CHRISTOPHER N. KLEIN, Chief Bankruptcy Judge.
Resolving the single objection to confirmation of the chapter 9 plan of adjustment of debts by the City of Stockton necessitates answering the threshold question whether, as a matter of law, pension contracts entered into by the City, including the pension administration contract, may be rejected pursuant to Bankruptcy Code § 365. 11 U.S.C. § 365.
After answering that question of law in the affirmative, we come to the main question: whether, as matters of law and fact, the City's chapter 9 plan should be confirmed even though the plan does not directly impair the City-sponsored pensions.
Franklin Templeton Investments ("Franklin") objects to confirmation, contending that the City's failure to modify pensions means that the plan (1) is not proposed in good faith and (2) that Franklin's unsecured claim should be separately classified so that Franklin can be deemed to be a separate, non-accepting class as to which the plan may be confirmed only if, with respect to Franklin, it is fair and equitable and does not unfairly discriminate against it. 11 U.S.C. §§ 1122 (a), 1129 (a) (3) & 1129(b).
If Franklin's unsecured claim is not separately classified, then the fair-and-equitable-and-not-unfairly-discriminatory analysis of § 1129(b) would not apply to this plan because Franklin's claim is dwarfed and out-voted in the single class of unsecured claims. The value given up by retirees who accepted the plan is on the order of ten times the value lost by Franklin.
The California Public Employees' Retirement System ("CalPERS"), which by contract administers the City-sponsored pensions, says that California law insulates its contract from rejection and that the pensions themselves may not be adjusted. Although, as will be seen, it is doubtful that CalPERS even has standing to defend the City pensions from modification, CalPERS has bullied its way about in this case with an iron fist insisting that it and the municipal pensions it services are inviolable. The bully may have an iron fist, but it also turns out to have a glass jaw.
This decision determines that the obstacles interposed by CalPERS are not effective in bankruptcy. First, the California statute forbidding rejection of a contract with CalPERS in a chapter 9 case is constitutionally infirm in the face of the exclusive power of Congress to enact uniform laws on the subject of bankruptcy under Article I, Section 8, of the U.S. Constitution — the essence of which laws is the impairment of contracts — and of the Supremacy Clause. U.S. CONST. art. I, § 8 & art. VI. Second, the $1.6 billion lien granted to CalPERS by state statute in the event of termination of a pension administration contract is vulnerable to avoidance in bankruptcy as a statutory lien. 11 U.S.C. § 545. Third, the Contracts Clauses of the Federal and State Constitutions, as implemented by California's judge-made "Vested Rights Doctrine," do not preclude contract rejection or modification in bankruptcy. Finally, considerations of sovereignty and sovereign immunity do not dictate a different result.
Hence, as a matter of law, the City's pension administration contract with CalPERS, as well as the City-sponsored pensions themselves, may be adjusted as part of a chapter 9 plan.
But, when one turns to the question of plan confirmation, pensions must be viewed as but one aspect of total compensation.
The City's plan achieves significant net reductions in total compensation (including lower pensions for new employees and elimination of up to $550 million in unfunded health benefits) that employees accepted in exchange for preserving existing pensions.
All capital markets creditors, except Franklin, accepted a package of restructured bond debt in impairments reflecting their relative rights in collateral. Franklin did not fare as well because it took poor collateral to support its loan.
Viewing compensation as a whole package, and comparing those net reductions with the net reductions for capital markets creditors, the plan is, in law and fact, appropriate to confirm.
Jurisdiction is founded on 28 U.S.C. § 1334. The question whether to confirm a chapter 9 plan of adjustment is a core proceeding that a bankruptcy judge may hear and determine. 28 U.S.C. § 157 (b) (2) (L)
The premise of Franklin's objection to confirmation is its theory that the City's pensions administered by CalPERS may be modified and that the plan should not be confirmed unless the pensions are modified. The City's plan does not propose to adjust the CalPERS pension.
In addition to acting as the pension system for employees of the State of California, CalPERS contracts with California municipalities in competition with other pension administrators to administer local pensions for municipalities. Public Employees' Retirement Law, Cal. Gov't Code § 20460 ("PERL").
The City's pension obligation is established by contract between the City and its employees. The terms of the City-sponsored pension conform to a template that CalPERS is willing to administer by contract. The City could also select a different administrator in the public or private sector or establish its own administration system.
If one were to diagram the relevant relationships, one would draw a triangle in which the corners are the City, CalPERS, and City employees. There are three distinct relationships. First, the City agrees with its employees to provide pensions. Second, the City agrees with CalPERS that CalPERS will administer City pensions by collecting payments from the City and investing those funds so as to produce enough to pay the pensions, and then paying on behalf of the City. Third, CalPERS promises City employees that it will pay the pensions.
From the viewpoint of the law of contract, there are three connected bilateral relationships. Two legs of the triangle are contracts: between City and employees and between City and CalPERS. The third leg is a third-party beneficiary relationship according to which pensioners are intended third-party beneficiaries of the City's contract with CalPERS.
CalPERS does not bear financial risk from reductions by the City in its funding payments because state law requires CalPERS to pass along the reductions to pensioners in the form of reduced pensions. Rather, it is the pensioners, present and future, themselves who are at risk of loss.
As noted, a municipality is free to establish its own self-funded, self-administered pension system, commonly funded by individual or group life insurance or annuity contracts.
A municipality is entitled to shift from one pension administrator to another. If it shifts away from CalPERS, it cannot enter into a new CalPERS contract for three years. Cal. Gov't Code § 20460.
The key legal point to draw from this structure is that the authority of CalPERS to interject itself into the potential modification of a municipal pension in California under the Federal Bankruptcy Code is doubtful. As CalPERS does not guaranty payment of municipal pensions and has a connection with a municipality only if that municipality elects to contract with CalPERS to service its pensions, its standing to object to a municipal pension modification through chapter 9 appears to be lacking.
Nevertheless, the reality is that CalPERS has captured a substantial portion of the local pension servicing market in California. As of June 2014,
A municipality that contracts with CalPERS is not dealing with an ordinary contractual counterparty.
First, CalPERS enjoys some natural competitive advantages over other local pension servicers. CalPERS pension rights are "portable" in that they can be carried by an employee from one CalPERS employer to another CalPERS employer. By limiting pension provisions to standard features approved by CalPERS, it can keep track of benefits as they accumulate, charging each employer its appropriate contribution. That "portability" facilitates nimble public-sector career management in California.
Second, the PERL, in the course of nearly 800 pages in the California Government Code, mandates myriad non-negotiable provisions and practices that might otherwise be negotiable in contracts with a private pension provider. A municipality that wishes to contract with CalPERS must choose from a template of benefit formulae and optional contract provisions acceptable to CalPERS. Hence, there is less of the freedom of contract than one might experience in dealing with a private pension provider.
Second, the CalPERS board is not typical of a private board. The thirteen-member CalPERS board is selected on a political basis: seven public officials or appointees thereof and six persons elected by the employees participating in CalPERS.
The California Constitution restricts the ability of the state legislature to reform the composition of the CalPERS board. I CAL. CONST. art. XVI, § 17(f).
The California Constitution also provides that the board of a public pension or retirement system, be it CalPERS, a county system, or a city system, has "plenary authority and fiduciary responsibility for investment of moneys and administration of the system" and proceeds to spell out various duties and to limit the ability of the state legislature to affect investment policies. CAL. CONST. art. XVI.
Once a municipality agrees to a CalPERS contract, the CalPERS board gets into a position to block changes in the municipality's pensions by saying a local change would adversely affect the system.
In effect, municipal employees are permitted indirectly to participate in negotiations between a municipality and CalPERS. The process of voluntarily adjusting a CalPERS pension requires that the municipality, first, negotiate with its employees regarding the pension and, second, run the gauntlet of also satisfying the CalPERS board.
The PERL also operates to involve CalPERS in negotiations between a municipality and its employees.
Although the PERL contemplates that a municipality is free to shift to a different pension administrator, the ferocity of CalPERS' behavior in this case indicates that it has a policy of, by overt and passive aggression, resisting attempts to make such shifts. Some PERL provisions fuel that policy.
In PERL § 20487, the California legislature singled out CalPERS, and no other municipal pension administrator, for special protection in chapter 9 bankruptcy cases by forbidding the rejection of any contract between a municipality and CalPERS under 11 U.S.C. § 365. Further, PERL § 20487 purports to give CalPERS a veto over any assumption or assignment of a contract between it and a municipality in chapter 9.
The PERL nominally permits a municipality to shift from CalPERS to another pension provider or system. Thus, CalPERS is authorized to negotiate terms of a switch.
Nevertheless, PERL discourages such a shift by imposing a termination charge that is backed by a confiscatory statutory lien. PERL § 20574.
The PERL § 20574 termination lien operates as follows. Upon termination, either voluntary or involuntary, CalPERS holds accumulated contributions for the benefit of employees and beneficiaries with respect to previously-credited service.
The amount of underfunding in the termination pool is determined under PERL § 20577.
The PERL § 20574 lien enforces the debt determined under PERL § 20577. It applies to all assets of the terminated contracting municipality. The provision that it is "subject only to a prior lien for wages" means that it jumps into line ahead of all other liens.
The effect of shifting accumulated contributions from the CalPERS general investment pool to the termination pool means that a municipality that has theretofore been deemed fully funded instantaneously becomes underfunded by virtue of lower projected investment returns in the termination pool. Since the termination pool is invested on a more conservative basis than the normal pool, it produces lower yields.
Deep down, the reason for the sudden underfunding is simple. Pension funding status is a measure of the extent to which assets on hand, plus future required contributions, plus future investment earnings are sufficient to pay benefits. A formula is set forth in the margin.
Elementary mathematics teach that if a pension is fully funded (i.e. a funding ratio of 1.0, colloquially stated in percent), then the sum of the assets on hand, plus the present value of future required contributions, plus the present value of future investment earnings, exactly equal the present value of all benefits to be paid.
If everything is equal where the expected rate of return on future earnings is 8 percent, then a reduction in the investment earning assumption from 8 percent to 3 percent causes the funding ratio to drop below 100 percent. Hence, fully funded status could only be restored by increasing future required contributions.
That is what happens with the CalPERS termination lien when a terminating entity's assets are shifted to the termination pool. What may have been fully funded at the regular CalPERS 7.5 percent expected rate of return becomes underfunded at the termination pool 2.98 percent expected rate of return. The problem is exacerbated because the future required contributions are instantly accelerated to one lump sum.
That lump sum liability resulting from a potential shift to the termination pool, in the case of the City, is $1.6 billion.
The actual analysis of the problem of the sudden descent into underfunded status that has just been stated in oversimplified form is much more complex because of the need to place actual numbers on future benefits, future contributions, and future investment returns and discount them to present value. Actuaries specialize in the mind-numbing computations needed to produce the basic numbers, while the appropriate discount rate strays into the realm of economists.
There is a debate currently raging among economists over the appropriate discount rate to apply in assessing the fiscal health of public pensions.
All agree that standard financial theory requires that future streams of payments be discounted to present value at a rate that reflects their risk. The problem becomes determining the correct discount rate.
In the mathematics of finance, decreasing the discount rate applied to future benefits increases the present discounted value of those benefits. When the value of benefits is compared with the value of plan assets, the lower the discount rate, the higher the contributions required to keep a plan in fully-funded status.
In the private sector, the discount-rate issue has been largely settled by the Financial Accounting Standards Board ("FASB") guidance that certain corporate bond rates be used as discount rates to determine funded status of private pensions. MUNNELL, at 59.
In the public sector, the practice is to base discount rates on expected investment returns instead of rates on government bonds. Therein lies controversy.
The Governmental Accounting Standards Board (WGASB), which sets standards of accounting and reporting for state and local governments, recommends that the funded status of public pensions be determined using a discount rate of 8 percent, based on expected investment return on assets. MUNNELL, at 59.
Many economists disagree with GASB and argue that it is more appropriate to measure funding status of public pensions using a lower riskiess rate of return analogous to the corporate bond rates used to discount private sector pensions, such as a long-term Treasury rate, instead of a higher expected long-run investment return on assets. They reason that there is an implicit public guarantee that assures public pensions will be paid regardless of investment returns, which makes it hazardous to determine funded status and make benefit promises based on anticipated investment returns that may not come to pass. In lay terms, they say using expected investment returns amounts to counting the chickens before they hatch.
By way of example, when estimating the overall national unfunded liability of state and local government pension plans, the difference between using an assumed riskiess rate of 5 percent and using the 8 percent GASB-recommended rate affected the total aggregate unfunded liability by more than 300 percent. MUNNELL, at 61-62.
CalPERS is actually more conservative than GASB in that, instead of the 8 percent GASB rate, it has recently adjusted its rate to 7.5 percent, based on 2.75 percent for inflation and 4.75 percent for investment return (net of expenses)
The expected return rate in the CalPERS termination pool is the yield on 30-year Treasury obligations — 2.98 percent as of June 30, 2012. The lower termination expected return rate leads to the claim that termination of the CalPERS pension administration contract for Stockton would yield a liability of $1.6 billion, even though the underfunded status for the City's two pension plans is about $211 million on an actuarial basis.
In this respect, PERL § 20577 functions as a "golden handcuff" and a "poison pill." If the fully-funded municipality does not terminate its CalPERS contract, then its accumulated pension contributions will remain in the normal investment pool, and it will remain fully funded (except to the extent that CalPERS itself may, on a global basis, be underfunded) . But if it terminates, then it faces a sobering termination bill that renders it underfunded.
Here, CalPERS says the City is deemed to be in full compliance with its funding obligations (underfunding of between $212 million and $412 million due to changed CalPERS assumptions about the future is being recouped by additional annual payments).
The enforcement mechanism for the termination liability is a lien created by PERL § 20574. The lien arises on account of the PERL § 20577 termination liability and is senior to all liens other that a prior lien for wages.
Accordingly, CalPERS says there would be a $1.6 billion priming lien. If enforceable, then a lien of such proportions could cripple opportunities to restructure municipal debt. The threat of such a lien casts a pall over any municipal restructuring in which pension obligations are part of the financial predicament.
The termination lien is presumptively valid as a matter of I California law. A question addressed later in this opinion is whether, as a matter of overriding federal law, the termination lien is efficacious in a chapter 9 municipal debt adjustment.
In principle, the notion that a terminating entity must pay any pension underfunding makes good business sense. If a pension administrator is to be liable for payment of a promised pension in full, then surely it is entitled to minimize the financial risk by insisting that the obligations it has undertaken be fully funded. Any responsible public or private sector pension administrator would insist on no less.
Correlatively, one would expect a well-advised pension administrator's contract to provide that a consequence of underfunding would be pro rata reduction of pensions. CalPERS is no exception.
CalPERS is not liable to pay underfunded pensions in full. If the terminating municipality does not pay the termination liability, then "all benefits under the contract, payable after the board declares the agency in default therefor, shall be pool. Cal. Gov't Code § 20577.
The rub is that CalPERS does not bear the financial risk of loss from underfunding a municipal pension. Benefits to retirees are automatically reduced if a terminating municipality does not pay its CalPERS bill in full. Cal. Gov't Code § 20577.
The automatic reduction of benefits dictated by PERL § 20577 when a municipality does not pay its pension bill casets a different light on the CalPERS termination lien because it means that CalPERS bears no financial risk of underfunding of the termination pool. Rather, the individual members and their beneficiaries are the ones who bear the risk of inadequate funding. In effect, CalPERS is merely a servicing agent that does not guarantee payment.
If CalPERS is not liable for the consequences of municipal pension underfunding, then it follows that it is not accurate to say, as Franklin argues, that CalPERS is the largest creditor of the City. That obligation, if it exists, is a debt owed to past and present municipal employees.
Rather, CalPERS is a creditor in its own right only for the fees that it is permitted to charge for administering the City's pensions. The real creditors are the employees, retirees, and their beneficiaries who will bear the burden of any reduction in the City's pensions.
At this juncture, the triangle of bilateral contractual relationships becomes important to the analysis. The consequence of rejecting the CalPERS contract would be to terminate CalPERS as the administrator of the City's pensions. But that would not terminate the contractual relationships between the City and its employees to provide pensions. Impairing the direct employer-employee pension obligations would require impairing contracts to which CalPERS is not party.
The structure of the federal-state relationship, as previously explained, regarding restructuring of municipal debt is dictated by the U.S. Constitution.
Congress has the power, exclusive of the states, to 4 legislate uniform laws on the subject of bankruptcy. U.S. CONST. art. I, § 8, cl. 4.
The essence of bankruptcy is impairing the obligation of contract.
The states are forbidden to enact any law impairing the obligation of contract. U.S. CONST.,art. I, § 10, cl.1.
The Supremacy Clause operates to cause federal bankruptcy law to trump state laws, including state constitutional provisions, that are inconsistent with the exercise by Congress of its exclusive power to enact uniform bankruptcy laws. U.S. CONST., art. VI, cl. 2;
As explained in prior decisions in this case, municipal debt adjustment under federal bankruptcy law dates back to the 1930s.
After the false start disapproved in
Before 1976, adjustment of municipal debts was essentially limited to bond financing. So-called "prepackaging" was mandatory. No case could be commenced unless pre-filing acceptances to proposed plan treatment had been obtained from a stated majority of the affected bond creditors. Thus, the law focused on dealing with the problems of unanimity commonly required in bond indentures, including the so-called "holdout" problem in which a minority withholds its consent in an effort to drive a better bargain.
In 1976, former chapter IX was revised to open the door to restructure all municipal debts. That revision was carried forward into the 1978 Bankruptcy Code as chapter 9.
It is always necessary to pay attention to issues of sovereignty within our federal system. There is a state sovereign and a federal sovereign. The ability of the federal sovereign to intrude in such matters as the control of subdivisions of the state sovereign is constrained by the Tenth Amendment. U.S. CONST. amend. X. Congress has structured chapter 9 to accommodate those concerns.
The first step in honoring the balance between federal and state sovereignty is the requirement that only the state may authorize a chapter 9 filing by any of its municipalities. 11 U.S.C. § 109(c) (2).
This makes the state the gatekeeper and entitles it to establish prerequisites to filing.
California exercises its gatekeeping function by requiring that, before filing a chapter 9 case a California municipality must either engage in a neutral evaluation process with a mediator for a specified period or declare a fiscal emergency under specified procedures. Cal. Gov't Code § 53760.
A municipality that has satisfied California's statutory prerequisites has the state's permission to proceed through the gate into a chapter 9 case.
Once a chapter 9 case has been filed in the circumstances authorized by the state, the federal Bankruptcy Code controls all proceedings in the case.
The primacy of the Bankruptcy Code does not, however, mean that state sovereignty can be disregarded.
Rather, the Bankruptcy Code contains limitations designed to assure that the federal court and the federal process does not unduly intrude upon the state's power to control the exercise of "political or governmental powers" of a municipality. 11 U.S.C. §§ 903 & 904.
Neither section purports to delineate which powers are "political" or "governmental"? correlatively, what powers are not included within those concepts? Neither question appears to have been closely examined in prior cases.
Since calPERS argues that the California statute forbidding the rejection of a contract with calPERs under 11 U.S.C. § 365 in a chapter 9 case is a legitimate exercise of the state's power to control the "political" or "governmental" powers of the municipality, those questions need to be answered here.
The first facet of honoring the sovereignty of a state within chapter 9 is Bankruptcy code § 903, which reserves certain state powers. That section provides that chapter 9 does not limit or impair the "power of a state" to control a municipality "in the exercise of the political or governmental powers of such municipality." 11 U.S.C. § 903.
The second facet is Bankruptcy Code § 904, which limits bankruptcy court authority over the municipality. The chapter 9 court may not, without the consent of the municipality (either directly or through a plan), interfere with any of the "political or governmental powers" of the municipality, may not interfere with any municipal property or revenues, and may not interfere with municipality's use or enjoyment of any income-producing property. 11 U.S.C. § 904.
Section 903 is the linchpin of CalPERS' argument that the California legislature, despite the Supremacy Clause of the U.S. Constitution, can protect CalPERS from provisions of the Federal Bankruptcy Code in a chapter 9 case that the state has authorized to be filed.
In defending the state statutes creating the CalPERS termination lien and the special CalPERS immunity from contract avoidance under Bankruptcy Code § 365, CalPERS contends that the § 903 power of the state to "control" a municipality in the exercise of municipal "political or governmental powers" means that it can "control" decisions by the City from exercising Bankruptcy Code powers by dictating which contracts may not be rejected or modified in the chapter 9 case.
Thus, CalPERS says that such an exercise of "control" is implemented by PERL § 20487 prohibiting modification of a contract with CalPERS to service municipal pensions. Similarly, it views the PERL § 20574 termination lien as invulnerable to attack in chapter 9.
It is noteworthy that these PERL provisions creating the termination lien and the immunity from Bankruptcy Code contract modification are nonuniform. They selectivey protect only CalPERS and CalPERS pensions. They do not apply to any other California municipal pension. A California city pension system created by a California municipality (e.g., Los Angeles, San Diego, or Fresno) does not enjoy those CalPERS protections. Nor does a California county pension system created under the so-called 1937 Act or a municipal pension administered by a private-sector pension servicer.
The PERL's special protections for the pension servicing contract incidentally protect the underlying pensions in a manner that forges an alliance between CalPERS and municipal employees. If the City's contract with CalPERS to service its pensions could be rejected, then the pensions, even if not otherwise modified, could be moved to a servicer that does not enjoy the CalPERS termination lien and the CalPERS immunity from Bankruptcy Code § 365 contract modification.
The key to the analysis of the §§ 903 and 904 restrictions is the meaning of exercise of "political or governmental powers" of a municipality.
The phrase "political or governmental powers" suggests that Congress had in mind the existence of a broader array of municipal powers that are not "political or governmental."
For guidance, we have only the language and context of the statute. To the extent that it is legitimate to consider legislative history, the legislative history is opaque.
Two clues are provided by the language of § 904. First, the need to be specific in § 904(2) about "property or revenues" implies that "property or revenues" are not necessarily subsumed within the concept of "political or governmental powers." 11 U.S.C. § 904(2). Second, the need to be specific in § 904(3) about "use or enjoyment" of income-producing property implies that "use or enjoyment" of income-producing property is similarly not subsumed within "political or governmental powers." 11 U.S.C. § 904(3).
Since the concept of "political or governmental" powers is central to both sections 903 and 904, it follows that those clues in § 904 also inform the analysis of § 903.
Further, the abrogation of a state's sovereign immunity in § 106 indirectly illuminates the meaning of "political or governmental" powers in § 903. While sovereign immunity refers to a multifaceted agglomeration of difficult-to-corral doctrines, it is unquestionably an incident of sovereignty.
The Bankruptcy Code abrogates sovereign immunity with respect to, among other things, the basic bankruptcy trustee avoiding powers set forth at §§ 544-549. 11 U.S.C. § 106(a) (1) Those avoiding powers enable a trustee or, pursuant to § 902(5), • chapter 9 municipal debtor to avoid, for example, transfers to • state that qualify as preferences under § 547, fraudulent transfers under § 548, and, under § 545, statutory liens in favor of the state. 11 U.S.C. §§ 545, 547, and 548.
It is beyond cavil that § 106 applies in chapter 9 cases. In the first place, all of the sections of chapter 1 of the Bankruptcy Code apply in chapter 9. 11 U.S.C. § 103(f).
These specific provisions of the Bankruptcy Code that apply in chapter 9 in a context in which the municipal debtor can avoid certain liens and transfers in favor of the state, whose sovereign immunity has expressly been abrogated under § 106(a), indicate that § 903 "political or governmental" functions do not include the financial relations that are implicit in those avoiding powers.
To be sure, however, some expenditures are reserved to state control by § 903. The statutory text mentions associated expenditures: "does not limit or impair the power of a State to control . . . a municipality ... in the exercise of the political or governmental powers of such municipality,
The question becomes what are "expenditures for such exercise" as distinguished from other expenditures?
One clue comes from the plan confirmation requirement that there be compliance with nonbankruptcy law regarding
Requirements for electoral approval implicated the foundation of any republican form of government — the people speak through elections. As an exercise of political power, state law directs the circumstances in which elections are required and may allocate to municipalities responsibility for funding elections.
Thus, for example, an important source of funding for the City's chapter 9 plan now under consideration for confirmation is premised on an increase in local sales tax. The compromises that were achieved through mediation with the capital markets creditors and the retirees contemplated additional revenue from a local sales tax increase. Since California law requires a vote of the people to approve local sales tax increases, the question was put before the voters and approved in a duly-scheduled election.
Similarly, regulatory approval requirements, which usually are justified on police power or related power-of-government theories, are § 903 "political or governmental" powers.
In sum, § 903 "political or governmental" powers relate to basic requirements of government and political polity and exclude financial and employment relations. To hold otherwise would read out of the Bankruptcy Code a number of provisions that plainly apply in chapter 9.
This conclusion leads back to CalPERS. State law does not mandate pensions for municipal employees. A California municipality that chooses to provide a pension (virtually all do) is permitted to establish its own pension system (some do), to contract with private sector pension providers (others do), to participate in county-sponsored pension systems (ditto), or to contract with CalPERS (many, including Stockton, do).
Nothing about basic state government structure or procedure necessitates CalPERS. Rather, CalPERS is merely one of numerous competitors in the California municipal pension market. There is nothing inherently "governmental" or "political" about a CalPERS municipal pension, as opposed to a municipal pension administered by a different entity, within the meaning of § 903 that would make the special treatment for CalPERS that is not afforded to other California municipal pension providers an exercise of § 903 "political or governmental" powers.
The PERL § 20574 termination lien and the PERL § 20487 prohibition on rejection in chapter 9 of a municipality's CalPERS pension servicing contract do not reflect the exercise of the "political or governmental" powers protected by § 903.
Although the CalPERS statutes have been enacted through the political processes, they do not relate to basic matters of government and exercise of police and regulatory powers. Rather, they relate to aspects of administrative terms of employment that are tangential — albeit important — to government. They involve financial matters that are of the character of the sort of financial matters that are legitimately within the ambit of the financial reorganization contemplated by chapter 9.
In other words, hiding behind the § 903 protection of the exercise of "political or governmental" powers does not work for CalPERS.
In order to accept the CalPERS argument that § 903 insulates the PERL § 20574 termination lien from avoidance and the PERL § 20487 ban on application of 11 U.S.C. § 365 to CalPERS from Supremacy Clause preemption, too many chapter 9 provisions that unambiguously apply to a state would have to be ignored. Permitting a state to modify the federal Bankruptcy Code amounts to an impermissible encroachment on the power of Congress to establish uniform laws on the subject of bankruptcies. U.S. CONST. art. I, § 8.
The "political or governmental" functions in § 903 refer to basic matters of the organization and operation of government that are incidents of sovereignty, but do not extend to financial relations between the state and its municipalities.
Sovereignty as protected by the Tenth Amendment is honored by the state's threshold control over whether, and under what procedures, one of its municipalities may file a chapter 9 case. The specialized relief in the form of the ability to cause municipal contracts to be impaired under the exclusive federal authority to impair contracts implemented by the Bankruptcy Code is available to a state on an all-or-nothing, take-or-leave-it basis. While § 903 protects the basic incidents of state sovereignty — described as "political and governmental" powers — from encroachment, contractual relations as between state and municipality are generally outside the ambit of "political or governmental" powers.
Having concluded that § 903 does not give the state a blank check to rewrite the federal Bankruptcy Code, several specific points of California law warrant analysis.
The California Supreme Court has construed the Contracts Clause of the California Constitution to recognize an unusually inflexible "vested right" in public employee pension benefits.
In contrast, the United States Supreme Court takes a less rigid view of the extent of a "vested right" in retiree benefits.
CalPERS places great reliance on the strength of a "vested right" under the Contracts Clause of California Constitution, which it describes as prohibiting the "unconstitutional impairment" of a public pension contract. CalPERS Legal Office,
The CalPERS backup position is the same argument founded on the Contracts Clause of the United States Constitution.
The rigidity of the California vested rights doctrine is a factor behind the current pressure on public pensions in California. It encourages dysfunctional strategies to circumvent limitations and peculiarities in California public finance.
The fatal flaw in the "vested rights" analysis of California public pensions is that neither the Contracts Clause of the California Constitution nor the Contracts Clause of the Federal Constitution prevents Congress from enacting a law impairing the obligation of contract. The Supremacy Clause of the Federal Constitution resolves conflicts between a clear power of Congress and a contrary state law in favor of Congress.
As explained above, so long as California authorizes its municipalities to be debtors in cases under Chapter 9 of the Bankruptcy Code, municipal contracts may be impaired by way of a confirmed chapter 9 plan of adjustment of municipal debts.
CalPERS contends that § 903 authorizes California to forbid the rejection of a pension servicing contract between it and a municipality, which is the gravamen of PERL § 20487:
Cal. Gov't Code § 20487.
It argues that providing such special protection for CalPERS, but no other entity providing or servicing a California municipal pension, is a "political or governmental" function insulated by § 903 from interference by the bankruptcy court.
There are multiple flaws in the CalPERS theory. First, no incident of state sovereignty is implicated in a contractual transaction when a municipality is free to contract with private sector entities as an alternative.
Second, PERL § 20487 merely operates to protect CalPERS in its capacity as creditor with a claim based on a rejected or modified contract. A competitor of CalPERS in the business of servicing California municipal pensions receives no such protection. As already explained, this is neither "political" nor "governmental" in nature.
Third, honoring PERL § 20487 would be inconsistent with Bankruptcy Code provisions that unambiguously apply to a state that permits its municipalities to obtain chapter 9 relief. For example, § 106(a) (1) abrogates sovereign immunity with respect to § 944, which binds creditors to the terms of a confirmed chapter 9 plan and discharges the municipality from all debts not perpetuated by the plan.
Fourth, special insulation of a state actor in a municipal insolvency is contrary to chapter 9 precedent. The State of Texas once permitted the Mission Independent School District to file a municipal restructuring case involving bonded indebtedness on the condition that in the case there be no discharge of any bond owned by the State of Texas. The Fifth Circuit rejected that condition as invalid.
The invalid
To honor PERL § 20487 would amount to permitting a state to usurp the exclusive power of Congress to legislate uniform laws on the subject of bankruptcy.
The termination lien established by PERL § 20574 is not a Imajor impediment to rejection of a CalPERS pension servicing contract. PERL § 20574 provides:
Cal. Gov't Code § 20574.
The legislative history of the 1982 enactment of PERL § 20574 explains that it is premised, in part, on the possibility of contract termination in a federal bankruptcy case:
Lamoureux Direct Testimony, Ex. 13.
The PERL § 20574 termination lien qualifies as a "statutory lien" under the Bankruptcy Code. A "statutory lien" is a lien arising solely by force of a statute on specified circumstances or conditions or lien for distress of rent, even if not based on statute. 11 U.S.C. § 101(53).
By its terms, the termination lien arises solely as a result of PERL § 20574 upon termination of a CalPERS pension servicing contract and only if there is an "actuarially determined deficit in funding for earned benefits." PERL § 20574. Given the strength of the California vested rights doctrine for municipal pensions, it is quite unlikely that such a termination would occur before the filing of a chapter 9 case.
The Bankruptcy Code authorizes the avoidance of statutory liens that are not perfected or enforceable at the time of the commencement of the case. 11 U.S.C. § 545(2).
Since Stockton had not terminated its contract with CalPERS as of the commencement of its chapter 9 case, it would be legally impossible for a lien that had not yet arisen to be perfected or enforceable as of that date.
The § 545 statutory lien avoidance provision applies in a chapter 9 case. 11 U.S.C. § 901(a).
Sovereign immunity is abrogated with respect to § 545. 11 U.S.C. § 106(a) (1).
The consequence of avoidance of a statutory lien on property of the estate is that the avoided transfer is preserved for the benefit of the estate. 11 U.S.C. § 551.
As with the statutory lien avoidance provision, § 551 applies in chapter 9 cases and is the subject of an abrogation of sovereign immunity. 11 U.S.C. §§ 901(a) & 106(a) (1).
It follows that the fixing of the CalPERS termination lien would be avoidable in a chapter 9 case and the debtor municipality would hold subject property free of the statutory lien.
Despite public rhetoric in this case that has been based on an uncritical assumption that the CalPERS termination lien would be a major obstacle to dealing with CalPERS, the vulnerability of that lien to avoidance under § 545 renders it a toothless tiger.
None of this means that public pensions can be rejected or unilaterally modified willy-nilly.
Although the business judgment rule governs most § 365 contract rejections, the Supreme Court held in its 1984
Under the
While Congress supplanted the Bildisco analysis in chapter 11 cases with the enactment of § 1113 for collective bargaining agreements and § 1114 for retiree benefits, neither of those provisions is incorporated by § 901 into chapter 9.
The judicial consensus is that in chapter 9 the
The same considerations that led the Supreme Court to impose a more stringent standard to the rejection or modification of collective bargaining agreements apply to executory municipal pension plans. There is no reason to believe that the
But the situation is potentially different with respect to a municipality's contract with a pension servicer, such as CalPERS, to service the municipality's pensions. That contract is essentially administrative in nature and does not govern the terms of the municipal pension. It may be that the business judgment rule would govern the rejection of the CalPERS contract to service a municipality's pensions. If a lower-cost provider were to emerge, a municipality may, as a matter of business judgment, be able to shift servicers. As the City does not propose to reject the CalPERS servicing contract, that question can be left to another day.
This brings us to the question of confirmation of the City's plan of adjustment.
At the outset, two myths inherent in the rhetoric of this case need to be dispelled. Repetition of incorrect statements does not make them correct.
First, the assertion that CalPERS is the largest creditor of the City is not correct. CalPERS in its own right is only a small-potatoes creditor for the expenses that it is entitled to charge for administering the City-sponsored pension.
The debt relevant to Franklin's rhetoric is the City's obligation to its employees to fund the City-sponsored pension. As has been explained, CalPERS must pass on to retirees the City's shortfalls in funding its City-sponsored pension, which makes CalPERS merely a pass-through conduit to the actual creditors. Cal. Gov't Code § 20577. Hence, the potential pension liability makes the employees and retirees the largest creditors of the City, not CalPERS.
Second, the assertion that pensions are not affected by the City's plan of adjustment incorrectly suggests that employees and retirees are not sharing the pain with capital markets creditors. To the contrary, the reality is that the value of what employees and retirees lose under the plan is greater than what capital markets creditors lose.
One result of this case is that the City terminated its program for lifetime retiree health benefits valued on the schedules at nearly $550 million for existing retirees. Although Franklin says that sum is too high, it concedes that the value is at least $300 million. Prospective retirees also lose that expectation and receive nothing in return. In contrast, Franklin loses about $32 million.
Likewise, pension liabilities are also indirectly reduced as a result of curtailed pay and curtailed future pay increases in the renegotiated collective bargaining agreements.
This court's findings of fact and conclusions of law addressed all of the essential elements for plan confirmation and need not be repeated here. Several key points will provide perspective.
When evaluating the financial situation of the City, it is misleading to focus on comparing the situation on the day the chapter 9 case was filed with the situation at the time of confirmation. Any useful before-and-after view requires that one take into account the effect of the effort to reduce municipal costs during the several years before the case was filed. By the time the case was filed, the City had been pared down to core functions and been reduced to a situation in which such essential services as police were being operated below sustainable standards. The murder rate had soared. Police responded only to crimes in progress. A wrecker had to accompany fire engines on emergency calls.
During the pre-filing mediation required by California law, agreements were achieved modifying all unexpired collective bargaining agreements. And there had been substantial progress on a new contract to replace the expired police contract, which was completed several months after the case was filed.
The quid pro quo for the concessions made by labor in the new and modified collective bargaining agreements was the City's promise not to modify pensions subject to the servicing contract with CalPERS. Pensions would be neither increased nor decreased. This is neither irrational nor inappropriate. Pension underfunding is not a burning issue for the City, which is current on its pension contribution obligations. As noted above, on an actuarial basis the City's two plans are funded at 82.6 percent and 88.5 percent, which is below the goal of 100 percent. Future required payments to return to a better funded status following CalPERS' recent reduction in its expected rate of investment return are built into the budget on which the plan is based; they are for a finite number of years and do not support the argument that the required contributions to CalPERS are on an endless upward spiral. The evidence suggests that funding ratios are improving, rather than deteriorating. To mandate that pensions be modified would so fundamentally change the balance in the labor negotiations as to unravel all of the concessions achieved.
During the case, there were extensive mediation sessions with Bankruptcy Judge Elizabeth Perris. In addition to resolving outstanding labor issues, complex agreements were hammered out with all of the capital markets creditors except Franklin. Payments were adjusted, terms were extended by about a decade, bond debt was reduced, the City's pledge of its general revenues as collateral was extinguished, and the City obtained the use of such facilities as its new city hall that had been taken over by creditors.
The ability to pay the capital markets creditors the agreed amounts contemplated a tax increase that, under California law, required a vote of the people. The voters of the City ultimately approved a sales tax increase in the greatest amount and longest period permitted by California law. If that tax increase had not been approved, all the parties agreed that the mediated plan would be dead, putting the case back to "square one."
Franklin differs from the other capital markets creditors in that it issued its $36 million in bonds without taking equivalent collateral. It turned out that its collateral was worth only about $4 million, which sum is being paid in full by the City. The rest is unsecured debt, to be paid the same 1 percent as all other unsecured creditors, including the retirees on their $550 million in terminated health benefits.
There is no evidence suggesting that Franklin was misled about the quality of its collateral when it entered into its transaction with the City; nor is there any evidence to suggest that Franklin's pricing of the transaction did not reflect the greater risk being undertaken in order to get a higher return.
It is interesting that the settlement with the other capital markets creditors included an additional "sweetener" fund that would become available by about 2040 if the City prospers. Part of that fund was offered to Franklin and held open for Franklin to join even during the confirmation hearing, but Franklin refused the offer.
The time has come to decide the confirmation question. The myriad parties in interest, save Franklin, have agreed upon a consensual plan of adjustment that reflects a complex balance achieved through many months of exhaustive mediation.
As explained in open court, this court is persuaded that no better plan is likely under the circumstances. Everyone has made substantial concessions.
Franklin is receiving about $4.35 million on its $36 million in bonds that were largely unsecured. While that is unfortunate for Franklin, it reflects the bargain that Franklin made and the risk that it undertook. Its 12 percent overall return is not so paltry or unfair as to undermine the legitimacy of classification in the plan or the good faith of the plan proponent.
Although pensions may, as a matter of law, be modified by way of a chapter 9 plan of adjustment and although a CalPERS pension serving contract may be rejected without fear of an enforceable termination lien, the City's choice to achieve savings in total compensation by negotiating salary and benefit adjustments rather than pension modification is appropriate. Total compensation, of which pensions are a component, has been reduced. Indeed, the City's employees and retirees have surrendered more value in this chapter 9 case than the capital markets creditors.
The plan is feasible and is in the best interests of creditors. All other element of confirmation having been established, the plan will be CONFIRMED.
First Amended Plan For the Adjustment of Debts of City of Stockton, California, As Amended (August 8, 2014), at 43-44.
Cal. Gov't Code § 20460.
Cal. Gov't Code § 20090.
CAL. CONST. art. XVI, § 17(f)
CAL. CONST. art. XVI, § 17(a)
CAL. CONST. art. XVI, § 17(g)
Cal. Gov't Code § 20461.
Cal. Gov't Code § 20463.
Cal. Gov't Code § 20487.
Cal. Gov't Code § 20573.
Cal. Gov't Code § 20574.
Cal. Gov't Code § 20576(a).
Cal. Gov't Code § 20576(b).
Cal. Gov't Code § 20577.
MUNNELL, at 61-62.
Stockton Safety Plan:
Stockton Miscellaneous Plan:
Lamoureux Decl., Ex. 6 & 7.
Cal. Gov't Code § 20574.
11 U.S.C. § 903.
11 U.S.C. § 904.
11 U.S.C. § 103(f).
11 U.S.C. § 943(b) (6).
MUNNELL, at 119-20.
11 U.S.C. § 101(53).
11 U.S.C. § 545.
11 U.S.C. § 551.