Paul W. Grimm, United States District Judge.
The litigation history between the Intellectual Ventures companies (Plaintiffs, Counter-Defendants, Third-Party Defendants, and Joined Counter-Defendants to this action; collectively referred to as "IV") and the Capital One companies (Defendants, Counterclaimants, and Third-Party Plaintiffs in this action; collectively referred to as "Capital One") is protracted, beginning with a patent infringement action that Intellectual Ventures I, LLC and Intellectual Ventures II, LLC (together, "IV I and II") filed in the Eastern District of Virginia on June 19, 2013. In that case, as well as in this patent infringement action that IV I and II filed on January 15, 2014, Capital One brought antitrust counterclaims. The Virginia court dismissed Capital One's antitrust claims for failure to state a claim, and IV now seeks summary judgment on very similar claims. ECF No. 656. Because Noerr-Pennington immunity and collateral estoppel both bar Capital One's antitrust claims, I will grant IV's motion.
IV I and II filed suit in this Court, alleging that Capital One infringed five of their patents. Compl., ECF No. 1. IV I and II ultimately voluntarily withdrew one patent infringement claim and proceeded with the others. ECF Nos. 80, 81. The parties engaged in extensive discovery and agreed to referral to a Special Master highly experienced in patent law, jointly selected by the parties and appointed pursuant to Fed. R. Civ. P. 53. ECF Nos. 134, 136, 143. He oversaw additional discovery, following which the parties extensively briefed the patent infringement claims. ECF Nos. 147, 147-1, 169, 169-1, 227, 246, 297, 300, 303. The Special Master issued two reports and recommendations, ECF
After reviewing the Special Master's reports and recommendations and the parties' extensive briefs, I overruled the Special Master with respect to the '081 Patent and the '002 Patent, finding that they were unenforceable. ECF Nos. 377, 378. I also ruled that collateral estoppel applied regarding the '409 Patent and the '084 Patent, barring IV from bringing claims against Capital One for infringement of those patents. ECF No. 382. The net effect of my ruling was that each of the patents that IV claimed Capital One had infringed was unenforceable, two patents because I concluded that they were invalid pursuant to 35 U.S.C. § 101, and two patents because the United States District Court for the Southern District of New York in Intellectual Ventures v. JPMC, Case No. 13-3777-AKH, 2015 WL 1941331 (S.D.N.Y. Apr. 28, 2015), concluded that they were invalid, and issue preclusion barred me from reaching a different conclusion. On those grounds, I entered summary judgment in Capital One's favor on those four remaining patent infringement claims. ECF Nos. 378, 382. And, finding no just reason for delay, I entered a final judgment in favor of Capital One on the patent infringement claims, making that order immediately appealable. ECF No. 387. The Federal Circuit affirmed my rulings, Intellectual Ventures I LLC v. Capital One Fin. Corp., 850 F.3d 1332 (Fed. Cir. 2017), thereby ending the patent infringement claims against Capital One.
Meanwhile, Capital One had sought leave to file three antitrust counterclaims, claiming monopolization and attempted monopolization, in violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 2, and unlawful asset acquisition, in violation of Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. § 18, as part of its Third Amended Answer, Defenses, and Counterclaims. ECF No. 106. IV I and II opposed the motion. ECF No. 118. I granted Capital One leave to file its counterclaims, ECF Nos. 194, 195, which it did, ECF No. 196; see also Fourth Amended Answer, Defenses, and Counterclaims, ECF Nos. 438 (redacted), 439 (sealed). It also filed a Third Party Complaint against additional Intellectual Ventures companies: Invention Investment Fund II, LLC; Intellectual Ventures Management, LLC; Invention Investment Fund I, L.P. ECF Nos. 228 (sealed), 230 (redacted). Capital One alleges that IV has tried, without success, to license to Capital One its extensive patent portfolio, which includes the patents that IV has sued Capital One, in this suit and the Virginia suit, for infringing. Capital One believes that IV's repeated claims against it are actionable under antitrust law.
I denied IV's motions to dismiss the counterclaims and Third Party Complaint, ECF Nos. 225, 296, finding that Capital One had pled them sufficiently to proceed to discovery. ECF No. 328. After another round of extensive (and expensive) discovery regarding liability on the antitrust counterclaims, I attended a tutorial involving the economic experts that the parties had identified. ECF No. 651. Also in attendance was the court technical advisor, Professor John M. de Figueiredo of Duke University Law and Business Schools, whose appointment the parties had confirmed on a status conference call, and who assisted the court in evaluating the economic
The essence of Capital One's antitrust claim is that IV is a "patent troll,"
Capital One characterizes IV's business model as comprised of three components: accumulate a vast portfolio of patents purportedly relating to essential commercial banking services, conceal the details of those patents so that the banks cannot determine whether their products infringe any of IV's patents, and serially litigate to force the banks to capitulate and license the portfolio at exorbitant cost. This conduct, Capital One insists, constitutes monopolization under § 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 2, attempted monopolization under § 2 of the Sherman Act, and unlawful asset acquisition under § 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. § 18.
Nonsense, IV indignantly responds. It counters Capital One's charges by arguing that it legitimately purchased or otherwise acquired its large portfolio of patents that relate to multiple technology markets. It then offers to license its portfolio to banks (and other types of businesses), beginning its negotiation with an opening offer, and expecting the bank to counteroffer, thereby initiating a back-and-forth exchange that it hopes will result in a mutuallyagreeable licensing fee. IV vehemently denies that it conceals the details of its individual patents or that Capital One could not determine what they relate to by reviewing publicly available information. As IV sees things, when Capital One declined to make a counter offer to its opening bid, it then selected a number of its patents and brought suit against Capital One, first in the Eastern District of Virginia, and then, when that suit was unsuccessful, in this Court, with respect to a different set of patents. Moreover, IV claims that Capital One is, in essence, an "efficient infringer" — an entity that engages in its business without care for whether it infringes on patents held by others, with the knowledge that a patent infringement case is expensive to bring, and many patent holders lack the funds to do so to protect their rights. As such, Capital One can play the odds, infringing patents with near impunity until the rare patent holder with the resources to sue does so, and then negotiate a favorable license fee.
IV points out that each of its patents is presumptively valid, and that it has an absolute right to file litigation to enforce them. And, in IV's view, if enforcing its patents through litigation has any monopoly effect (which IV denies it does), it has immunity under the Noerr-Pennington doctrine.
IV also asserts that Capital One's antitrust theory is fundamentally flawed, because no liability can attach unless Capital One can prove that IV exercises monopoly power within a relevant market. "Monopoly power is the power to control prices or exclude competition." United States v. E. I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S. 377, 391, 76 S.Ct. 994, 100 S.Ct. 1264 (1956); see Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Tech. Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451, 481, 112 S.Ct. 2072, 119 L.Ed.2d 265 (1992) (quoting E.I. du Pont); United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 571, 86 S.Ct. 1698, 16 L.Ed.2d 778 (1966) (same). IV insists that it does neither, because the correct market definition would recognize that what IV owns is a series of patents that relate to multiple, distinct technology markets. And IV could exercise monopoly power only if Capital One can show that its patents include those affecting alternative substitute technologies that Capital One otherwise could turn to in order to avoid having to license IV's patents. Capital One has not made this showing, IV contends, entitling it to summary judgment.
Underlying the legal issues in this case are two important but competing policies. On one hand, we value innovation that leads to new inventions that advance science and technology, protecting that creative effort by issuing patents. A patent, by its very nature, vests its owner with a type of legal monopoly, which it can enforce against anyone who infringes the patent. Enforcing a patent through litigation protects this monopoly, even though in other circumstances we view monopolies as harmful.
The other important policy implicated by this case, of course, is the strong desire to ensure vigorous competition in the marketplace, so that consumers (whether businesses or individuals) can purchase at the lowest possible price. To promote the benefits of robust competition, antitrust law aims to prevent a company from having the ability to control the price of its product or exclude competitors to the extent that it can charge sustained supracompetitive prices (prices substantially above what a competitive price would be if consumers could simply buy a close substitute product from a competitor at lower cost).
The exercise of monopoly power with regard to a single patent (or even a few patents) usually does not offend antitrust law. But it is another matter to acquire a vast portfolio of patents that are essential to technology employed by an entire industry and then to compel its licensing at take-it-or-leave-it prices because it is not economically feasible to determine if alternative technologies, not covered by the accumulation of patents, are available. This acquisition and compelled licensing could amount to the ability to exercise monopoly power on an entirely different scale.
In a very real sense, antitrust law is founded on economic theory about how efficient markets should operate. In an ideally competitive market where there are no barriers to entry or exit by competing businesses, the availability of the same product (or a close substitute) from many sources will tend to drive the price downwards to a point slightly above the cost to make the product — the so-called "competitive price." Think of pizzerias. There are lots of them, and entry and exit from this business is relatively free and unrestricted. If one restaurant decides to charge too much for a slice of pizza, there are many others nearby where the consumer can buy at a lower cost. The ready supply of close substitutes keeps costs competitive — slightly above the cost of making the pizza.
Each of the above important competing policies is at play in this case. Capital One argues, through its highly credentialed and impressive economic expert, Professor Fiona Scott Morton of Yale University, that IV possesses monopoly power in connection with its large financial services patent portfolio, which touches on essential technologies that commercial banks have heavily invested in and cannot realistically design around to avoid the reach of IV's patents. Because of the size of this portfolio (between 7,725 and 35,000 patents, depending on whether Capital One or IV's expert is correct),
As Professor Scott Morton sees it, antitrust analysis commonly used to determine whether a proposed merger will result in anticompetitive effects, simply does not work for the facts of this case. That is because merger analysis is ex ante, focusing on whether, if the merger is approved, the new entity will be able to charge a small but significant non-transitory increase in price (referred to as "SSNIP")
Scott Morton analogizes IV's financial services patent portfolio to a "cluster market" that IV promotes as a single product (for which there are no close substitutes) at a supracompetitive price. And she asserts that IV exercises monopoly power, despite the fact that no bank (including Capital One) has agreed to purchase a license to the entire portfolio, and IV has yet to prevail in any of its patent suits against banks.
Pure humbug, counters IV, through its equally well-credentialed and impressive economic expert, Professor Richard Gilbert from the University of California, Berkley. He challenges Professor Scott Morton's market definition, arguing that the proper definition is not a "cluster" of financial services patents constituting a single product, but rather a collection of patents that relate to multiple distinct technology markets. Professor Gilbert relies on the Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property issued jointly by the U.S. Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission ("Guidelines"). See U.S. Dep't of Justice & Fed. Trade Comm'n, Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property (Jan. 12, 2017), available at https://www.justice.gov/atr/guidelines-and-policy-statements-0/2017-update-antitrust-guidelines-licensing-intellectual-property. The Guidelines state, relevantly, that "[a]lthough the intellectual property right confers the power to exclude with respect to the specific product, process, or work in question, there will often be sufficient actual or potential close substitutes for such product, process, or work to prevent the exercise of market power." Id. § 2.2, at 4. The flaw in Capital One's antitrust analysis, according to Professor Gilbert, is its failure to analyze the distinct technology markets for which IV does have patents to determine whether there are alternative close substitutes that Capital One could turn to in order to avoid having to license from IV.
As Professor Gilbert sees it, IV's patents touch on a large number of distinct technology markets, each of which must be analyzed using SSNIP analysis, which Professor Scott Morton failed to do. Thus, he strongly disagrees that IV's patent portfolio can be analyzed as a cluster market at all. And, even more fundamentally, he challenges Professor Scott Morton's conclusions, arguing that proper market definition and analysis requires looking at actual prices (competitive price, market price and monopoly price). Here, he insists, there are no prices at all because IV's licensing offer was only an opening bid in a negotiation, not a take-it-or-leave-it supracompetitive monopoly ultimatum. The negotiation did not progress to a point where a final demand was reached because Capital One refused to engage by making a
As IV and Capital One agree, the essential first step in analyzing the antitrust claims in this case is to define the relevant market by product(s) and geography. See United States v. Marine Bancorporation, Inc., 418 U.S. 602, 618, 94 S.Ct. 2856, 41 L.Ed.2d 978 (1974); Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. 294, 324, 82 S.Ct. 1502, 8 L.Ed.2d 510 (1962); Buccaneer Energy (USA) Inc. v. Gunnison Energy Corp., 846 F.3d 1297, 1319-20 (10th Cir. 2017). "[M]arket definition is a deeply fact-intensive inquiry...." E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co. v. Kolon Indus. Inc., 637 F.3d 435, 443 (4th Cir. 2011) (quoting Todd v. Exxon Corp., 275 F.3d 191, 199 (2d Cir. 2001)). In determining the relevant market, the Court must consider "the `commercial realities' faced by consumers." Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Tech. Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451, 482, 112 S.Ct. 2072, 119 L.Ed.2d 265 (1992). Where the facts are hotly disputed, as here, defining relevant market is "generally a question for the trier of fact." ABA Section of Antitrust Law, Antitrust Law Developments 627-30 (ABA 8th ed. 2017), Ex. 127, Jt. Rec. 9557; see also Fineman v. Armstrong World Indus., Inc., 980 F.2d 171, 199 (3d Cir. 1992) ("[T]he determination of a relevant product market or submarket ... is a highly factual one best allocated to the trier of fact."). The burden of proof lies with the antitrust plaintiff to prove relevant market. Spectrum Sports, Inc. v. McQuillan 506 U.S. 447, 455-56, 113 S.Ct. 884, 122 L.Ed.2d 247 (1993); Berlyn Inc. v. The Gazette Newspapers, Inc., 73 Fed.Appx. 576, 582 (4th Cir. 2003); Satellite Television & Associated Res., Inc. v. Cont'l Cablevision of Va., Inc., 714 F.2d 351, 355 (4th Cir. 1983). When the parties proffer competing economic experts on the proper definition of relevant market, summary judgment is inappropriate as long as each expert's views could be found by the trier of fact to be reasonable. Spirit Airlines, Inc. v. Nw. Airlines, Inc., 431 F.3d 917, 945 (6th Cir. 2005) ("`[I]ntellectual disagreement' among the parties' experts creates material factual disputes on the relevant market ... so as to preclude an award of summary judgment." (quoting record)); Thompson v. Metro. Multi-List, Inc., 934 F.2d 1566, 1573-74 (11th Cir. 1991) ("The parameters of a given market are questions of fact, and therefore summary judgment is inappropriate if there are material differences of fact." (internal citations omitted)).
IV does not dispute this authority, but contends that it is entitled to summary judgment despite the substantial disagreement between Professor Scott Morton and Professor Gilbert on the definition of relevant market (as well as other antitrust elements) because the methodology used by Professor Scott Morton is so far removed from commonly employed antitrust analysis that it must be rejected as unreasonable as a matter of law. It is true that Professor Gilbert's analysis of relevant market is firmly grounded in commonly used antitrust analysis, as evidenced by its reliance on the Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission's Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property. But, in support of their alternative analysis, Capital One and Professor Scott Morton have cited authority for the application of cluster market analysis to the definition of a relevant antitrust market. See United States v. Phila. Nat'l Bank, 374 U.S. 321, 355-56, 83 S.Ct. 1715, 10 L.Ed.2d 915 (1963) (citing Brown Shoe); United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 572-73, 86 S.Ct. 1698, 16 L.Ed.2d 778 (1966) (citing Brown Shoe); Brown Shoe, 370 U.S. at 324-25, 82 S.Ct. 1502; and Fed. Trade Comm'n v. Staples,
With respect to cluster markets, Professor Ayres, one of the early scholars to study such markets in antitrust law, was critical of the courts' failure to articulate "a sound justifying theory" of when cluster analysis is appropriate, opting instead for a series of "ad hoc" standards. He noted:
Ayres, supra, at 112-14. He advocated using a standard he called "transactional complementarity," meaning:
Id. at 114-15.
Applying Ayres's standard for using cluster markets to define a relevant antitrust market in this case would be problematic for Capital One, because Professor Scott Morton's analysis rests on the notion that Capital One (and other banks to which IV has pitched its portfolio) does not want the cluster of products that IV offers. In such circumstances, it would be difficult to argue that consumers (banks) "strongly prefer to purchase a group of goods" (IV's patent portfolio) from a single firm (IV). Nevertheless, the parties do not cite, nor have I located, any controlling legal authority that Professor Ayres's test for the use of cluster markets must be used instead of any others that courts that have employed cluster market analysis in antitrust cases have used. While factfinders ultimately might reject Scott Morton's reliance on cluster markets to justify her antitrust market analysis, I cannot conclude that as a matter of law it is unreasonable.
But, neither is Professor Gilbert's analysis immune from criticism. His contention that it would be economically feasible for Capital One to discern the particulars of each of IV's thousands of patents to determine whether there are close substitutes to which Capital One could turn in order to avoid IV's portfolio, even if all of the information needed to do so was readily available, stretches plausibility to the near breaking point.
Id. at 3.
The sheer scope of IV's patent holdings calls into question how it would be feasible to perform the analysis of available substitutes that Professor Gilbert calls for to determine whether there are close substitutes to which Capital One could turn to avoid the reach of IV's portfolio. And while the Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property do apply the SSNIP analysis favored by Professor Gilbert, there is nothing in the Guidelines that seems to recognize the near impossibility of doing so with a collection of intellectual property as massive as IV's (despite the fact that it was revised and reissued on January 12, 2017).
After all, the phenomenon of applying antitrust doctrine to intellectual property rights on the scale presented by IV's holdings is a new challenge. As noted by Feldman and Ewing:
Id. at 1.
And even if cluster market analysis ultimately is not considered the appropriate framework for analyzing the relevant antitrust market in cases such as this one (despite the fact that Capital One has cited abundant facts that a jury reasonably could conclude supports its contention that IV does, in fact, market its patents as a portfolio, rather than a collection of individual patents relating to a number of discrete technology markets), it is hard to deny that there is something concerning from an antitrust perspective about the way in which IV engages in its licensing business. See, e.g., Michelle Miller & Janusz Ordover, Intellectual Ventures v. Capital One: Can Antitrust Law and Economics Get Us Past the Trolls?, Competition Policy Int'l: Antitrust Chronicle (Jan. 19, 2015), available at https://www.competition policyinternational.com/intellectual-ventures-v-capital-one-can-antitrust-law-and-economics-get-us-past-the-trolls ("[M]any PAEs [Patent Assertion Entities] exploit the lack of transparency in patent ownership to amass huge portfolios of `secret' patents that are then asserted against manufacturers. Manufacturers faced with a royalty demand based on a large number of unidentified patents cannot determine an appropriate royalty, or even whether any royalty is owed at all. That uncertainty may lead to manufactures paying supracompetitive royalties that can depress product innovation.").
If the only issue raised in IV's summary judgment motion was whether there are genuine disputes of material fact that would entitle it to judgment as a matter of law on the issues of possession of monopoly power in a relevant market and the willful acquisition or maintenance of that power as distinguished from growth or development as a consequence of a superior product, business acumen, or historic accident, see Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S. at 481, 112 S.Ct. 2072, I would deny the motion and allow the case to proceed to trial. This is because I have concluded from the record before me that Capital One has identified admissible evidence to establish a genuine dispute as to these issues, precluding summary judgment. But as next will be seen, there are further legal issues which, when resolved, require the granting of IV's motion.
Summary judgment is proper when the moving party demonstrates, through "particular parts of materials in the record, including depositions, documents, electronically stored information, affidavits or declarations, stipulations ..., admissions, interrogatory answers, or other materials," that "there is no genuine dispute as to any
Antitrust law proscribes the willful acquisition or maintenance of monopoly power within a market, as well as attempts to monopolize. See 15 U.S.C. § 2; Spectrum Sports, Inc. v. McQuillan, 506 U.S. 447, 456, 113 S.Ct. 884, 122 L.Ed.2d 247 (1993); United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 570-571, 86 S.Ct. 1698, 16 L.Ed.2d 778 (1966). In contrast, a patent creates a legal monopoly. Fed. Trade Comm'n v. Actavis, Inc., 570 U.S. 136, 133 S.Ct. 2223, 2231, 186 L.Ed.2d 343 (2013). Additionally, "[t]hose who petition government for redress are generally immune from antitrust liability" under what is known as Noerr-Pennington immunity. Prof'l Real Estate Inv'rs, Inc. v. Columbia Pictures Indus., Inc. ("PREI"), 508 U.S. 49, 56, 113 S.Ct. 1920, 123 L.Ed.2d 611 (1993) (citing E. R.R. Presidents Conf. v. Noerr Motor Freight, Inc., 365 U.S. 127, 81 S.Ct. 523, 5 L.Ed.2d 464 (1961); United Mine Workers of Am. v. Pennington, 381 U.S. 657, 85 S.Ct. 1585, 14 L.Ed.2d 626 (1965)). This holds true for parties who file suit in court. See id. at 57, 113 S.Ct. 1920 (noting that California Motor Transport Co. v. Trucking Unlimited ("California Motor"), 404 U.S. 508, 510, 92 S.Ct. 609, 30 L.Ed.2d 642 (1972), "extended Noerr to `the approach of citizens ... to courts'"). And, patent holders that believe that their patents have been infringed may seek to enforce their rights under the patent through patent litigation. 35 U.S.C. § 281 ("A patentee shall have remedy by civil action for infringement of his patent."). Thus, when a party challenges a patent holder's efforts to enforce its patents through litigation, the court must determine whether the patent holder is exercising "the lawful restraint on trade of the patent monopoly" or "the illegal restraint prohibited broadly by the Sherman Act." United States v. Line Material Co., 333 U.S. 287, 310, 68 S.Ct. 550, 92 S.Ct. 701 (1948). To do so, courts must "balance the privileges of [a patent holder] under [its] patent grants with the prohibitions of the Sherman Act against combinations and attempts to monopolize." United States v. U.S. Gypsum Co., 333 U.S. 364, 390-91, 68 S.Ct. 525, 92 S.Ct. 746 (1948).
IV contends that "[u]nder the First Amendment and the Noerr-Pennington doctrine, Intellectual Ventures I and Intellectual Ventures II, like other patent owners, ... are entitled to petition a court for a redress of their grievances," that is, IV may sue corporations like Capital One for patent infringement without being sued under the antitrust laws for bringing suit. IV Mem. 12. On that basis, it argues that, for Capital One to proceed on its antitrust claims against IV based on IV's patent litigation activities, Capital One must establish that an exception to Noerr-Pennington exists such that IV was not entitled to exercise its right to sue. Id. According to IV, Capital One has failed to prove that IV's claims were "objectively baseless," as it had to do to
Capital One counters that Noerr-Pennington immunity simply does not apply because the "litigation conduct is part of a broader monopolistic scheme," and "Noerr does not insulate the entire scheme." Capital One Opp'n 19; see also id. at 21 ("IV's lawsuits against Capital One (and other banks) are part of its overall, multi-step scheme to force a portfolio license at a supracompetitive price."). Insofar as Capital One argues that "IV's aggregation of patents to create market power would support substantial Section 2 and Section 7 claims on its own," and that "the concealment and misdirection at the heart of IV's extortive licensing strategy would be anticompetitive even if IV had never filed a lawsuit," id., this contention is contrary to Capital One's pleadings. Capital One alleges that "IV has eliminated banks' access to substitutes for IV's license, both in the form of other patent licenses and banking-product designs, through a carefully orchestrated campaign of patent aggregation, concealment, and sham litigation," Fourth Am. Countercl. (Redacted) ¶ 157, and that "IV's use of patent accumulations to cut off banks' design and license choices, as weapons in negotiation, and to provide fuel for repeated sham litigation, violates Section 2 of the Sherman Act," id. ¶ 125. See also id. ¶ 171 ("IV's actions in secretly aggregating 3,500 financial-services patents through shell companies, subjecting Capital One to sham litigation, demanding nine-figure sums for a limited and temporary patent respite, and refusing to disclose many of the patents that IV demanded Capital One pay more than $100 million for are all part of a carefully orchestrated plan to achieve monopoly power in the relevant technology-licensing market and wield it against the banking industry."); id. ¶ 177 ("Even though the patents in its portfolio are individually of little or no worth, IV can and does acquire monopoly power by amassing them as a source of serial sham litigation threats."); Third Party Compl. (Redacted) ¶¶ 17, 49, 63, 69 (same).
And, while patent acquisition and aggregation is the focus of the Clayton Act claim, acquisition is actionable under the Clayton Act only where "the effect of such acquisition may be substantially to lessen competition, or to tend to create a monopoly." 15 U.S.C. § 18. To establish this effect, Capital One relies on IV's purported "campaign," which could not succeed absent the allegedly sham litigation. See Third Am. Countercl. (Sealed) ¶ 218 ("IV combines [its patent acquisitions] in a way that `gives [IV] market power,' because, now that IV has eliminated alternative licensing sources by acquiring the patents, banks `can not avoid' paying a hold-up demand (which IV styles as a `license') if they want to avoid repeated meritless litigation and uncertainty."); see also Third Party Compl. (Sealed) ¶ 110 (same). Clearly, the allegation of sham litigation is an integral component of IV's alleged strategy underlying all of Capital One's claims. See Third Am. Countercl. ¶¶ 125, 157, 171, 177, 218; Third Party Compl. ¶¶ 17, 49, 63, 69, 110.
Moreover, even if the sham litigation allegations could be excised from its pleadings, Capital One does not cite any controlling authority in support of its position that Noerr-Pennington immunity does not apply because sham litigation is only one component of a larger scheme, and I am not persuaded by the authority it cites from other circuits. Capital One includes a quote from California Motor as indirect support for its argument: "First Amendment rights are not immunized from regulation when they are used as an integral
Capital One also cites Fed. Trade Comm'n v. Actavis, Inc., 570 U.S. 136, 133 S.Ct. 2223, 186 L.Ed.2d 343 (2013), as stating that "anticompetitive effects [that] fall within the scope of the exclusionary potential of the patent" do not "immunize [conduct] from antitrust attack." Capital One Opp'n 19 (quoting Actavis, 133 S.Ct. at 2230). But, a holding that, when the validity and preclusive scope of a patent are in question, the patent holder can be sued under antitrust laws for activities that may be permissible under the patent (such as charging supra-competitive prices) does not mean that a patent holder can be sued under antitrust laws for filing suit to enforce the patent, and Capital One has not identified any binding authority extending the Supreme Court holding in this manner.
Alternatively, Capital One argues that IV is not immune to suit under Noerr-Pennington because a party loses its immunity if it brings a series of "petitions... `pursuant to a policy of starting legal proceedings without regard to the merits' and for the purpose of injuring competition," which is what, in Capital One's view, IV did when it "brought its ten patent claims against Capital One without regard to the merits and for the purpose of restraining trade." Capital One Opp'n 22-25 (quoting USS-POSCO Indus. v. Contra Costa Cty. Bldg. & Constr. Trades Council, AFL-CIO, 31 F.3d 800, 811 (9th Cir. 1994)).
Nobelpharma AB v. Implant Innovations, Inc., 141 F.3d 1059, 1068 (Fed. Cir. 1998) (quoting Noerr, 365 U.S. at 144, 81 S.Ct. 523);
Walker Process held narrowly that "the enforcement of a patent procured by fraud on the Patent Office may be violative of § 2 of the Sherman Act provided the other elements necessary to a § 2 case are present." 382 U.S. at 174, 86 S.Ct. 347. Thus, "`to strip [a patentee] of its exemption from the antitrust laws' because of its attempting to enforce its patent monopoly, an antitrust plaintiff is first required to prove that the patentee `obtained the patent by knowingly and willfully misrepresenting facts to the [Patent and Trademark Office]'" and that the patent holder seeking to enforce its patent through litigation was "aware of the fraud when bringing suit." Nobelpharma, 141 F.3d at 1068-69 (citing Walker, 382 U.S. at 177 & n.6, 86 S.Ct. 347) (footnote omitted). For Walker Process purposes, "fraud is a more serious offense than inequitable conduct." Id. at 1070. Where, as here, there is no evidence that the Patent Office was tricked by fraud or that IV (which later acquired the patents) was aware of any such fraud, Walker Process's holding has no application.
Because Walker Process is inapplicable, to determine whether IV is immune from antitrust liability stemming from its patent litigation, I must determine whether the "sham litigation exception to Noerr-Pennington immunity" applies. See Tyco Healthcare Grp. LP v. Mut. Pharm. Co., 762 F.3d 1338, 1343 (Fed. Cir. 2014). The Supreme Court first observed that "[t]here may be situations in which a publicity campaign, ostensibly directed toward influencing governmental action, is a mere sham to cover up what is actually nothing more than an attempt to interfere directly with the business relationships of a competitor and the application of the Sherman Act would be justified" in Noerr, 365 U.S. at 144, 81 S.Ct. 523. The sham litigation exception has been extended to patent litigation, in which a patentee's "conduct in the prosecution of a patent" may be "sufficient to strip [the] patentee of its immunity from the antitrust laws." Nobelpharma, 141 F.3d at 1067. But this exception to Noerr-Pennington immunity is narrow, "[g]iven the presumption of patent validity and the burden on the patent challenger to prove invalidity by clear and convincing evidence." Tyco Healthcare, 762 F.3d at 1343. Consequently, rarely will "a patentee's assertion of its patent in the face of a claim of invalidity ... be so unreasonable as to support a claim that the patentee has engaged in sham litigation." Id.
As for what qualifies as sham litigation, PREI, 508 U.S. 49, 113 S.Ct. 1920, 123 L.Ed.2d 611, and California Motor, 404 U.S. 508, 92 S.Ct. 609, 30 L.Ed.2d 642, provide guidance. In California Motor, a group of trucking companies brought antitrust claims against another group of trucking companies, alleging that the defendants "conspired to monopolize trade and commerce in the transportation of goods" through "a concerted action ... to institute state and federal proceedings [including rehearings, reviews, and appeals from agency and court orders] to resist and defeat applications by [the plaintiffs] to acquire operating rights or to transfer or register those rights." 404 U.S. at 509,
In PREI, the operators of a resort hotel ("PRE") "sought to develop a market for the sale of videodisc players to other hotels wishing to offer in-room viewing of prerecorded material." Columbia Picture Industries, Inc. ("Columbia") "held copyrights to the motion pictures recorded on the videodiscs that PRE purchased" and, like PRE, "licensed the transmission of copyrighted motion pictures to hotel rooms." 508 U.S. at 51-52, 113 S.Ct. 1920. Columbia sued PRE for copyright infringement, and PRE counterclaimed in antitrust, claiming that "Columbia's copyright action was a mere sham that cloaked underlying acts of monopolization and conspiracy to restrain trade." Id. at 52, 113 S.Ct. 1920. Notably, Columbia only initiated one suit against PRE, id., unlike the "pattern of baseless, repetitive claims" that defeated the antitrust defendants' immunity claim in California Motor, 404 U.S. at 513, 92 S.Ct. 609. It is also significant that in PREI, the district court case was in the same posture as this case, with a summary judgment motion pending, and the court decided the case on summary judgment. PREI, 508 U.S. at 53, 113 S.Ct. 1920.
The PREI Court held that, to qualify as "sham litigation," a lawsuit "must be objectively baseless in the sense that no reasonable litigant could realistically expect success on the merits," and "the litigant's subjective motivation" must be "to interfere directly with the business relationships of a competitor." PREI, 508 U.S. at 60-61, 113 S.Ct. 1920; see Tyco Healthcare, 762 F.3d at 1343 (noting that a lawsuit qualifies as "sham litigation" under the PREI test when it "(1) is `objectively baseless in the sense that no reasonable litigant could realistically expect success on the merits' (the objective element), and (2) is motivated by a desire `to interfere directly with the business relationships of a competitor' (the subjective element)" (quoting PREI, 508 U.S. at 60-61, 113 S.Ct. 1920)). Because "the antitrust defendant admittedly had probable cause to institute [its copyright suit]," the Court concluded that its suit against PREI was not objectively baseless and therefore could not qualify as sham litigation to defeat Noerr-Pennington immunity. PREI, 508 U.S. at 51, 113 S.Ct. 1920. Thus, although both factors must be present to establish that litigation is a sham, a finding of "an objectively reasonable effort to litigate" is sufficient to show that the litigation was not a sham, "regardless of subjective intent." Id. at 51, 113 S.Ct. 1920. Simply put, if the court concludes that the antitrust defendant had probable cause to file suit (which it can determine as a matter of law if, as here, "there is no dispute over the predicate facts of the underlying legal proceeding"), it cannot find that the defendant engaged in sham litigation, even if the
The PREI Court analogized to the common law tort of wrongful civil proceedings (often erroneously referred to as malicious prosecution, a tort that involves wrongful criminal proceedings) to define probable cause for purposes of determining whether litigation is objectively baseless. Id. at 62, 113 S.Ct. 1920.
Id. at 62-63, 113 S.Ct. 1920 (some internal citations omitted).
In his concurrence, Justice Stevens "agreed with the Court's disposition of [PREI] and with its holding that `an objectively reasonable effort to litigate cannot be sham regardless of subjective intent,'" but he wrote separately because he believed that the majority's opinion included "unnecessarily broad dicta" that the Court "might regret when confronted with a more complicated case." Id. at 67-68, 113 S.Ct. 1920. Justice Stevens distinguished cases like PREI in which a single lawsuit is alleged to be a sham, from cases like California Motor that involved "repetitive filings." Id. at 67-73, 113 S.Ct. 1920. He noted that "[t]here might well be lawsuits" in which "`reasonable litigant[s] could realistically expect success on the merits,'" but the litigation could "be objectively unreasonable" nonetheless, "and thus shams." Id. at 68, 113 S.Ct. 1920. Justice Stevens observed that "more complicated cases [previously before the Supreme Court], in which, for example, the alleged competitive injury has involved something more than the threat of an adverse outcome in a single lawsuit, have produced less definite rules." Id. at 72-73, 113 S.Ct. 1920. Citing California Motor, he stated that "[r]epetitive filings, some of which are successful and some unsuccessful, may support an inference that the process is being misused." Id. at 73, 113 S.Ct. 1920. Moreover, he said, "[i]n such a case, a rule that a single meritorious action can never constitute a sham cannot be dispositive," and "a simple rule may be hard to apply when there is evidence that the judicial process has been used as part of a larger program to control a market and to interfere
Similarly, in Waugh Chapel S., LLC v. United Food & Commercial Workers Union Local 27, the Fourth Circuit, considering a series of proceedings in the labor context, observed that "[i]t is unclear whether PREI [and its two-step standard] distinguished or displaced the sham litigation test first propounded in California Motor" for analyzing the proceedings on the record before it. 728 F.3d 354, 363 (4th Cir. 2013). The Fourth Circuit noted that, under the California Motor standard, "the focus is not on any single case. Rather a district court should conduct a holistic evaluation of whether `the administrative and judicial processes have been abused.'" Id. (quoting Cal. Motor, 404 U.S. at 513, 92 S.Ct. 609). It is "[t]he pattern of the legal proceedings, not their individual merits," that the court considers to determine "whether the [antitrust defendant] indiscriminately filed ... a series of legal proceedings without regard for the merits and for the purpose of violating federal law." Id. As with the PREI standard, "the subjective motive of the litigant and the objective merits of the suits are relevant," but the California Motor standard is different because "other signs of bad-faith litigation... may also be probative of an abuse of the adjudicatory process." Id.
The Fourth Circuit adopted the Second and Ninth Circuits' approach
The parties disagree about which standard I should apply in this case. IV insists that Federal Circuit law governs, and therefore I should apply the PREI standard. See IV Mem. 13. Indeed, "an antitrust claim premised on stripping a patentee of its immunity from the antitrust laws
Nonetheless, Capital One argues that Federal Circuit law does not apply in this instance because it is not necessary to resolve any issues under patent law to determine antitrust liability, and this Court should, under Fourth Circuit law, apply the California Motor standard instead because the facts of this case involve what Capital One characterizes as a series of legal proceedings. Capital One Opp'n 23 n.7. In its view, "Capital One's claims are based on IV's overall scheme, not solely on IV's `conduct in ... enforcing a patent." Id. Capital One contends in the alternative that, even under Federal Circuit law, California Motor, not PREI, "is still the correct standard because the Federal Circuit has not reached the question of whether [California Motor] applies to a series of petitions," as Capital One asserts is present in this case, and "every circuit that has addressed the issue [including the Fourth Circuit] holds that the [California Motor] standard, not PREI, applies where, as here, more than one lawsuit (or petition) is at issue." Id. at 23.
Federal Circuit law, under which PREI provides the standard for deciding whether Noerr-Pennington immunity exists or whether the sham-litigation exception is present, clearly applies in this case. Capital One's antitrust claims are counterclaims brought in the patent litigation that IV initiated. These are the circumstances that Nobelpharma describes.
In any event, even if Fourth Circuit law applied or the Federal Circuit applied the California Motor standard to cases involving a series of claims, the result would not change: PREI still would provide the standard. The facts before me are easily distinguished from the facts of California Motor, Waugh Chapel, and the cases on which the Fourth Circuit relied, POSCO, 31 F.3d 800, and Primetime 24 Joint Vent., 219 F.3d 92. In California Motor, 404 U.S. at 509, 513, 92 S.Ct. 609, there was a "pattern of baseless and repetitive claims" made in a number of administrative and court proceedings. In Primetime 24 Joint Venture, 219 F.3d at 101, there were "voluminous challenges," and in POSCO, 31 F.3d at 804, there were "numerous grievances, arbitrations and enforcement proceedings." Waugh Chapel, 728 F.3d 354, involved fourteen separate proceedings — a barrage of proceedings that was clearly a series. Here, there have been only two cases that IV has brought against Capital One. While it is true that IV has sued various other entities in other courts, that litigation does not make its two instances of litigation against Capital One a series.
Moreover, insofar as the Waugh Chapel Court identified PREI as the standard when there was only one lawsuit that could qualify as sham litigation and California Motor as the standard for when there was a series of prior proceedings, it left open the question of the standard to apply when there were two lawsuits that could have been sham litigation (a situation closer to the facts in PREI than in California Motor). After all, the sham litigation cases array along a continuum of instances of only one case filed to instances where many have been filed, and it seems overly rigid to limit the underlying analysis of PREI to situations involving only a single suit. Therefore, even if I applied Fourth Circuit law, I would have to consider the underlying rationale of Waugh Chapel to determine whether these allegations of two instances of sham litigation are analyzed best under PREI or California Motor. As the Waugh Chapel Court observed, the PREI standard is "ill-fitted" when "the presiding tribunal [for earlier] cases had no occasion to measure the baselessness of the suit," while the California Motor standard enables a court to assess potentially sham litigation when it cannot determine whether each legal proceeding was objectively baseless. Waugh Chapel, 728 F.3d at 364.
In Waugh Chapel, there was no way of knowing what the merits were of the various earlier proceedings. At least two petitions were withdrawn such that the tribunals never had the chance to consider them. Others were dismissed as moot or as conjecture without any decision on the merits with regard to whether the claims were objectively baseless.
Here, in contrast, in the sole earlier proceeding, Judge Trenga clearly had the opportunity to consider the bona fides because, as in this case, Capital One brought its antitrust counterclaims in response to IV's patent litigation. Indeed, Judge Trenga reached a decision on the merits with regard to four of the five patents IV originally identified. His conclusions are available to me in a published opinion that informed me of the court's rationale. Further, the issue of sham litigation arose in the Virginia court, and I have the benefit of Judge Trenga's cogent analysis.
Under PREI, what I need to determine is whether a reasonable litigant in IV's position could realistically expect to succeed on the merits of its claims in this Court because, if it could, the litigation was not objectively baseless and therefore not sham litigation. PREI, 508 U.S. at 51, 62, 113 S.Ct. 1920. As noted, this is an "absolute defense" that "requires no more than a `reasonabl[e] belie[f] that there is a chance that [a] claim may be held valid upon adjudication.'" Id. at 62, 113 S.Ct. 1920 (emphasis added) (citation omitted).
Fatally, Capital One cannot establish that IV's litigation against it was objectively baseless because there were too many indicia of probable cause. Most significantly, in this case, it is undisputed that the parties selected (ECF No. 134) and the Court appointed (ECF No. 143) an independent Special Master (with significant experience handling patent litigation), who wrote two comprehensive reports and recommendations (ECF Nos. 298, 315) regarding the merits of four of IV's patent claims after the parties submitted cross-motions for summary judgment on patent validity under 35 U.S.C. § 101. Prior to issuing those reports and recommendations, the Special Master resolved multiple discovery disputes (ECF Nos. 170, 199, 203, 209, 223, 286, 290, 294); reviewed the parties' extensive formal briefing (ECF Nos. 147-1, 169-1, 227, 246), as well as supplemental letter briefing that the Special Master requested (ECF Nos. 298-1, 298-2) and twenty-seven exhibits; and heard argument (ECF No. 298-3). Under the Special Master's detailed and insightful analysis, IV did succeed on two of its patent claims: the Special Master recommended a judgment of patent eligibility for the '084 and '002 Patents. ECF No. 298. This fact alone is sufficient to show that a reasonable litigant could realistically expect to succeed on the merits, and it vitiates the notion that the loss before Judge Trenga meant that IV no longer could reasonably believe that it could prevail in this court. And, next to this fact, any other disputes are scintillae.
Moreover, various other undisputed facts also support the finding that IV's litigation in this Court was not objectively baseless. First, there is the presumptive validity of each of the nine patents that were the subjects of IV's claims against Capital One. See 35 U.S.C. § 282(a) ("A patent shall be presumed valid."). Second, IV filed both suits before the Supreme Court decided Alice Corp. Pty. v. CLS Bank Int'l, ___ U.S. ___, 134 S.Ct. 2347, 2351-52, 189 L.Ed.2d 296 (2014) (holding that claims "disclos[ing] a computer-implemented scheme for mitigating `settlement risk' ... by using a third-party intermediary" were not patent eligible under 35 U.S.C. § 101 but rather were "drawn to the abstract idea of intermediated settlement, and that merely requiring generic computer implementation fails to transform that abstract idea into a patent-eligible invention"). I considered Alice and the parameters it set for eligibility in concluding that two of the patents before me were not actually patent-eligible. See Intellectual
Third, IV has not filed any additional suits against Capital One post-Alice. Fourth, IV withdrew specific claims when it was persuaded that it would not prevail, suggesting that it reasonably believed it could prevail on the others. Fifth, IV appealed my summary judgment rulings, an extra step that one who did not expect to succeed likely would not bother taking. Sixth, while Capital One incurred significant costs defending IV's patent claims, IV also incurred substantial litigation expenses. The litigation before me has involved nineteen attorneys for IV, as well as a Special Master and an economic consultant, the costs of whom the parties have shared. The docket includes almost 700 entries, and the documents in support of the parties' pending summary judgment briefing exceed 13,000 pages. Seventh, IV did not file for these patents with the Patent and Trademark Office; it acquired them and was entitled to rely on their presumptive validity. Eighth, Judge Trenga ruled that IV's patent infringement action was not an "exceptional case" marked by "unreasonable conduct" that would justify an award of attorneys' fees to Capital One pursuant to 35 U.S.C. § 285. Intellectual Ventures I LLC v. Capital One Fin. Corp., No. 13CV0740 (AJT/TCB), 2015 WL 7283108, at *1, *4 (E.D. Va. Nov. 17, 2015). Ninth, IV incurred the significant expense of designating nine experts on objective reasonableness — in comparison to Capital One's failure to designate any — something IV hardly would have done had it thought its underlying patent claims were objectively baseless. Under these circumstances, no reasonable factfinder could conclude that IV lacked probable cause.
Further, if I were to reach the subjective inquiry of whether IV initiated litigation to interfere directly with its competitor's business, it is questionable whether Capital One, a bank, could qualify as a
In sum, not only is Capital One not a competitor of IV, but more significantly, a reasonable litigant in IV's position realistically could have expected to succeed on the merits of its claims in this Court. Therefore, the litigation was not objectively baseless. Consequently, it was not sham litigation, and IV is entitled to Noerr-Pennington immunity, as its patent litigation is integral to Capital One's antitrust claims. PREI, 508 U.S. at 51, 62, 113 S.Ct. 1920.
Collateral estoppel, also known as issue preclusion, "works to ensure that parties get `one full and fair opportunity to litigate a particular issue, while preventing needless relitigation of that issue.'" Barna Conshipping, S.L. v. 2,000 Metric Tons, More or Less, of Abandoned Steel, 410 Fed.Appx. 716, 720 (4th Cir. 2011) (quoting In re Cygnus Telecomms. Tech., LLC, Patent Litig., 536 F.3d 1343, 1350 (Fed. Cir. 2008)). Collateral estoppel bars relitigation of an issue or fact if
In re Microsoft Corp. Antitrust Litig., 355 F.3d 322, 326 (4th Cir. 2004) (emphasis added).
Collateral estoppel may be offensive or defensive. Id. Offensive collateral estoppel is "[w]hen a plaintiff [or counter claimant or third party plaintiff] employs the doctrine of collateral estoppel or issue preclusion `to foreclose the defendant [or counter defendant or third party defendant] from litigating an issue the defendant has previously litigated unsuccessfully in an action with another party.'" Id. (quoting Parklane Hosiery Co. v. Shore, 439 U.S. 322, 326 n.4, 99 S.Ct. 645, 58 L.Ed.2d 552 (1979)). Defensive collateral estoppel is "when a defendant [or counter defendant or third party defendant] employs the doctrine `to prevent a plaintiff [or counter claimant or third party plaintiff] from asserting a claim the plaintiff [or counter claimant or third party plaintiff] has previously litigated and lost against another defendant.'" Id. (quoting Parklane Hosiery, 439 U.S. at 326 n.4, 99 S.Ct. 645). A defendant (or defending party) also can employ defensive collateral estoppel to bar claims the plaintiff (or claimant) already unsuccessfully made against it, rather than another defendant. See Zeno v. United States, No. DKC-09-544, 2009 WL 4910050, at *8 (D. Md. Dec. 11, 2009), aff'd, Zeno v. U.S., 451 Fed.Appx. 268 (4th Cir. 2011). Here, the Intellectual Ventures companies, which are Counter Defendants and Third Party Defendants, invoke the doctrine to prevent the Capital One companies, which are Counter Claimants and Third Party Plaintiffs, from asserting the claims they unsuccessfully alleged against IV in the Virginia litigation. This is an instance of defensive collateral estoppel. See id.; Microsoft, 355 F.3d at 326.
Notably, "relevant market" is a necessary element of all of Capital One's antitrust claims. See Berlyn Inc. v. The Gazette Newspapers, Inc., 73 Fed.Appx. 576, 582 (4th Cir. 2003) (noting that, "to determine whether any antitrust violation [under the Sherman Act or the Clayton Act] has occurred, `[the court]must first define the relevant market because the concept of competition has no meaning outside its own arena, however broadly that arena is defined,'" and that the party bringing an antitrust claim "bears the burden of proof on the issue of the relevant product and geographic markets" (emphasis added) (citing Satellite Television & Assoc. Res., Inc., v. Continental Cablevision of Va., Inc., 714 F.2d 351, 355 (4th Cir.1983))); see also Spectrum Sports, Inc. v. McQuillan, 506 U.S. 447, 456, 113 S.Ct. 884, 122 L.Ed.2d 247 (1993) (stating that, for an attempted monopolization claim under § 2 of the Sherman Act, "to determine whether there is a dangerous probability of monopolization, courts have found it necessary to consider the relevant market and the defendant's ability to lessen or destroy competition in that market" (emphasis added)); United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384 U.S. 563, 570-71, 86 S.Ct. 1698, 16 L.Ed.2d 778 (1966) (stating that, to prevail on a claim of monopolization under § 2 of the Sherman Act, a plaintiff must prove: "(1) the possession of monopoly power in the relevant market and (2) the willful acquisition or maintenance of that power as distinguished from growth or development as a consequence of a superior product, business acumen, or historic accident" (emphasis added)); United States v. Phila. Nat'l Bank, 374 U.S. 321, 363, 83 S.Ct. 1715, 10 L.Ed.2d 915 (1963) (holding that "a merger which produces a firm controlling an undue percentage share of the relevant market, and results in a significant increase in the concentration of firms in that market is so inherently likely to lessen competition substantially that it [is a violation of § 7 of the Clayton Act unless there is] evidence clearly showing that the merger is not likely to have such anticompetitive effects" (emphasis added)); It's My Party, Inc. v. Live Nat., Inc., 88 F.Supp.3d 475, 503 (D. Md. 2015) (stating that, to prevail on a claim of attempted monopolization, a plaintiff must prove "(1) a specific intent to monopolize a relevant market; (2) predatory or anticompetitive acts; and (3) a dangerous probability of successful monopolization") (emphasis added) (quoting Kolon Indus. Inc. v. E.I. DuPont de Nemours & Co., 748 F.3d 160, 177 (4th Cir. 2014)), aff'd sub nom. It's My Party, Inc. v. Live Nation, Inc., 811 F.3d 676 (4th Cir. 2016). Therefore, if the relevant market that Capital One alleges has
Capital One does not challenge whether it had a full and fair opportunity to litigate the sufficiency of its market definition before the Eastern District of Virginia, whether the sufficiency of the relevant market it alleged was actually resolved in that court, or whether Judge Trenga issued a valid, final judgment. See Capital One Opp'n 15-17. Rather, as noted, Capital One challenges the applicability of issue preclusion in two regards: (1) whether the relevant market is materially different in this litigation, and (2) whether Judge Trenga's conclusion that the proposed relevant market was not a relevant market for antitrust purposes was critical and necessary to the judgment he issued. See id. I will consider each challenge in turn.
In the Virginia litigation, Capital One alleged that the relevant market was the "market for technology enabling business processes common throughout the commercial banking industry in the United States." Intellectual Ventures, 2013 WL 6682981, at *5 (quoting pleadings). The Virginia court reworded the relevant market definition as "IV's `portfolio of 3,500 or more patents that [IV] alleges cover widely used financial and retail banking services' in the United States." Intellectual Ventures, 2013 WL 6682981, at *5. Here, Capital One once again alleges that IV's 3,500 patents comprise the relevant market. Fourth Am. Countercl. ¶ 158; Third Party Compl. ¶ 50. Notably, the alleged market has not changed because IV has not acquired any new patents in the relevant investment funds since Capital One filed its antitrust counterclaim in the Virginia litigation. Detkin Decl. ¶ 4, Ex. 69, Jt. Rec. 3,415. And, Capital One acknowledges that, previously, I observed that the "[Virginia] court restated the relevant market as the Intellectual Ventures companies' `portfolio of 3,500 or more patents,' the same market alleged here." Intellectual Ventures I LLC v. Capital One Fin. Corp., No. PWG-14-111, 2016 WL 160263, at *3 (D. Md. Jan. 14, 2016) (quoting Intellectual Ventures, 2013 WL 6682981, at *5); see Capital One Opp'n 16. Yet, in Capital One's view, the Virginia court's "restatement [of what the relevant market was] was dicta... based on comments made by Capital One's counsel during oral argument on IV's motion to dismiss," and the actual alleged market in the Virginia litigation was not the same as it is here. Capital One Opp'n 16. On the contrary, as IV asserts, IV Reply 5, the transcript from oral argument demonstrates that Judge Trenga
But, in this case, Capital One sets forth different facts to support a finding that these patents qualify as a relevant market for antitrust purposes. In the Virginia litigation, Capital One alleged that IV's patent portfolio qualified because Capital One had a business need to avoid litigation, which it only could do by licensing the patents in the portfolio. Now, instead of relying solely on the need to avoid litigation, which Judge Trenga already found to be insufficient to define a relevant market, Capital One also contends that "continu[ing] to provide the online services they already offer without paying the cost-prohibitive licensing fees to the Intellectual Ventures companies — the only source of such licenses —," is a business necessity. See Intellectual Ventures, 2016 WL 160263, at *3 (quoting Intellectual Ventures I LLC v. Capital One Fin. Corp., 99 F.Supp.3d 610, 622-23 (D. Md. 2015)). Based on this change in the factual allegations, I denied IV's motion to dismiss on claim preclusion grounds. Intellectual Ventures, 2016 WL 160263, at *3. Thus, pre-discovery, I concluded that Capital One adequately alleged a plausible relevant market that was not identical to the one alleged in Virginia and therefore not barred by collateral estoppel. Id.
Capital One relies on this preliminary finding to argue that the relevant markets are not identical. Capital One Opp'n 15, 17. In its view, these changes are material because "the evidence confirms that, to compete, Capital One must provide the core banking services that IV's infringement claims targeted, including ATMs, payment cards, and online and mobile banking," and "the business necessity allegations (and evidence) raise different market definition issues than those present in Virginia." Id. at 17.
IV counters that there "is no evidence to support the argument that a license was a `business necessity' for Capital One or any other bank, none of which licensed any patents." IV Reply 23 n.17. Indeed, discovery has concluded, and to date, IV's patent litigation has not led to Capital One (or any other company) licensing the portfolio of thousands of financial services patents that IV amassed, as none of IV's patent claims have resulted in a judgment in IV's favor. Nor is there any other evidence that Capital One has to license IV's patent portfolio or has been unable to do business because it has not licensed the patents. Certainly, Capital One may feel compelled to license the patents to avoid litigation, but Judge Trenga already concluded that avoiding litigation is not a sufficient business necessity to define a relevant market. Therefore, despite the new factual allegations before me, the alleged relevant market has not changed in a material way.
The crux of Capital One's argument is that the Fourth Circuit has stated that
Because, as noted, the motion before me involves defensive collateral estoppel, I look first to Ritter. There, the district court had dismissed the plaintiff's legal claims of discrimination against her employer under the Equal Pay Act ("EPA") and Age Discrimination in Employment Act ("ADEA") and held a bench trial on her equitable claims under Title VII. 814 F.2d at 988. At trial, the court found that Ritter "was not qualified for tenure" ("tenure issue") and that the only valid comparator she identified "was clearly more qualified" than she ("comparator issue"). Id. at 989-90. Ritter appealed the dismissal and the trial ruling. Id. at 989. The Fourth Circuit affirmed the results of trial based on the trial court's finding on the tenure issue, without reaching the comparator issue, but remanded for the trial court to hold a second trial, this time by jury, on the EPA and ADEA claims. Id. at 988.
On remand, the employer moved for summary judgment on the EPA and ADEA claims, arguing that, "because the ADEA and EPA claims had common elements with the Title VII claim, the issues determined by the court in the Title VII claim collaterally estopped the relitigation of those issues before a jury," and the district court granted the motion. Id. at 988-90. Ritter again appealed, and the Fourth Circuit considered "whether the findings of fact made by the trial judge in the Title VII equitable suit should collaterally estop the relitigation of those facts before the jury on the remanded EPA and ADEA legal actions." Id. at 988.
The Fourth Circuit decided that, even though "the doctrine of collateral estoppel was designed to bar the relitigation of issues determined in a prior suit," it could apply to relitigation within the same suit (as in the case before it), because where the relitigation "involves the same parties, the same issues arising out of the same set of facts, and the same court," the "`sameness' or mutuality of parties in interests which serves as the basis for the development
The court then considered whether collateral estoppel should apply, given that the district court decided both the tenure issue and the comparator issue when resolving Ritter's Title VII claim, and the Fourth Circuit had affirmed based on only the tenure issue. Id. at 993. It observed the general rule that, "where the court in the prior suit has determined two issues, either of which could independently support the result, then neither determination is considered essential to the judgment" and collateral estoppel does not bar relitigation of either issue, unless "one of the two determinations is upheld on appeal," in which case "collateral estoppel [bars relitigation] as to that issue. Id. The Fourth Circuit noted:
Id. at 993-94.
Despite this rule, the Fourth Circuit concluded that collateral estoppel barred relitigation of both issues in the case before it, reasoning that collateral estoppel is "limited by the overriding principle that the courts should protect a litigant's right to a full and fair opportunity to litigate his claims" but otherwise "capable of flexible determination to serve the interests of judicial economy by preventing needless relitigation." Id. at 994. It noted that Ritter "had a full and fair opportunity to litigate" the comparator issue as well as the tenure issue, given that she had "conducted extensive discovery" and "presented a vigorous argument to the trial court" on the comparator issue, and both rounds of litigation involved "the same parties, the same issues, the same facts, and even the same court." Id.
Zeno v. United States, No. DKC-09-544, 2009 WL 4910050 (D. Md. Dec. 11, 2009), aff'd, 451 Fed.Appx. 268 (4th Cir. 2011), in which this Court considered both Ritter and Microsoft, also provides guidance. In Zeno, the plaintiff, an attorney who had been subject to disciplinary proceedings in Puerto Rico, Massachusetts, and Texas, filed suit (with his wife) in this Court against several federal judges, the United States Attorney for the District of Puerto Rico, and several Assistant United States Attorneys, a Massachusetts state court judge, two clerks from the Massachusetts state court, and three Massachusetts attorneys. Id. at *1. The defendants moved to dismiss, and this Court granted the motion on the bases of lack of personal jurisdiction, improper venue, and, with regard to the defendant judges, prosecutors, and clerks, absolute and qualified immunity. Id. The plaintiffs appealed but then voluntarily dismissed their appeal. Id.
Thereafter, they filed suit again in this Court, against the same federal defendants as in their earlier lawsuit, as well as the United States. Id. at *2. They asserted that the Court had jurisdiction under the Federal Tort Claims Act. Id. The defendants moved to dismiss and the Court considered both claim and issue preclusion, concluding that claim preclusion barred
Zeno, 2009 WL 4910050, at *7 (emphasis added; original emphasis removed). Indeed, the Fourth Circuit noted that, in Ritter, it "essentially appl[ied] a law-of-the-case principle" while "call[ing] it collateral estoppel and appl[ying] it in the exceptional circumstances of that case, where the parties were the same, the issues were the same, the facts were the same, and even the court was the same." 355 F.3d at 328. In Microsoft, the Fourth Circuit held, in the context of offensive collateral estoppel, that "when issue preclusion is considered in the context of two separate litigations, the restrictive principle recognized in Ritter remains viable — that if a judgment in the prior case is supported by either of two findings, neither finding can be found essential to the judgment." Id.
But, significantly, in Zeno, this Court then noted that, "[d]espite the Fourth Circuit's general rule regarding alternative rulings and collateral estoppel, the Fourth Circuit [in Ritter] applied defensive collateral estoppel to bar issues in a case where two issues were previously decided and where both of the issues could have independently supported the result." Zeno, 2009 WL 4910050, at *8 (citing Ritter, 814 F.2d 986). This Court concluded in Zeno
Id.
As noted, what IV seeks to invoke is defensive collateral estoppel. Thus, the "greater possibility of unfairness from the use of offensive collateral estoppel" is not present. See Microsoft, 355 F.3d at 326. And, the prior litigation in the Eastern District of Virginia involved "the same parties, the same issues, [and] the same facts." Ritter, 814 F.2d at 994. Although the prior litigation was not in this Court, Judge Trenga's reasoning and analysis in his comprehensive written opinions in the Virginia case is available to me. See Intellectual Ventures I LLC v. Capital One Fin. Corp., No. 13CV0740 (AJT/TCB), 2015 WL 7283108, at *1, *4 (E.D. Va. Nov. 17, 2015); Intellectual Ventures I LLC v. Capital One Fin. Corp., No. 13-CV-740 AJT, 2013 WL 6682981 (E.D. Va. Dec. 18, 2013). Certainly, the conclusion that Capital One's alleged relevant market was "not a `relevant market' under any recognized antitrust jurisprudence," Intellectual Ventures, 2013 WL 6682981, at *5, which provided a basis for dismissal of the monopolization and attempted monopolization claims, see id. at *5, *8, was only one of two alternative grounds for dismissal of these claims. See id. at *6-7 (concluding that capital One failed to alleged unlawful monopoly power sufficiently); see also id. at *8 ("Capital One's attempted monopolization claim alleges the same injury, and in the same fashion, as its monopolization claim ... and fails to state a claim for the same reasons.").
But, as noted, Capital One does not challenge whether it had a full and fair opportunity to litigate the sufficiency of its market definition before the Eastern District of Virginia. See Capital One Opp'n 15-17. Indeed, Capital One filed an opposition to IV's motion to dismiss in that court and argued its position at a hearing, advocating for its alleged relevant market in both instances. Moreover, the court considered both the opposition brief and the oral argument in resolving the motion, id. at *5 (citing hearing transcript and opposition). Also, as in Zeno, Capital One appealed the prior court's ruling to the Fourth Circuit and then withdrew its appeal. Thus, the sufficiency of the market definition was fully and fairly litigated. Under these circumstances, it is appropriate to apply defensive collateral estoppel in this case to estop Capital One from arguing that its relevant market, which has not changed materially from the relevant market alleged
In sum, IV's Motion for Summary Judgment, ECF No. 656, IS GRANTED because Noerr-Pennington immunity and collateral estoppel both bar Capital One's antitrust claims. The parties' Motions to Seal, ECF Nos. 658, 665, and 676, ARE GRANTED. IV's objections to the Joint Record Exhibits, ECF No. 674, ARE OVERRULED. A separate Order will issue.
Also pending are motions to seal the opening brief and opposition. ECF Nos. 658, 665. I have considered the motions and other filings in this case, included redacted versions of the sealed documents, and in the interest of protecting confidential, proprietary, trade secret, and/or commercially sensitive information, I will grant the motions to seal.
Intellectual Ventures also has filed objections to the Joint Record Exhibits, ECF No. 674 (redacted), 675 (sealed), as well as a motion to seal its objections, ECF No. 676. Its motion to seal is granted for the same reasons that the summary judgment briefings are sealed. However, the objections are overruled. And, although I relied on the sealed briefings for this Memorandum Opinion, its contents do not justify sealing it, because the public's interest in a public ruling outweighs the parties' interest in sealing information related to this case.