GREGORY A. PRESNELL, UNITED STATES DISTRICT JUDGE.
This matter comes before the Cozurt on motions to dismiss (Doc. 89, 90, 92) filed by various groups of Defendants, the response in opposition (Doc. 98) to those motions filed by the Plaintiffs, and the replies (Doc. 99, 101, 103, 104) filed by the movants. The portions of those motions having to do with the Plaintiffs' state law claims have been referred to Magistrate Judge Smith for disposition by way of a report and recommendation. Accordingly, this order will address only the portions of those motions that deal with the Plaintiffs' claims under federal law.
The instant case is one of 24 similar actions, consolidated for pretrial purposes,
The plaintiffs in the Florida Action filed an amended complaint later that same month. (Doc. 167 in Case No. 6:14-cv-310-Orl-31TBS). Subsequently, various defendants moved to dismiss. In January 2015, this court granted those motions in part, dismissing all the claims in the Florida Action, some with prejudice. (Doc. 291 in Case No. 6:14-cv-310-Orl-31TBS). The Sherman Act claims in that case — one for price-fixing, and one for an illegal boycott — were dismissed because the Florida Action Plaintiffs had failed to adequately plead the existence of an agreement and had failed to adequately allege a concerted refusal to deal, respectively. (Doc. 291 at 20-21 in Case No. 6:14-cv-310-Orl-31TBS). After another amended complaint and another round of motions to dismiss, the Court dismissed the Florida Action with prejudice in September 2015. (Doc. 341 in Case No. 6:14-cv-310-Orl-31TBS). In regard to the antitrust claims, the court again found that the plaintiffs had failed to adequately allege the existence of an agreement or a concerted refusal to deal. (Doc. 341 at 20-21 in Case No. 6:14-cv-310-Orl-31TBS). The plaintiffs in the Florida Action did not appeal that dismissal.
The instant case was filed in the United States District Court for the Southern District of Mississippi in January 2014. (Doc. 1). In March 2014, the Plaintiffs filed an Amended Complaint. (Doc. 3). The United States Judicial Panel on Multidistrict Litigation transferred the case to this Court in August 2014, along with a number of pending motions to dismiss. (Doc. 76). On February 9, 2015, Magistrate Judge Smith entered a Report and Recommendation (Doc. 82) that all of the claims asserted in the Amended Complaint in this matter be dismissed, some with prejudice. On February 27, 2015, the Court adopted the Report and Recommendation. The Plaintiffs filed a Second Amended Complaint (henceforth, the "SAC") (Doc. 87); in response, the Defendants filed another round of motions to dismiss, including those that are the subject of this order.
Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 8(a)(2) requires "a short and plain statement of the claim showing that the pleader is entitled to relief" so as to give the defendant fair notice of what the claim is and the grounds upon which it rests, Conley v. Gibson, 355 U.S. 41, 47, 78 S.Ct. 99, 103, 2 L.Ed.2d 80 (1957), overruled on other grounds, Bell Atlantic Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544, 127 S.Ct. 1955, 167 L.Ed.2d 929 (2007). A Rule 12(b)(6) motion to dismiss for failure to state a claim merely
The plaintiff must provide enough factual allegations to raise a right to relief above the speculative level, Twombly, 550 U.S. at 555, 127 S.Ct. at 1966, and to indicate the presence of the required elements, Watts v. Fla. Int'l Univ., 495 F.3d 1289, 1302 (11th Cir.2007). Conclusory allegations, unwarranted factual deductions or legal conclusions masquerading as facts will not prevent dismissal. Davila v. Delta Air Lines, Inc., 326 F.3d 1183, 1185 (11th Cir.2003).
In Ashcroft v. Iqbal, 556 U.S. 662, 129 S.Ct. 1937, 173 L.Ed.2d 868 (2009), the Supreme Court explained that a complaint need not contain detailed factual allegations, "but it demands more than an unadorned, the-defendant-unlawfully-harmed-me accusation. A pleading that offers labels and conclusions or a formulaic recitation of the elements of a cause of action will not do. Nor does a complaint suffice if it tenders naked assertions devoid of further factual enhancement." Id. 678, 129 S.Ct. at 1949 (internal citations and quotations omitted). "[W]here the well-pleaded facts do not permit the court to infer more than the mere possibility of misconduct, the complaint has alleged — but it has not `show[n]' — `that the plaintiff is entitled to relief.'" Id. at 679, 129 S.Ct. at 1950 (quoting Fed. R. Civ. P. 8(a)(2)).
NO DIRECT EVIDENCE OF CONSPIRACY
According to the allegations of the Second Amended Complaint (Doc. 87), which are accepted in pertinent part as true for purposes of resolving the instant motions, the Plaintiffs are a group of 26
as well as
(SAC at 12-13).
The Plaintiffs go on to assert that the Defendants have
(SAC at 13).
Simply stated, the Plaintiffs complain that all of the Defendants pay Mississippi automobile repair shops (on behalf of the Defendants' insureds or claimants) essentially the same hourly rates for repairs, painting and the like. Those rates, the Plaintiffs allege, are based on market surveys performed by Defendant State Farm Mutual Automobile Insurance Company and Defendant State Farm Fire and Casualty Company (henceforth, collectively, "State Farm"). (SAC at 10, 33). The Plaintiffs allege that State Farm manipulates or fakes the survey results, producing bogus "market rates" that are below the rates actually prevailing in the marketplace. (SAC at 34-37). State Farm insists that it is only willing to pay these bogus market rates, and the other Defendants insist on paying no more than State Farm pays. (SAC at 34-35).
In addition, the Plaintiffs allege that the Defendants have a list of repair procedures for which they all refuse to pay, even when that particular procedure is recommended by the industry's leading repair-estimating databases, (SAC at 45-48), and that the Defendants insist that the shops use cheaper (and lower-quality) parts when performing repairs, (SAC at 52-55). Finally, the Plaintiffs contend that when repair shops balk at any of this, such as by trying to raise their hourly rates or utilize higher-quality parts, they are subject to boycotts in the form of having the Defendants' insureds "steered" away from their shops to compliant shops. (SAC at 68-71).
In Count One, the Plaintiffs allege that the Defendants and unnamed co-conspirators have entered into an agreement "to control and suppress automobile damage repair costs through coercion and intimidation" of the Plaintiffs, all in violation of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1 et seq. (Doc. 87 at 88). Section 1 of the Sherman Act prohibits "[e]very contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States." While § 1 could be interpreted to bar every agreement in restraint of trade, the Supreme Court has long recognized that Congress intended to outlaw only unreasonable restraints. See, e.g., Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical Soc., 457 U.S. 332, 342-43, 102 S.Ct. 2466, 2472-73, 73 L.Ed.2d 48 (1982) (citing United States v. Joint-Traffic Assn., 171 U.S. 505, 19 S.Ct. 25, 43 L.Ed. 259 (1898)). Even where a restraint of trade is unreasonable, it is only prohibited if it was effected by a contract, combination or conspiracy. Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp., 467 U.S. 752, 775, 104 S.Ct. 2731, 2743, 81 L.Ed.2d 628 (1984). Because of this, the "crucial question" in § 1 cases is whether the challenged anticompetitive conduct
As is the norm in antitrust cases, the Plaintiffs here offer no direct evidence that the Defendants have entered into a price-fixing agreement, instead relying on allegations of parallel behavior. A showing of parallel business behavior is admissible circumstantial evidence from which the fact finder may infer agreement, but it falls short of conclusively establishing agreement or itself constituting a Sherman Act offense. Id. (citations omitted). Because of this, stating a claim under Section 1 of the Sherman Act requires "a complaint with enough factual matter (taken as true) to suggest that an agreement was made." Twombly, 550 U.S. at 556, 127 S.Ct. at 1965.
The actions allegedly taken by the Defendants in this case, such as paying the same labor rates, refusing to pay for the same list of procedures, and requiring the use of lower-quality parts, are not enough, on their own, to constitute a violation of Section 1 of the Sherman Act. Evidence of conscious parallelism
In Twombly, the Supreme Court noted a number of "plus factors," identified by commentators (and the parties in that case) that could support a plausible inference of such a collusive agreement, including: "parallel behavior that would probably not result from chance, coincidence, independent responses to common stimuli, or mere interdependence unaided by an advance understanding among the parties;" conduct indicating "restricted freedom of action and sense of obligation that one generally associates with agreement;" or "complex and historically unprecedented changes in pricing structure made at the very same time by multiple competitors, and made for no other discernible reason." Twombly, 550 U.S. at 556 n. 4, 127 S.Ct. 1955 (internal citations omitted).
Thus, in addition to setting out the Defendants' uniform conduct, the Plaintiffs must provide enough factual matter, taken as true, to show that the Defendants took steps that would otherwise have been against their economic self-interest or that tends to show collusion.
Twombly, 550 U.S. at 557, 127 S.Ct. 1955.
The Plaintiffs contend that they have satisfied the requirement of pleading facts that show that a collusive agreement exists among the Defendants because they have alleged that, in addition to engaging in parallel behavior, the Defendants have taken actions that would have been against their economic self-interest in the absence of a conspiracy. Specifically, the Plaintiffs argue that
(Doc. 98 at 15).
This argument is simply not plausible. The "underpaying" which is seen by the Plaintiffs as ultimately harmful to the self-interest of the Defendants is simply the buyer-side version of the profit-maximizing behavior described approvingly by the Supreme Court in the Brooke Group case and by the Eleventh Circuit in Harcros Chemicals. (See note 3, supra.) If the oligopoly has market power — as alleged in this case — then it is consistent with that power for its members to observe price parity. The possible eventual loss of customers resulting from such a practice is nothing more than speculation. See Twombly, 550 U.S. at 567-68, 127 S.Ct. 1955 (rejecting argument that defendants' failure to compete in each other's geographic areas was suggestive of conspiracy to restrain trade where plaintiff had no support for allegation that such competition would have proven lucrative and reluctance to expand beyond existing areas could be explained by legitimate concerns). Compare Evergreen Partnering Group, Inc. v. Pactiv Corp., 720 F.3d 33 (1st Cir.2013) (finding that plaintiff successfully pled that defendants acted against their own interests in refusing to do business with plaintiff, where successful pilot programs showed that participation in plaintiff's recycling enterprise would have been cost-neutral to defendants and would have increased sales to defendants' customers).
The Plaintiffs also argue that the Second Amended Complaint contains numerous allegations that, taken as true, establish the existence of "plus factors" that support a plausible conclusion that the Defendants have entered into a collusive agreement. For brevity's sake, the Court quotes the Plaintiff's assertions as to each purported plus factor and then addresses each assertion:
(Doc. 98 at 12) (internal citations to Second Amended Complaint omitted).
The Plaintiffs offer no explanation as to how the possession of market power itself can constitute a "plus factor." The fact that a group of alleged price-fixers possess power in a particular market does not, standing alone, make it more likely that the members of that group have entered
(Doc. 98 at 12) (internal citations to Second Amended Complaint omitted).
The mere desire to make a profit cannot constitute a "plus factor," because conscious parallelism is itself a profit-maximizing behavior. See Jacobs v. Tempur-Pedic Int'l, Inc., 626 F.3d 1327, 1342 (11th Cir.2010) ("Jacobs had the burden to present allegations showing why it is more plausible that TPX and its distributors... would enter into an illegal price-fixing agreement ... to reach the same result realized by purely rational profit-maximizing behavior.").
In addition, because the motive behind most (if not all) price-fixing agreements is to increase profits among the participants, adopting "profit motive" as a plus factor would effectively eliminate any pleading requirements regarding such agreements. If the existence of a profit motive was enough to make it plausible that the defendants had colluded to fix prices, then essentially every alleged price-fixing agreement would survive a motion to dismiss.
The Plaintiffs' second argument on this point — involving "BlackRock, Inc." (henceforth, "BlackRock") — is difficult to follow. It appears that the Plaintiffs are arguing (1) that the Defendants are invested in BlackRock, (2) that BlackRock owns some businesses to which the Defendants steer their insureds and to which they provide discounted materials, and (3) that somehow this contributes to the Defendants earning record profits. This argument fails for numerous reasons. First, it is simply another version of the profit-motive-as-plus-factor argument, which fails for the reasons set forth above. Second, the details of the financial relationship between the Defendants and BlackRock — an asset management firm — are incomprehensible, especially in regard to how the Defendants might profit from that arrangement. The Plaintiffs allege that some (but not all) of the Defendants "are invested in or through BlackRock". (Doc. 87 at 78). It is not apparent how an entity that has invested through BlackRock would profit just because a BlackRock-owned property prospered. Finally, assuming arguendo that the Defendants have an ownership interest in BlackRock (and therefore would share in the profits of a BlackRock-owned business), it is not clear why this would give them an incentive to enter into an agreement to underpay for repairs performed by such businesses, which is the gist of Count I. The Plaintiffs do not allege that the Defendants pay more for repairs performed at BlackRock-owned businesses or permit the use of higher quality parts when repairs are performed there. Thus, any ill-gotten gains from the alleged price-fixing scheme would come at the expense of BlackRock and/or themselves.
It is not clear from the allegations of the Second Amended Complaint that all of the Defendants belong to any of the trade associations or beneficent organizations referred to in that document, much less that all of them belong to the same association or organization. Regardless, participation in trade associations and similar organizations provides no indication of a conspiracy. See American Dental Association v. Cigna Corp., 605 F.3d 1283, 1295 (11th Cir.2010).
(Doc. 98 at 12) (internal citations to Second Amended Complaint omitted).
The Plaintiffs' argument on this point asserts a uniformity of action among the Defendants that far outstrips the allegations included in the Second Amended Complaint. For example, the Plaintiffs argue in their response to the instant motions that the Defendants "all pay the same labor rates" and that they "raise the labor rate ceiling in uniformity and immediately following a change by State Farm." (Doc. 98 at 12). However, the Second Amended Complaint does not include any examples of such behavior. Instead, the Plaintiffs allege such things as
(SAC at 40) (emphasis added). As the italicized text shows, State Farm's price increase was matched weeks later by a few of the Defendants — not immediately by all of the Defendants, as the Plaintiffs assert here. Similarly, the Plaintiffs allege that
(SAC at 40). Again, the price change was not matched immediately by all Defendants; rather, it was matched over the course of months by some of the Defendants. The Court has not uncovered any instance in the Second Amended Complaint where the Plaintiffs have alleged that the other Defendants matched a State Farm price change uniformly or immediately.
The Plaintiffs' other allegations on this point also fall short of the claims made in their response to the instant motions. For example, the Plaintiffs cite to a portion of the Second Amended Complaint allegedly showing that the Defendants "refuse to pay for the same processes and procedures required to return a vehicle to pre-accident
(Doc. 98 at 12-13) (internal citations to Second Amended Complaint omitted).
Again, the cited allegations do not suggest collusion on the part of the Defendants. For example, if one assumes that State Farm's survey and the resulting "market rates" are entirely bogus, this would not suggest that the other Defendants entered into a conspiracy to pay no more than State Farm pays. The Plaintiffs also argue that the fact that the other Defendants know the prices paid by State Farm indicates collusion, because "the prices in question are considered secret." (Doc. 98 at 13). However, there are no allegations in the Second Amended Complaint that State Farm tries to keep those prices secret.
Finally, the Plaintiffs attempt to rely on their allegations that the Defendants, when refusing to pay for certain recommended procedures, uniformly utilize the same explanations. For example, the Plaintiffs have alleged in the Second Amended Complaint that the Defendants refuse to pay separately for a painting-related procedure known as "denib and finesse," claiming that it is included as part of the paint job, even though industry repair databases identify it as a separate procedure. (SAC at 48). But the Plaintiffs fail to offer any explanation as to how this indicates collusion on the part of the Defendants, and no such rationale is apparent to the Court. Even if one assumes that the Defendants have agreed to refuse to pay for certain procedures, it defies logic that they would also agree to use the same bogus excuses to justify their refusal.
In light of the foregoing, the Court finds that the Plaintiffs have again failed to state a claim for price-fixing in violation of Section 1 of the Sherman Act.
In Count II, the Plaintiffs assert that the Defendants have attempted to coerce auto repair shops into going along with their price-fixing scheme by
(SAC at 94).
The generic concept of "boycott" refers to a method of pressuring a party with whom one has a dispute by withholding, or enlisting others to withhold, patronage or services from the target. St. Paul Fire & Marine Ins. Co. v. Barry, 438 U.S. 531, 541, 98 S.Ct. 2923, 57 L.Ed.2d 932 (1978). The Defendants argue, inter alia, that the Plaintiffs' boycott claim must be dismissed because the Plaintiffs have again failed to allege conduct that would constitute a concerted refusal to deal — the same reason their previous boycott claim was dismissed. See, e.g., Doc. 90 at 16. At best, the Defendants argue, the Plaintiffs have included in the Second Amended Complaint some allegations of a particular insurer attempting to steer its insured from a shop operated by one of the Plaintiffs to a different shop that had a relationship with the insurer. (Doc. 90 at 17).
The Plaintiffs do not directly respond to these arguments. Rather, they argue that 1) the Defendants are not free to refuse to deal with the Plaintiffs, because the choice of repair facilities lies with the insured, not the insurer; 2) the insurers are not sellers, they are only payers; and 3) "refusal to deal" considerations only apply to monopoly claims under Section 2 of the Sherman Act, and the Plaintiffs have not asserted such a claim. (Doc. 98 at 17).
The Plaintiffs' first two points are unresponsive. As for the third, it is incorrect. In the antitrust context, group boycotts, or concerted refusals to deal, may run afoul of Section 1 of the Sherman Act. See, e.g., Times-Picayune Pub. Co. v. United States, 345 U.S. 594, 625, 73 S.Ct. 872, 97 L.Ed. 1277 (1953) and see F.T.C. v. Superior Court Trial Lawyers Ass'n, 493 U.S. 411, 422, 110 S.Ct. 768, 107 L.Ed.2d 851 (1990) (finding that boycott by criminal
The Court also notes that there are no allegations in the Second Amended Complaint that any Defendant (much less all of them) has ever refused to do business with any of the Plaintiffs. The Plaintiffs do include allegations that a number of Defendants, on different occasions, had attempted to steer one of their insureds away from one of the Plaintiff's shops to another shop that had some sort of relationship with the insurer. (SAC at 57-62). Only a few of these attempts are alleged to have succeeded. Id. None of them aid the Plaintiffs in stating a boycott claim, however, as none of the efforts are alleged to have involved more than a single Defendant, and there are no allegations that any of the attempted steering occurred because the repair shop originally chosen by the insured was attempting to obtain a higher reimbursement rate or anything of that nature.
The Plaintiffs have again failed to allege a concerted refusal to deal, as required to state a boycott claim under Section 1 of the Sherman Act.
This is the Plaintiffs' third attempt to state an antitrust claim. Based upon a review of the pleadings in this and the other 20-odd consolidated cases — the vast majority of which share the same short-comings — the Court finds that giving the Plaintiffs another opportunity to state a claim would be an exercise in futility. Accordingly, both antitrust claims will be dismissed with prejudice. In consideration of the foregoing, it is hereby
City of Tuscaloosa v. Harcros Chemicals, Inc., 158 F.3d 548, 570 (11th Cir.1998)