LEGROME D. DAVIS, District Judge.
AND NOW, this 14th day of September 2010, it is hereby ORDERED that the Motion to Dismiss of Defendants Bristow Group Inc., Era Helicopters, LLC, Era Group Inc., Era Aviation, Inc., PHI, Inc., and Seacor Holdings Inc. (Doc. No. 22) is GRANTED. Accordingly, it is further ORDERED that the Complaint of Plaintiff Superior Offshore International, Inc. (Doc. No. 1) is DISMISSED.
In this putative class action, Plaintiff alleges that Defendants are liable under the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1, which requires a "contract, combination . . ., or conspiracy in restraint of trade or commerce." Defendants move to dismiss the Complaint under Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 12(b)(6) for failure to state a claim upon which relief can be granted. We conclude that Plaintiffs Complaint must be dismissed because the facts pled do not plausibly allow a reasonable inference that Defendants are liable for the misconduct alleged.
Plaintiff filed its Complaint on June 12, 2009. Defendants filed the instant motion to dismiss on September 4, 2009, in lieu of answering the Complaint.
Plaintiff alleges
Plaintiff alleges that for nearly a decade from 1990 through 2000, the oil and gas industry "experienced an extended period of depressed demand and flat [stable] pricing." (Id. ¶¶ 29-30.) Plaintiff alleges that a downturn in oil prices in the late 1990s led to a reduction in drilling for oil and gas in the Gulf of Mexico, which decreased demand for Defendants' services and, in turn, their earnings. (Id. ¶¶ 44-46, 50.) Plaintiff alleges that after the terrorist attacks on September 11, 2001, there was another downturn in oil prices and production, and a consequent decrease in demand for Defendants' services. (Id. ¶ 47.)
Plaintiff alleges that between January 1, 2001, and December 31, 2005, Defendants conspired "to fix, raise, maintain or stabilize" the prices of helicopter services to offshore oil and gas industries in the Gulf of Mexico. (Id. ¶¶ 1, 27, 29-35.) Plaintiff's conspiracy claim rests on allegations of contemporaneous and uniform price increases by Defendants. Plaintiff thus alleges that Defendants, "[i]n the first half of 2001, . . . implemented two across-theboard price increases totaling 30%" and that by the end of 2005, Defendants had "rais[ed] rates by approximately 50%." (Id. ¶¶ 30, 35.) According to Plaintiff, this conduct artificially inflated prices for Defendants' services. (Id. ¶ 17.)
Although Plaintiff alleges that Defendants "agreed" to implement these price increases in concert, no allegations of fact are pled that directly bear on the formation of an anti-competitive agreement. Apart from identifying a four-year period from January 1, 2001, through December 31, 2005, during which the § 1 violations allegedly occurred in the Gulf of Mexico region, Plaintiff does not state any specific time, place, or person involved in the alleged conspiracy. There are no allegations as to which of the Defendants, let alone which of their employees or officers, agreed with another to restrain competition by fixing prices, or how, when, and where any illegal agreement took place. Plaintiff makes no factual contentions that any Defendant specifically did or said something to create an understanding on pricing. Plaintiff makes no allegations of any individual's firsthand, personal knowledge of the alleged conspiracy.
In the absence of any allegations of direct evidence of an agreement or concerted action, Plaintiff necessarily supports its conspiracy claim with allegations about the circumstances surrounding the price increases and the market for helicopter services in the Gulf of Mexico during the relevant period. Plaintiff alleges these circumstances show that the helicopter-services market was vulnerable to antitrust conspiracy. (Id. ¶¶ 43-81.) Plaintiff further alleges that these vulnerabilities support sequential inferences that Defendants not only had opportunities and motive to conspire to fix prices, but also that they actually did so conspire and then acted as an illegal cartel. (Id.) As shown by the following, the pled circumstances and market conditions were publically available to all market participants.
Specifically, Plaintiff alleges that despite the decreased demand for helicopter services, a combination of market conditions
Plaintiff also alleges that because Defendants dominated the market for offshore helicopter services during the relevant period, this "high degree of concentration" in the "insular," "close-knit" helicopter-services market, along with the high barriers that existed for potential competitors who wanted to enter this business, made it "easier to coordinate behavior among coconspirators." (Id. ¶¶ 51, 78; see also id. ¶¶ 40, 52-58, 79-81.)
Plaintiff further alleges that Defendants had ample opportunities to conspire. Plaintiff alleges that Defendants shared a similar cost structure for helicopter-service businesses in the same geographical market, which cost information they shared through their participation in helicopter trade organizations. (Id. ¶¶ 65-67, 72-77.) Plaintiff alleges that various trade associations met regularly during the relevant period, "fostering the opportunities for the conspiracy." (Id. ¶ 68.) Based on Defendants' participation in such meetings, Plaintiff alleges Defendants did conspire to raise prices. (Id. ¶¶ 69-77.) Plaintiff alleges that in the helicopter-services industry, "[m]anagerial and executive level officials move[d] from one competitor to another," which "gave Defendants additional opportunities to conspire." (Id. ¶ 81.)
Plaintiff further supports its conspiracy claim with allegations that on June 15, 2005, the Department of Justice Antitrust Division ("DOJ"), in conjunction with a grand jury investigation concerning possible antitrust violations in the offshore helicopter-services industry, served criminal document subpoenas on some Defendants. (Id. ¶¶ 36-42.) Although the investigation allegedly is ongoing, it is undisputed that it has resulted in no indictments to date. Plaintiff does not otherwise plead any facts concerning the nature, scope, or status of the DOJ's investigation.
Plaintiff further supports its conspiracy claim with quotations from newspaper and media reports, (id. ¶¶ 33-34, 44-46, 49, 52-54), and annual Form 10-K reports filed by some Defendants with the Securities and Exchange Commission ("SEC"), (id. ¶¶ 32, 41-42, 50, 54), alleging that these reports support an inference of price-fixing. Most of these reports reference only the author's or speaker's views concerning the Defendants' rate increases, improved revenue and earnings, and stock prices. For example, Plaintiff alleges that Lance Bospflug, Chief Executive Officer of Defendant PHI, Inc., was quoted in December 2001 as saying that "[t]he improvement in revenue and earnings is primarily related to the implementation of rate increases in January and May of this year." (Id. ¶ 46, quoting Helicopter News, Dec. 4, 2001.) Plaintiff alleges that Peter Ricchiuti, Assistant Business Dean at Tulane University and an investment analyst, was quoted as saying that he had "never seen a [cl]earer example of bad news [decreased demand], good stock price[.]" (Id. ¶ 46, quoting New Orleans City Business, June 21, 2001.) Plaintiff alleges that Defendant Bristow Group Inc. ("Bristow") acknowledged that "[t]he disproportionate increase in revenue in relation to flight hours was primarily due to rate increases . . . which went into effect in January and June
Plaintiff alleges that one news article in particular strongly supports an inference of a price-fixing conspiracy. (Id. ¶ 34; see also Pl.'s Br., Doc. 37 at 8.) The President of Bristow was quoted as publically stating: "I'm concerned about them [new competitors] coming into the market and trying to increase their market share by putting downward pressure on rates. If they are operating out there with inadequate support, and something bad happens, it will be bad for the entire industry." (Id. ¶ 34, quoting Oil and Gas Investor, May 29, 2004.)
Plaintiff relies on another news article as an even more compelling reason to infer a price-fixing conspiracy, alleging the article confirms an admission of concerted action. (Id. ¶ 33; see also Pl.'s Br., Doc. 37 at 8, 20.) Responding to a question about the price increases, an unidentified "operator" was quoted as saying: "If we were to say that the helicopter operators all got together and agreed to these increases, that would be illegal; it would be price fixing. Let's just say that everyone more or less agreed to the necessity of a more or less equal rate hike for everyone." (Id. ¶ 33, quoting Bill Wagstaff, "Gulf Coast Oil Support Struggles to Keep Its Footing Amid Uncertain Times," Aviation International News, April 2002.)
Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 8(a)(2) requires a pleading to set forth a "short and plain statement of the claim showing that the pleader is entitled to relief." Rule 8 does not require "detailed factual allegations," but it demands more than "labels and conclusions" or "a formulaic recitation of the elements of a cause of action." Bell Atl. Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544, 555, 127 S.Ct. 1955, 167 L.Ed.2d 929 (2007). A complaint is not sufficient if it offers "naked assertion[s]" without "further factual enhancement." Id. at 557, 127 S.Ct. 1955. A plaintiff must provide the grounds for its entitlement to relief and "[f]actual allegations must be enough to raise a right to relief above the speculative level." Id. at 555, 127 S.Ct. 1955. "A claim has facial plausibility when the plaintiff pleads factual content that allows the court to draw the reasonable inference that the defendant is liable for the misconduct alleged." Ashcroft v. Iqbal, ___ U.S. ___, 129 S.Ct. 1937, 1949, 173 L.Ed.2d 868 (U.S.2009). In determining whether a pleading states a plausible claim, all factual allegations must be assumed to be true; however, conclusory statements and legal conclusions are not entitled to the assumption of truth. Id. at 1949-50.
Applying these general standards to a § 1 claim, a well-pleaded complaint must state "enough factual matter (taken as true) to suggest that an agreement was made." In re Ins. Brokerage Antitrust Litig., 618 F.3d 300, 320 (3d Cir.2010) (citing Phillips v. County of Allegheny, 515 F.3d 224, 234 (3d Cir.2008) (quoting
The Sherman Act § 1 "does not prohibit [all] restraints of trade . . . but only restraints effected by a contract, combination or conspiracy." Copperweld Corp. v. Indep. Tube Corp., 467 U.S. 752, 775, 104 S.Ct. 2731, 81 L.Ed.2d 628 (1984); In re Baby Food Antitrust Litig., 166 F.3d 112, 117 & n. 3 (3d Cir.1999) (noting that courts have interpreted these three terms together to require some sort of "concerted action"). "It does not reach conduct that is `wholly unilateral,'" no matter the motivation. Copperweld, 467 U.S. at 768, 104 S.Ct. 2731 (citation omitted); In re Ins. Brokerage, 618 F.3d at 314 & n. 10. Section 1 claims thus always require the existence of an agreement. "To allege such an agreement between two or more persons or entities, a plaintiff must allege facts plausibly suggesting `a unity of purpose or a common design and understanding, or a meeting of minds in an unlawful arrangement.'" Howard Hess Dental Lab. Inc. v. Dentsply Int'l, Inc., 602 F.3d 237, 254 (3d Cir.2010) (quoting Copperweld, 467 U.S. at 771, 104 S.Ct. 2731 (internal quotation marks omitted)); see In re Flat Glass Antitrust Litig., 385 F.3d 350, 357 (3d Cir.2004) (quoting Monsanto Co. v. Spray—Rite Serv. Corp., 465 U.S. 752, 764, 104 S.Ct. 1464, 79 L.Ed.2d 775 (1984) (requiring "a conscious commitment to a common scheme")). Therefore, the "crucial question" is whether the challenged anti-competitive conduct "stem[s] from independent decision or from an agreement, tacit or express." Theatre Enter., Inc. v. Paramount Film Distrib. Corp., 346 U.S. 537, 540, 74 S.Ct. 257, 98 L.Ed. 273 (1954).
Circumstantial evidence of parallel business conduct is probative but not sufficient to establish a proscribed anti-competitive agreement among market participants. Theatre Enter., 346 U.S. at 540-41, 74 S.Ct. 257. In the absence of direct evidence of an anti-competitive agreement, evidence of parallel business conduct is ambiguous in that it may be "consistent with conspiracy, but just as much in line with a wide swath of rational and competitive business strategy unilaterally prompted by common perceptions of the market." Twombly, 550 U.S. at 554, 127 S.Ct. 1955.
For example, parallel pricing may result from illegal price fixing or instead, from lawful unilateral and independent conduct of competitors, where their decisions are interdependent:
6 Phillip E. Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, ANTITRUST LAW § 1429a, at 207 (2d ed. 2003). In other words, such evidence may support both an inference of proscribed agreement and an inference of lawful conduct:
In re Baby Food, 166 F.3d at 122 (internal quotation marks and citations omitted); see also In re Ins. Brokerage, 618 F.3d at 321 & nn. 10, 19 (noting that such oligopolistic behavior or "conscious parallelism" is often adverse to consumer interests, "nonetheless [courts have] found that it is not, without more, sufficient evidence of a § 1 violation, both because it is not an agreement within the meaning of the Sherman Act, and because it is resistant to judicial remedies"); Twombly, 550 U.S. at 553-54, 127 S.Ct. 1955 (noting that "[e]ven `conscious parallelism,' a common reaction of `firms in a concentrated market [that] recogniz[e] their shared economic interests and their interdependence with respect to price and output decisions' is `not in itself unlawful'") (quoting Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209, 227, 113 S.Ct. 2578, 125 L.Ed.2d 168 (1993)).
Antitrust law restricts the range of acceptable inferences that may be drawn from ambiguous circumstantial evidence in order to "avoid deterring innocent conduct that reflects enhanced, rather than restrained, competition." In re Flat Glass, 385 F.3d at 357; see also Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 588, 106 S.Ct. 1348, 89 L.Ed.2d 538 (1986) (reaffirming that "antitrust law limits the range of permissible inferences from ambiguous evidence in a § 1 case" in order to avoid deterring "permissible competition"). Given the ambiguity of interdependent parallel business behavior, allegations of such conduct, standing alone, are not sufficient to state a plausible contract, combination, or conspiracy in violation of the Sherman Act § 1:
In re Ins. Brokerage, 618 F.3d at 322-23 (footnote omitted) (quoting Twombly, 550 U.S. at 557, 560, 567, 127 S.Ct. 1955). As a result, the Third Circuit requires a plaintiff,
Although there is no finite set or exhaustive list of such criteria, the Third Circuit has recognized three "plus factors": (1) evidence that the defendant had a motive to enter into a price fixing conspiracy; (2) evidence that the defendant acted contrary to its interests; and (3) evidence implying a traditional conspiracy. In re Flat Glass, 385 F.3d at 360. The Third Circuit cautions that "care must be taken with the first two types of evidence, each of which may indicate simply that the defendants operate in an oligopolistic market, that is, may simply restate the (legally insufficient) fact that market behavior is interdependent and characterized by conscious parallelism." In re Ins. Brokerage, 618 F.3d at 322; In re Flat Glass, 385 F.3d at 360-61 (acknowledging that in the context of parallel pricing in an oligopoly, "the first two factors largely restate the phenomena of interdependence," and may not suffice—by themselves—to support a claim of horizontal price-fixing by oligopolists). Thus, in a highly concentrated, interdependent oligopolistic market such as that alleged here, the third factor, "evidence implying a traditional conspiracy," becomes crucial. This factor requires allegations of "non-economic evidence that there was an actual, manifest agreement not to compete, which may include proof that the defendants got together and exchanged assurances of common action or otherwise adopted a common plan even though no meetings, conversation, or exchanged documents are shown." In re Ins. Brokerage, 618 F.3d at 322 (citations and internal quotation marks omitted).
Plaintiff sets forth no factual allegations directly bearing on the formation of an agreement to fix prices during the relevant period. Although in numerous paragraphs of its pleading, Plaintiff avers that Defendants "agreed" or "conspired" to inflate their prices, such conclusory allegations are not entitled to a presumption of truth on a motion to dismiss. Assessing a conspiracy pled under 42 U.S.C. § 1983 in light of the pleading standards set forth in Twombly, the Third Circuit recently instructed:
Great W. Mining & Mineral Co. v. Fox Rothschild LLP, No. 09-3189, 615 F.3d 159, 178 (3d Cir.2010) (quoting Iqbal, 129 S.Ct. at 1951).
Plaintiff is mistaken that the statement reportedly made by an unidentified "operator" that "everyone more or less agreed to the necessity of a more or less equal rate hike for everyone," confirms an agreement among Defendants. (Pl.'s Compl. ¶ 33.) This statement is not direct evidence of an agreement. "Direct evidence of a conspiracy, such as a document or conversation explicitly manifesting
Moreover, the relevance of the operator's statement as circumstantial evidence of an agreement is dubious. Even taking the operator's reported words for the truth, his statement is ambiguous as to whether he comments on the industry's lawful but interdependent pricing decisions; casual observations about the general convergence of prices among unnamed market participants at that time; or perhaps an illegal agreement by unnamed actors at some unspecified point in time. Plaintiff does not plead which of the Defendants supposedly agreed with another to restrain competition by fixing prices, or how, when, and where the illegal agreement took place. Instead, Plaintiff throws a blanket charge of conspiracy over all Defendants based on their parallel price increases, implying that each conspired to fix prices.
Plaintiff's charge of conspiracy among Defendants rests entirely on inferences to be drawn from alleged economic and other non-economic circumstances. The question thus becomes whether Plaintiff has alleged sufficient factual content that would justify a reasonable inference that any Defendant illegally agreed with one or more other Defendants, making any such Defendants liable for the misconduct alleged.
Plaintiff alleges economic circumstances amounting to a textbook example of an industry that is vulnerable to efforts to implement and maintain supracompetitive prices. Plaintiff thus alleges that the market for helicopter services in the Gulf of Mexico is a highly concentrated, interdependent oligopoly in which Defendants were the "dominant players" holding a combined 90% market share. Plaintiff alleges that this market gave Defendants a motive to conspire, afforded them ample opportunities to conspire under cover of legitimate business and professional
The alleged parallel conduct—setting prices at the same level—is probative and consistent with the existence of an agreement among Defendants, but it is not sufficient to establish a proscribed anti-competitive agreement. In a highly concentrated, interdependent market such as that alleged here, the alleged price coordination among the few defending sellers might be the result of an understanding among the sellers to fix prices or it equally might be the result of each seller's lawful independent pricing decisions. Plaintiff thus must establish at least one "plus factor" to state a plausible conspiracy claim. As shown below, Plaintiff fails to do so.
Plaintiff's allegations of Defendants' conspiratorial motives and pricing decisions that were purportedly against each firm's self-interest amount to allegations of Defendants' interdependent conduct. Plaintiff alleges that Defendants' prices for helicopter services uniformly increased in a parallel fashion during a period of decreased demand, concluding that the increases must have resulted from Defendants' illegal agreement because the increases make no economic sense when viewed from the perspective of an ideally competitive market.
Petruzzi's IGA Supermarkets, Inc. v. Darling-Delaware Co., Inc., 998 F.2d 1224, 1244 (3d Cir.1993); see also Areeda, supra, ¶ 1434c1, at 244-45.
Plaintiff quotes a number of newspaper and trade media reports, and portions of mandatory SEC reports filed by Defendants, alleging that these reports support an inference of price-fixing. Even assuming the veracity of the facts reported about Defendants' alleged rate increases, improved revenue and earnings, and stock prices, those facts do not tend to exclude the possibility that Defendants acted independently. The reported facts are consistent with lawful, interdependent business behavior among oligopolists.
Similarly, Plaintiff is mistaken that the reported statement by Bristow's President strongly supports a price-fixing conspiracy. No anti-competitive inferences can be drawn from his reported concern "about [new competitors] coming into the market and trying to increase their market share by putting downward pressure on rates." (Pl.'s Compl. ¶ 34.) It is entirely lawful to compete. See Matsushita, 475 U.S. at 594, 106 S.Ct. 1348 (noting that "cutting prices in order to increase business is the very essence of competition"). Also, no reasonable inference of an agreement can be drawn from his reported concern about new entrants coming into the market and "operating out there with inadequate support, and something bad happens, it will be bad for the entire industry." (Pl.'s Compl. ¶ 34.) There is nothing in the statement that indicates any discussion or collusion among Defendants. Moreover, no reasonable inference can be drawn from this statement of a warning or threat to deter potential entrants from coming into the market. But see Rossi, 156 F.3d at 468 (holding that a rival's threat indicated an anti-competitive agreement, where it was stated that the rival and other named competitors "would do anything they could . . . whatever they had to do they were going to do to keep [the plaintiff] out of business"). Rather, his statement can fairly be read as a concern about potential pricecutting entrants that might operate on a shoestring with "inadequate support" for their operations, implying that pricing below a certain level would require entrants to forego earnings that might be needed for adequate equipment, maintenance, and personnel, at the expense of the industry's reputation for safety in the event of a
Plaintiff's Complaint is devoid of any factual allegations that would allow an inference of a traditional conspiratorial agreement. Plaintiff alleges Defendants had numerous opportunities to conspire at regularly convened trade-association meetings, through their employment of various managers and executives from one helicopter-service firm to another competitor, and in their socializing in a small Louisiana community "in an atmosphere of informal cooperation and mutual interests in the industry." (Pl.'s Compl. ¶¶ 79-80.) Nonetheless, "`[p]roof of opportunity to conspire, without more, will not sustain an inference that a conspiracy has taken place.'" Petruzzi's, 998 F.2d at 1235, 1242 n. 15 (noting that evidence of social calls and telephone contacts among the defendants' representatives was insufficient to exclude the possibility that defendants acted independently); see also In re Baby Food, 166 F.3d at 133-34 (agreeing with the district court that evidence of "chit chat" at chance meetings or trade shows among persons with no pricing authority should be given little, if any weight, because "[c]ompany personnel do not often operate in a vacuum or `plastic bubble'; they sometimes engage in the long-standing tradition of social discourse"). Plaintiff's allegations concerning Defendants' opportunities to conspire thus do not permit a reasonable inference of collusion.
Plaintiff alleges that Defendants openly shared information about their capacity to serve the oil and gas producers, and the costs Defendants commonly faced for fuel, helicopters, support facilities, personnel, and maintenance. Plaintiff makes no allegation of any specific concerted exchange of pricing information between or among Defendants. Defendants' alleged knowledge of their co-competitors' cost structures, and the competitors' "unfettered" exchange of business information, are neither remarkable nor actionable. (Pl.'s Compl. ¶ 72.) Such exchanges among rivals "can in certain circumstances increase economic efficiency and render markets more, rather than less, competitive." In re Baby Food, 166 F.3d at 118, 123, 125-26 (quoting United States v. U.S. Gypsum Co., 438 U.S. 422, 441 n. 16, 98 S.Ct. 2864, 57 L.Ed.2d 854 (1978)). The Third Circuit has clearly ruled that "communications between competitors do not permit an inference of an agreement to fix prices unless `those communications rise to the level of an agreement, tacit or otherwise.'" Id. at 126 (quoting Alvord-Polk, Inc. v. Schumacher & Co., 37 F.3d 996, 1013 (3d Cir. 1994)). Plaintiff alleges only non-actionable exchanges of information, setting forth no facts permitting an inference that the data shared had any impact on pricing decisions.
Plaintiff attempts to bolster its conspiracy theory with allegations that on June 15, 2005, the DOJ served document subpoenas on some Defendants in connection with an investigation of possible antitrust violations among helicopter-service providers in the Gulf of Mexico. Plaintiff provides no other facts about the DOJ's investigation. Although Plaintiff also alleges some Defendants made public announcements and filed mandatory SEC Form 10-K disclosures about the investigation, these reports add no additional facts. (See Pl.'s Compl. ¶¶ 41-42.) Rather, Defendants reported their opinions and predictions about the material risks and impact of the DOJ's investigation. Plaintiff concludes that some Defendants "have acknowledged that they are targets of this antitrust investigation" (Pl.'s Br., Doc. 37 at 13), but this is not supported by the Complaint's wellpleaded facts. (See Pl.'s Compl. ¶¶ 41-42.)
Although Plaintiff pleads that Defendants illegally agreed to raise prices in restraint of trade, this conclusion rests largely on descriptions of Defendants' parallel conduct, not on any allegations of an actual agreement. Although some stray statements conceivably speak of an illegal agreement, they also imply lawful conduct. Because Defendants' alleged parallel price coordination is equally consistent with legal and illegal conduct, the Complaint is insufficient to allege a conspiracy. See, e.g., Hess, 602 F.3d at 256 (affirming dismissal of § 1 claims where the allegations did not offer "even a gos-samer inference of any degree of coordination" among the defendants and did "no more than intimate `merely parallel conduct that could just as well be independent action'" (quoting Twombly, 550 U.S. at 557, 127 S.Ct. 1955)). As the Third Circuit has instructed, "lawful parallel conduct fails to bespeak unlawful agreement. . . . [A]n allegation of parallel conduct and a bare assertion of conspiracy will not suffice." Twombly, 550 U.S. at 556, 127 S.Ct. 1955.
Plaintiff's claim of conspiracy stops short of the line between possibility and plausibility of entitlement to relief. There are not enough facts alleged to suggest that an illegal agreement was made, or to raise a reasonable expectation that discovery will reveal evidence of illegal agreement.
Accordingly, it is ORDERED that Defendants' Motion to Dismiss is granted as to all Defendants. The Clerk of Court is directed to close this matter for statistical purposes.
(Pl.'s Compl. ¶¶ 47, 48.)
Areeda, supra, ¶ 1434c1, at 244-45 (footnotes omitted).