Musgrave, Senior Judge:
The defendant's International Trade Administration, U.S. Department of Commerce ("Commerce") has submitted its third Final Results of Redetermination Pursuant to Court Remand ("Redetermination" or "RR3") on the antidumping duty investigation into Certain Coated Paper from the PRC.
On remand, Commerce determined to disregard the MEP prices for the relevant inputs from Thailand because they had likely benefitted from subsidies and therefore were likely distorted. This changed the calculation of the normal value for APP-China but not the number of APP-China sales that were found to be targeted. See RR3 at 10. Commerce also considered whether its current differential pricing methodology involving the Cohen's d test was a more appropriate measure of whether the targeted sales were "pervasive" than the prior Nails test. Id. at 8-11. After considering the question, Commerce determined that it was not; therefore it continued to rely on the Nails test in determining that APP-China's targeted was not "pervasive." Id. However, due to the changes in APP-China's calculated normal value occasioned by the foregoing, Commerce determined that it was appropriate
APP-China contests Commerce's decision to reject the Thai input prices, and the defendant-intervenors ("Appleton") argue for remand of the targeted dumping issue, in particular the agency's decision to rely on the Nails test instead of differential pricing analysis. These issues are addressed in turn.
APP-China argues that Commerce's disregard of Thai prices for certain inputs represents an unexplained and unlawful reversal from the second remand determination. See generally APP-China Br. at 2-11. The court concludes otherwise.
As previously noted, Commerce may disregard prices for inputs purchased from market-economy countries based on its prior findings that a country maintained broadly-available, non-industry-specific export subsidies, if there is no evidence that the subsidy had been terminated and the flow of benefits had ceased. See Gold East III, 39 CIT at ___, 61 F.Supp.3d at 1297-98. Among other things, Commerce's normal practice when analyzing whether claimed MEPs for inputs are useable is to provide parties with an opportunity to submit "evidence that the program has been terminated and flow of the residual benefits has ceased". See id., 39 CIT at ___ n. 16, 61 F.Supp.3d at 1297 n. 16 (quoting Commerce's practice). Commerce in the second remand explained its practice but at the time believed that its use had been precluded by the law of the case. Gold East III, however, clarified that the practice was not inconsistent therewith and could be used. See id., 39 CIT at ___, 61 F.Supp.3d at 1297-98. Thus, during the third remand, Commerce applied its normal practice and analyzed the evidence that had been submitted during the second remand in accordance with its established standards. See RR3 at 6, 15.
Commerce explained that the evidence indicated that the Thai Tax Certificates for Export program had previously been countervailed as a generally-available export subsidy. See RR3 at 6, citing Certain Apparel From Thailand: Final Results of Countervailing Duty Administrative Review, 62 Fed.Reg. 63071 (Nov. 26, 1997) ("1997 Apparel Review"). Absent evidence that the program was terminated and the flow of benefits ceased, Commerce considers that the benefits under the program continue, and in this matter Commerce found that such evidence had not been provided.
APP-China argues that Commerce improperly changed its position from the second remand, or that it did not articulate
APP-China contends that the presumption Commerce uses contravenes the Federal Circuit's holding in AK Steel Corp. v. United States, 192 F.3d 1367 (Fed.Cir. 1999). APP-China Br. at 3-4. In APP-China's view, that case stands for the proposition that Commerce "must provide evidence to support a reasonable inference that the subsidy continues into the period of investigation." Id. (emphasis omitted). AK Steel considered what evidence was required to support finding that a countervailable subsidy actually existed for purposes of actually imposing a countervailing duty order. See generally AK Steel, 192 F.3d at 1370. The Federal Circuit explained that when analyzing this issue in the context of a full-blown countervailing duty investigation, the fact that a subsidy existed at some point is insufficient; it must be found to have existed during the relevant period. AK Steel, 192 F.3d at 1376. AK Steel is therefore inapposite, because the standard for finding the existence of a subsidy in the countervailing duty context necessary to support imposition of a countervailing duty is higher, and therefore different, from a "reason to believe or suspect" standard that permits disregard of prices Commerce reasonably believes or suspects are distorted.
APP-China's argument that Commerce's remand analysis does not satisfy the test set out in Fuyao II fails for the same reason. See APP-China Br. at 5-7. The decision in Gold East III clarified that Fuyao II is just one way that Commerce
Commerce first recognized that it had previously countervailed the Thai tax coupon program as an export subsidy and pointed to a determination in which it had done so. See RR3 at 6, 18. Commerce described this program as one through which the Thai government "issue[d] tax certificates to exporters of record to rebate indirect taxes and import duties levied on inputs into exported products." Id. at 18 n.77. Next, Commerce explained that, under its practice, once the agency has determined that a particular program is countervailable, there is a presumption that the subsidy continues to exist absent evidence that the program has been terminated or benefits have ceased. Id. at 6-7; see Gold East III, 39 CIT at ___, 61 F.Supp.3d at 1297. Commerce noted that APP-China has placed no information on the record to suggest that the program has been terminated or that benefits have ceased, and therefore this presumption has not been rebutted. RR3 at 6. Finally, Commerce explained that the existence and availability of the countervailable export subsidy makes it reasonable to assume that the export prices of Thai goods are distorted. Id. at 6-7. Cf. China Nat'l Mach. Imp. & Exp. Corp. v. United States, 27 C.I.T. 1553, 1558, 293 F.Supp.2d 1334, 1339 (2003) ("Commerce's actions are reasonable because a company like CMC's suppliers may have benefitted from a generally available subsidy program given the competitive nature of the industry and by virtue of having engaged in foreign trade"). Commerce's remand thus articulates the basis for finding Thai prices distorted: it explains that the evidence of prior broadly-available, non-industry-specific export subsidies gives rise to an inference that prices may remain distorted by such subsidies, and justifies disregarding those prices in the absence of contrary evidence. No more is required.
Turning away from the legal standard, APP-China challenges how Commerce evaluated the evidence before it. But these challenges have no greater merit. For example, APP-China complains that Commerce improperly found the existence of generally-available subsidies based on only one piece of evidence — the 1997 Apparel Review. APP-China Br. at 5. But that ignores that Commerce also observed that it repeatedly "countervailed the Tax Certificates for Export Program as an export subsidy, first in 1989 Iron Pipe Investigation," as well as the 1997 Apparel Review. RR3 at 18 (citations omitted). Each of these determinations was supported by a fully-developed administrative record showing that Thai exporters were, in fact, receiving subsidies.
Contrary to APP-China's assertions, the mere fact that time had passed since these determinations were made does not, in itself, demonstrate that the subsidy terminated and the flow of benefits has ceased. See APP-China Br. at 5. Rather, under Commerce's normal practice (recognized in Gold East III as consistent with prior judicial decisions) APP-China was required to provide affirmative evidence to rebut the presumption that the program continues. The fact that the orders countervailing the tax coupon program had
APP-China's suggestion that the information petitioners submitted during the investigation may pertain to a different subsidy program than the one found to be countervailable in the 1997 Apparel Review is not relevant for the same reason. See APP-China's Br. at 8. Simply put, Commerce is not required to provide affirmative evidence that the subsidy found in the 1997 Apparel Review remains unchanged in all respects to infer that prices may continue to be distorted — rather, APP-China must provide affirmative evidence that the program was terminated and the flow of benefits has ceased. Commerce expressly declined to decide on remand whether the evidence submitted by petitioners "provide[d] an additional basis for the reason to believe or suspect" that prices may have been distorted, explaining that such a finding is not necessary. See RR3 at 16. APP-China's critiques of that evidence are therefore unavailing. See APP-China Br. at 8-9.
As an alternative argument, APP-China speculates that the information submitted by petitioners may nevertheless show that the subsidy program was somehow modified to no longer providing a subsidy. See APP-China Br. at 10. However, APP-China did not persuade Commerce that any subsequent modifications to the law under which the program was originally established have led to termination of the program and cause the flow of the benefits to cease, and Commerce found no reason to assume that they did.
APP-China also argues that the tax program is a fact-specific export subsidy, not
Commerce's response is that such findings are only required if it needed to establish for certain the particular amount of a subsidy that actually existed, whereas the statutory requirement that it have a "reason to believe or suspect" that prices may be subsidized requires no such showing. Commerce also notes that in the 1997 Apparel Review, it found that the Tax Certificates for Export program is an export subsidy, which can benefit companies in a number of different ways. Def's Resp. at 11, referencing Certain Apparel From Thailand: Preliminary Results of Countervailing Duty Administrative Review, 62 FR 46475, 46477 (Sep. 3, 1997), unchanged in 1997 Apparel Review, and Wheatland Tube Corp. v. United States, 17 C.I.T. 1230, 1231, 841 F.Supp. 1222, 1224 (1993) (explaining that "tax certificates rebate indirect taxes and duties on both physically incorporated inputs, and non-physically incorporated inputs (e.g. fuel, office equipment and services)" and "remission of indirect taxes and duties on the non-physically incorporated inputs is countervailable").
In the absence of such evidence, it was not unreasonable for Commerce to presume the continued existence of a broadly-available, non-industry-specific program that may have distorted APP-China's suppliers' prices, and in the final analysis, APP-China does not point to any affirmative evidence showing that the subsidy program was terminated and the flow of benefits had ceased. Instead, APP-China essentially asks the court to infer as much based on its own weighing of the evidence on the record, which the court cannot do. The question is not whether the court agrees with Commerce's conclusion or whether it would have reached the same result as Commerce if the matter were here de novo, the question is rather whether the agency's decision is reasonable and supported by the record as a whole. See Nippon Steel Corp. v. United States, 458 F.3d 1345, 1352 (Fed.Cir.2006) (citing Mitsubishi Heavy Indus., Ltd. v. United States, 275 F.3d 1056, 1060 (Fed.Cir.2001)).
For its part, Appleton continues to argue that Commerce should have employed the Cohen's d test in its targeted dumping analysis. According to Appleton, Commerce's current Cohen's d test is the best way to determine whether the respondent's targeted dumping was "pervasive" and therefore appropriate to determining whether the remedy normally applied to targeted sales should be used on all sales made by respondents. However, Appleton's comments do not show that Commerce's decision to use the Nails test was unreasonable.
The question of whether a respondent's targeting is pervasive derives from Commerce's earlier regulation which has since been withdrawn. See 19 C.F.R. § 351.414(c)(1) (2004). That regulation provided that Commerce would "normally" account for a respondent's targeting by applying the average-to-transaction (A-T) comparison only to targeted sales, and apply the standard — and statutorily preferred — average-to-average (A-A) comparison to the remainder. Id.; see also 19 U.S.C. §§ 1677f-1(d)(1)(A) (defining A-A, as the preferred methodology); 1677f-1(d)(1)(B)(ii) (permitting the use of the average-to-transaction methodology only if Commerce explained why one of the default approaches could not account for the observed pattern of price differences).
The regulation provided that applying the A-T comparison to all of a respondent's sales would be appropriate if the respondent's targeting was "pervasive" or impossible to segregate. See Antidumping Duties; Countervailing Duties, 61 Fed.Reg. 7308, 7350 (Feb. 27, 1996); Antidumping Duties; Countervailing Duties, 62 Fed.Reg. 27296, 27375 (May 19, 1997) (Preamble). Because Gold East I found the attempt to withdraw that regulation in 2008 ineffective, the regulation continued to apply to the proceeding at bar. See generally Gold East I, 37 CIT ___, 918 F.Supp.2d 1317, 1327-28 (2013) (directing Commerce to apply the regulation in this case). Thus, the orders of remand requested Commerce to consider the best way to measure "pervasiveness", for example through Commerce's prior targeted dumping analysis known as the Nails test, or through its new, recently developed, differential pricing methodology including the Cohen's d analysis. See Gold East III, 39 CIT at ___, 61 F.Supp.3d at 1305-06.
Considering the question, Commerce determined that the Nails test was a more appropriate way to measure pervasiveness under the old regulation because Commerce's current differential pricing methodology was developed after the withdrawal of the regulation that established the pervasiveness requirement and was not designed to evaluate the regulation's criteria. RR3 at 10. In Commerce's words, the differential pricing "analysis was not designed to evaluate, and does not address" the requirements of "the withdrawn targeted dumping regulation." Id. Accordingly, Commerce continued to rely on the Nails test. Id. Using that test, Commerce concluded that "the percentage of targeted sales in this case is not large enough to demonstrate that the targeted dumping is so pervasive or widespread as to justify" applying the A-T comparison to all of APP-China's sales. Commerce therefore applied the A-T test only to the targeted sales.
Commerce points out that Appleton does not dispute that there is no basis to apply the A-T comparison more broadly if the Nails test is used to measure "pervasiveness" — that is, they do not dispute that, under the Nails test, APP-China's targeted
Appleton also argues that the Cohen's d test should be used to answer the "pervasiveness" question because it is a valid statistical tool that represents a refinement over the Nails test. Def-Ints' Br. at 7. Responding, Commerce contends the argument fails for two reasons.
Commerce first contends Appleton's argument conflates different concepts, in that the differential pricing analysis is a refinement of determining whether sales satisfy the statutory criteria of forming a pattern of prices that differ significantly among consumers regions or time periods, not a refinement for determining whether targeted sales are pervasive. Commerce states that the reason for this is that the differential pricing analysis was developed at a time when Commerce understood the pervasiveness requirement to no longer apply, and that unlike the Nails test the differential pricing analysis "does not even measure the extent of targeted dumping per se — rather, it measures all sales, those above and below normal value that exhibit a pattern of significant price differences" — and using differential pricing analysis to measure "pervasiveness" of targeted (and dumped) sales "would therefore be extending the test far beyond its intended usage." Def's Resp. at 15, referencing RR3 at 21-22.
The above explanation seems contrived.
Because the methodology that Commerce employed in its remand redetermination was reasonable, the results will be