program, the only evidence in the trial court and the only evidence in this record on the question of voluntariness is the declaration of Janet Rabo, an economist with appellant, Morning Star Ms. Rabo declared, in pertinent part, as follows:
Rabo's declaration was admitted into evidence in the trial court without objection. There was no evidence admitted in the trial court contradicting her declaration. Thus, there was no evidence contradicting Rabo's declaration that Morning Star's participation in the auction program was "voluntary" only in the sense that Morning Star could voluntarily cease doing business in California if Morning Star did not participate.
While the trial court did not expressly accept or reject Rabo's evidence that Morning Star could not continue to do business in California without purchasing the state credits, the court did note that: "Contrary to what ARB argues, the charges have some traditional attributes of a tax. First, the charges are not entirely voluntary. It is important to remember that the allowances have value to covered entities only because the government has forbidden covered entities from emitting GHG without an allowance [noting that `[v]irtually every tax is in some sense "voluntary" in that one can avoid the tax by choosing not to engage in the taxed activity. Taken to its logical extreme, even income, sales, and property taxes would not be "compulsory" because they must be paid only if one "voluntarily" earns income, purchases goods, or owns property. Yet no one would dispute these are taxes.']. The covered entity either must reduce its GHG emissions to zero — which, generally speaking, is impractical or impossible — or acquire allowances. Thus, from the perspective of a covered entity, the purchase of allowances is little different from an emissions tax. In the case of an emissions tax, covered entities obtain the right to emit GHGs by paying the tax; in the case of the cap-and-trade auction, they obtain this right by purchasing all allowances." (Italics added.)
The trial court at least impliedly accepted Rabo's declaration to the effect that Morning Star could not continue to do business in California without participating in the auctions and purchasing the necessary credits.
Since the majority recognizes that "`[t]he word tax, in its common acceptation, denotes some compulsory exaction, which a government makes upon persons or property within its jurisdiction, for the supply of the public necessities.' (People v. Naglee (1850) 1 Cal. 232, 253, italics added; see Sinclair Paint, supra, 15 Cal.4th at p. 874 [`Most taxes are compulsory rather than [a] response to a voluntary decision to develop or to seek other government benefits or privileges'].)" (Maj. opn., ante, at pp. 640-641) Rabo's declaration presents the majority with a problem, that is, it is the only evidence in the record on the issue of the "voluntariness" of the purchase of credits, voluntary purchases being one of the three major underpinnings of the majority's analysis.
Confronted with that problem, in concluding that the state auction program is voluntary, the majority seems to decide that, notwithstanding Rabo's uncontradicted declaration, Morning Star could stay in business by acquiring — outside of the auction program — the number of credits Morning Star needed to continue to operate its business. There is no evidence to support that conclusion.
Further, the majority characterizes Rabo's declaration as demonstrating only that participation in the auction program results in nothing more than an increase in costs to do business saying that "the fact that the auction system may result in costs does not make the auction system a tax." (Maj. opn., ante, at p. 644, fn. 27.)
"Rabo does not explain why Morning Star cannot absorb the increased cost of doing business or mitigate the increase in some other fashion. As the Board pointed out at oral argument, a covered entity has a menu of options to achieve compliance, as we have referenced ante. Rabo does not describe any potential mechanism to recoup costs nor why any efforts to recoup costs would fail or prove insufficient. Although Morning Star may ultimately make the business decision that it must pay for allowances in order to maintain its operations in California, making the business decision to pay is not the same as being compelled to do so by the state." (Maj. opn., ante, at p. 644, fn. & italics omitted.)
The majority then goes on to take the Rabo declaration to task by stating that "the Rabo declaration in large part hinged on the claimed lack of
The majority finally dismisses Rabo's declaration by speculating, at respondent's invitation, that Morning Star had a "menu of options" that it could have turned to that would have allowed it to comply with the law without participating in the auctions and stay in business at the same time. (Maj. opn., ante, at p. 644.) But there is no evidence in the record that such is a fact. At its essence, the majority is saying that it simply disbelieves Rabo when she declares that Morning Star could not continue to do business in California without participating in the auctions, a credibility finding not often made in the first instance in my experience by a court of review, especially given the fact that the trial court apparently credited her declaration. In support of its statement of disbelief, the majority cites two cases for the proposition that, unless done arbitrarily, a "trier of fact" may reject the testimony of a witness even though that testimony is uncontradicted. (See Maj. opn., ante, at at pp. 643-644 & fn. 26.) We are not a trier of fact.
While it may be true that some participate in the auctions voluntarily as investors or those who would seek to resell credits, on this record, Morning Star's participation is not voluntary except in the sense, as noted by the trial court, that California income taxes are voluntary because one need not earn income or live in California as are property taxes as one need not own property.
The majority also says that, even though under the cap-and-trade law, a business may be required to absorb an increase in costs, those costs cannot be considered a tax even if the increased costs require it to go out of business in California, that is, results in "leakage," which the act anticipated. (Maj. opn., ante, at at p. 644.)
But in all of this the majority misses the point. This is an increase in costs that businesses such as Morning Star must bear if they wish to continue to do business in California; an increase in costs that is, in that sense, compulsory. It is no different than saying that an increase in income taxes is nothing more than an increase in costs that a private business or citizen must bear even though it may require it or him or her to leave California or an increase in property taxes are merely an increase in costs even though it may require the property's owner to give up its property in California. The point is, the "increase in costs" is compulsory and not voluntary unless one opts to "voluntarily" close their business in the state of California.
Finally, I must take exception to the majority's observation that, "[a]lbeit not explicitly, plaintiffs seem to rely on the foundational premise that covered entities have some vested right to continue polluting California's air without paying for the privilege to do so." (Maj. opn., ante, at p. 645.) That is not what plaintiffs are saying at all.
We must keep in mind this is not a challenge to the cap-and-trade program overall which requires covered entities to purchase credits if they cannot operate within the guidelines. Plaintiffs accept that. What they are challenging is the lawfulness of the Legislature's and the State AIR Resources Board's reservation to itself of sufficient credits to require purchase of credits from the state — as opposed to purchasing such credits on the free market — which revenue is used by the state as if it were general fund money, without calling that revenue generation a tax.
Working from the premise that the payment of taxes does not ordinarily convey a property right, the majority decides that the auction credits convey a property right in the nature of a commodity. The majority sees the state is selling a "right to pollute." This is a curious construction to say the least. While, without question, the state, in exercising its police powers, has the ability to legislate in an effort to achieve healthy air quality, it does not mean, conversely, that the state thereby also "owns" rights to pollute which it can sell to others. In any event, I do not find that construct persuasive.
The majority finds the auction proceeds convey a property right notwithstanding the provisions of California Code of Regulations, title 17, section 95820, subdivision (c) which reads: "Each compliance instrument issued by the Executive Officer represents a limited authorization to emit up to one metric ton in CO2e of any greenhouse gas specified in section 95810, subject to all applicable limitations specified in this article. No provision of this article may be construed to limit the authority of the Executive Officer to terminate or limit such authorization to emit. A compliance instrument issued by the Executive Officer does not constitute property or a property right." (Italics added.)
If I read the majority opinion correctly, it avoids what would otherwise be the plain language of this regulation by finding that it speaks only to property
In my view, in light of the plain language of California Code of Regulations, title 17, section 95820, subdivision (c), which describes (1) an authorization to emit as "limited," (2) as something that can be terminated or limited at the sole discretion of the state and (3) as something that, by regulation does not convey a property right, the conclusion cannot be avoided that where, as here, entities such as Morning Star are required to purchase auction credits to stay in business, what they purchase is no more a "thing of value" than is the payment of property taxes to keep ownership of one's home. Whatever else these authorizations are, as to Morning Star and others similarly situated, their value as a "property right" is ephemeral and the auction program cannot be said to convey a property right in the nature of a commodity or otherwise when emission authorizations can be limited or terminated by the state at any time.
The majority's effort to distinguish the auction programs from a tax by finding that the program conveys property rights in the form of a commodity to Morning Star is not analytically sound.
I note that in support of their analysis, the majority relies in part on Jopson v. Feather River Air Quality Management Dist. (2003) 108 Cal.App.4th 492 [133 Cal.Rptr.2d 506] (Jopson). But in Jopson, an opinion in which I joined, the court simply stated that emission reduction credits issued by air quality management districts were a "valuable commodity" that could be sold between private parties. (Id. at p. 494.) Jopson does not advance the majority's opinion here because, first, the court's description of emission credits as a valuable commodity in Jopson was simply background used to explain the litigation there at hand and, second, the court's observation was made without analysis or citation to any authority. Jopson certainly did not decide, or even discuss, whether limited authorizations to emit, authorizations that can be limited or terminated at any time, sold by the state to private businesses to be used by those businesses solely to stay in business in this state can or cannot be deemed a valuable commodity.
For plaintiffs, it cannot accurately be said that what Morning Star and others in their situation buy at the auctions are commodities carrying property rights. The auctions are instead a revenue vehicle for the state, a vehicle by which businesses are compelled to pay the state and obtain, in return only, the ability to remain in business in California; a state exaction that has all the components of a traditional tax.
The majority finds that the use of the revenue generated by the state auctions is a matter not "ripe" for adjudication because it is appropriate to "decouple" the issues of revenue generation and revenue expenditures. (Maj. opn., ante, at p. 650.) But an attempt to avoid factoring in the use of auction revenue on the question of whether or not the auction revenues arise from a tax does not stand up to careful scrutiny.
"The cases recognize that `tax' has no fixed meaning, and that the distinction between taxes and fees is frequently `blurred,' taking on different meanings in different contexts. (Russ Bldg. Partnership v. City and County of San Francisco [(1987)] 199 Cal.App.3d [1496,] 1504 [246 Cal.Rptr. 21]; Terminal Plaza Corp. v. City and County of San Francisco (1986) 177 Cal.App.3d 892, 905 [223 Cal.Rptr. 379]; Mills v. County of Trinity (1980) 108 Cal.App.3d 656, 660 [166 Cal.Rptr. 674]; County of Fresno v. Malmstrom (1979) 94 Cal.App.3d 974, 983-984 [156 Cal.Rptr. 777].) In general, taxes are imposed for revenue purposes, rather than in return for a specific benefit conferred or privilege granted. (Shapell Industries, Inc. v. Governing Board (1991) 1 Cal.App.4th 218, 240, [1 Cal.Rptr.2d 818]; County of Fresno v. Malmstrom, supra, 94 Cal.App.3d at p. 983 [`Taxes are raised for the general revenue of the governmental entity to pay for a variety of public services.'].)" (Sinclair Paint, supra, 15 Cal.4th at p. 874.)
As noted in the quote above, in general taxes are imposed for revenue purposes, that is for "the general revenue of the governmental entity to pay for a variety of public services." (County of Fresno v. Malmstrom, supra, 94 Cal.App.3d at p. 983.)
The majority reasons that, because none of the petitions before us seeks to invalidate known uses of the funds, we can ignore the hardly disputable fact
The use of the revenue from government exactions is a hallmark, probably the most important one, in determining whether that exaction is a tax. Although not alone determinative, the use of the money must be factored into the analytical equation. If the state treats the revenue as general revenue to be used to pay for public services, that strongly suggests the exaction is a tax.
I would note this court's decision in Morning Star Co. v. Board of Equalization (2011) 201 Cal.App.4th 737 [135 Cal.Rptr.3d 457] (Morning Star) wherein, being asked whether a state exaction imposed as part of a comprehensive state overhaul concerning hazardous wastes was a tax or a regulatory fee, we determined that it was a tax relying largely on the use of the revenue. Thus, "[the exaction] is not regulatory because it does not seek to regulate the Company's use, generation or storage of hazardous material but to raise money for the control of hazardous material generally. The charge is therefore a tax. At its most basic level, the ... charge is not a regulatory fee because it is not regulatory. It is monetary." (Id. at p. 755.)
While I recognize that Morning Star was a tax versus regulatory fee case, its recognition that the use of the funds plays a singular role in the definition of a tax was, and still is, accurate.
The majority's analysis on this point is, roughly, that none of the plaintiffs challenged the use of the funds as those uses are reflected in this record, therefore we need not consider those uses. But, accepting the majority's premise that plaintiffs could have challenged those uses, does their failure to do so mean that we can ignore those uses for judging whether or not the program exacts a tax? I think not; the majority's answer does not meet the challenge because there is nothing in the law that says that plaintiffs must have raised such challenges before we are required to consider the use of the money in deciding the question before us. There is a disconnect in the majority's analysis. And I note that while perhaps such individual challenges to expenditures could have been made each time the money was spent, it would make no practical or legal sense to piecemeal the litigation as opposed to challenging the entire program as a tax.
Health and Safety Code section 39712 in pertinent part provides:
And, Health and Safety Code section 39719 provides:
Health and Safety Code section 39713 provides:
Health and Safety Code section 39711 referenced in Health and Safety Code section 39713 quoted above provides in relevant part:
Item 3900-011-3228 of the Budget Act of 2013 (Stats. 2013, ch. 20, § 2, Item 3900-011-3228) provides that the State Controller will, upon the order of the Director of Finance, transfer $500 million from the Greenhouse Gas Reduction Fund to the General Fund as a loan.
Health and Safety Code section 39719.1 provides:
Thus, the revenues generated by the auctions can be used by the state for, at least:
To the obvious broad use of the auction revenues, and in order to avoid having to consider the effect of the use of the proceeds on the question before us, respondents argue that the uses of the proceeds are merely advancing the intent of the program, that is, to reduce greenhouse gases and are, therefore, used more narrowly than general revenue funds.
Asked during oral argument what the expenditures on affordable housing had to do with emissions, respondents said the affordable housing was to be built near places of employment and transportation hubs to encourage public transportation and reduce greenhouse gas emissions accordingly. Following that line of argument would probably allow the proceeds to be spent on
Respondents' argument conflates funding of the costs of administering the auction program with funding of the goals of cap and trade.
And here is the magic, the sleight of hand, of respondents' argument. Since an argument can be, and has been, made that nearly all human activity (and, apparently, some animal activity) increases greenhouse gases, voilà, auction funds can be used to address nearly any human activity without being considered a tax that generates general revenue, thus avoiding the prohibitions of Proposition 13, so long as the use of the funds has any tenuous connection to the reduction of greenhouse gases, connections that can always be found if one reaches far enough.
Howard Jarvis Taxpayers Assn. v. County of Orange (2003) 110 Cal.App.4th 1375 [2 Cal.Rptr.3d 514] (Howard Jarvis) is instructive. There, the City of Huntington Beach amended its city charter effective July 1978 (1) to mandate the city's participation in a retirement system, (2) gave the city council discretion to establish reasonable compensation and fringe benefits as appropriate and (3) established an excise tax on real property to fund the retirement program.
After that, and after the passage of Proposition 13, the city added to those city retirement benefits and collected increased excises tax to fund those additional benefits. A taxpayer brought suit contending the excise tax, to the extent it funded additional retirement benefits granted after July 1978, violated Proposition 13.
The city argued there was no violation because the 1978 city charter language gave the city a right to levy the excess tax for virtually anything so long as the costs the excess tax funded related to city employee retirement benefits "including `giv[ing] a house ... to every employee as they retire ... [¶] ...'" (Howard Jarvis, supra, 110 Cal.App.4th at p. 1383.)
The court disagreed and observed that the city's argument would eviscerate Proposition 13 adding: "Under City's interpretation, it would have virtually unfettered power to spend whatever sum of money and levy excess taxes to obtain the revenue, as long as the expenditure was designated `retirement.' This was one of the very things Proposition 13 was enacted to combat." (Howard Jarvis, supra, 110 Cal.App.4th at p. 1384.)
So too here. The state's argument gives it "virtually unfettered" power to spend whatever money the auction program raises so long as the purpose of the money is to a theoretical reduction of greenhouse gases.
It needs to be noted that the auction program revenues are not necessary to the funding of the cap-and-trade program in general or the auction program in particular.
Health and Safety Code section 38597 says: "The [State Air Resources Board] may adopt by regulation, after a public workshop, a schedule of fees to be paid by the sources of greenhouse gas emissions regulated pursuant to this division, consistent with Section 57001. The revenues collected pursuant to this section, shall be deposited into the Air Pollution Control Fund and are available upon appropriation, by the Legislature, for purposes of carrying out this division."
Pursuant to the statutory authority granted by Health and Safety Code section 38597, the State Air Resources Board adopted California Code of Regulations, title 17, section 95200 (Cal. Code of Regs., tit. 17, §§ 95200, 95203), which provides: "The purpose of this subarticle is to collect fees to be used to carry out the California Global Warming Solutions Act of 2006 (Stats. 2006; Ch. 488; Health and Safety Code sections 38500 et seq.), as provided in Health and Safety Code section 38597."
The State Air Resources Board also adopted California Code of Regulations, title 17, section 95203 which further provides:
It would thus appear that auction proceeds are not intended, or, more importantly needed, to pay for the costs of implementation of Assembly Bill No. 32 (2005-2006 Reg. Sess.).
The only reasonable conclusion one can reach is that the auction proceeds are intended to, and do, generate general revenue to the State of California. It is apparent that by respondent's express acknowledgement, this revenue may be used for any program that, arguably, might reduce greenhouse gases. But, as noted above, the effort to reduce greenhouse gases essentially encompasses all aspects of human activity and thus the use of the auction revenues by the state is virtually unlimited. Thus, the purchase of auction credits which, on this record, are imposed on Morning Star and businesses similarly situated, creates revenue to pay for a nearly unlimited variety of public services. (See, County of Fresno v. Malmstrom, supra, 94 Cal.App.3d at p. 983 ["Taxes are raised for the general revenue ... to pay for a variety of public services"].) This is a tax increase on businesses knowingly structured to avoid the provisions of Proposition 13.
Accepting the argument that there is social value to the cap-and-trade program, questions of the social value of any given law are the province of the Legislature and the Governor. It is the province of the courts to decide questions of law and the constitutionality of the laws and to do so based solely on the law regardless of the social value of the challenged legislation.
My colleagues and I have worked diligently on what is obviously a complex and difficult appeal. They, in good faith, have reached a conclusion different than mine. I simply cannot agree with their analysis or their result.
Given that the auction program is, for Morning Star and businesses that are similarly situated, compulsory if they are to remain in business in California and that the auction program creates, in actual effect, general revenue, I can
I would reverse the judgment.
We note that taxes must be levied by the legislative, not executive, branch. (See Hilliard, Law of Taxation (1875) § 1, p. 1; 1 Cooley, A Treatise on the Law of Taxation (3d ed. 1903) the Nature of the Power to Tax, p. 43 (Cooley).) Nor can the legislature delegate the power to tax to an administrative board, although a board can value property and collect taxes. (See 71 Am.Jur.2d (2001) State and Local Taxation, § 107, pp. 393-394.) Here, because we find no tax (see pt. II, post), we need not consider whether, if the revenue generated by the auction sales were a tax, it could have been created by the Board and then ratified by the Legislature. (See pt. IC.1., post.)
After oral argument in this case, our Supreme Court granted review in an unrelated case, raising the following two issues: "(1) Can a statute be challenged on the ground that compliance with it is allegedly impossible? (2) If so, how is the trial court to make that determination?" (National Shooting Sports Foundation, Inc. v. State of California (2016) 6 Cal.App.5th 298 [210 Cal.Rptr.3d 867], review granted Mar. 22, 2017, S239397.) Those issues arguably speak to Morning Star's act of submitting the Rabo declaration — material outside the normal administrative record — to the trial court. However, we express no view on the procedural propriety of such action herein.