KATHERINE B. FORREST, District Judge.
Purported class actions alleging securities laws violations are commenced in this district with frequency. And with frequency, class certification is granted. The certified action proceeds along a relatively predictable path of expensive litigation, significant potential loss allegations, and most often, an eventual settlement. Certification of the class is, therefore, a crucial inflection point in such a case. Given the enormous ramifications of certifying a class — turning potential losses from relatively small amounts into potentially massive exposure — careful analysis of the factors under Rule 23 is required. This rigorous analysis is further required by Supreme Court precedent
While it is certainly true that many motions for class certification meet the requirements of Rule 23, it is also true that there are those that do not. This is one that does not.
As set forth in this Court's prior decisions on the motions to dismiss,
Plaintiff now moves for class certification pursuant to Rules 23(a) and (b)(3) of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure of a class consisting of:
(Aug. 2, 2012 Am. Class Action Compl., ECF No. 59.)
This Court's most significant concern is that the particular named plaintiffs chosen to represent the putative class are subject to unique defenses. The Court finds that the presence of unique defenses defeats adequacy, typicality, and predominance. In addition, after an evidentiary hearing at which the Court heard testimony from the experts proffered by the parties, the Court also finds that plaintiffs have failed to show by a preponderance of the evidence that the China Automotive securities at issue — common stock, options, and puts — traded in an efficient market. In the absence of sufficient proof that the market for the securities at issue was efficient, plaintiffs are not entitled to a presumption of reliance. In the absence of such a presumption, reliance must be proven on an individualized basis — also defeating predominance. For all of these reasons, class certification must be denied.
Plaintiffs allege that defendants made a series of false and misleading statements regarding CAAS' accounting for certain convertible notes issued on February 15, 2008 (the "Convertible Notes"), CAAS' operating expenses and other charges against income. Plaintiffs also allege a series of actionable omissions: that defendants failed to reveal alleged material deficiencies in the CAAS' internal controls, failed to disclose that the financial results were not prepared in accordance with Generally Accepted Accounting Principles, and failed to disclose that SLF was not licensed to conduct audits in the People's Republic of China.
Plaintiffs allege that until December 31, 2008, CAAS was entitled to classify the Convertible Notes as equity and not as liabilities. However, a new accounting rule went into effect as of January 1, 2009 (EITF 07-05), which required that the Notes thereafter be classified as liabilities. In its 2008 Form 10-K, CAAS specifically recognized that EITF 07-05 would require it to evaluate its impact on its financial statements. Plaintiffs allege that despite the requirements of EITF, defendants continued to classify the Convertible Notes as equity during all of 2009 and the first three quarters of 2010, resulting in a significant misstatement of earnings.
Plaintiffs allege that in December 2010, CAAS announced that it was replacing SLF with PricewaterhouseCoopers LLP ("PWC"). This announcement was followed by a decline in CAAS' stock price. On March 12, 2011, CAAS disclosed in a press release and Form 8-K that its Form 10-K for 2010 would be delayed due to the prior misclassification of the Convertible Notes; this caused a significant drop in CAAS' stock price. Ultimately, CAAS issued a restatement of net income for the Class Period.
In order to prove their claims pursuant to Rule 10b-5, plaintiffs must demonstrate the following:
A prima facie claim under Section 20(a) — for control person liability in connection with a securities law violation — requires an underlying violation by a controlled person, control of the primary violator by the targeted defendant, and some "meaningful culpable participation" by the targeted defendant.
This Court's denial of class certification follows its rigorous review of the requirements of Rule 23 based on evidence from an evidentiary hearing, declarations, and other materials submitted in connection with this motion.
Earlier this year, the Supreme Court reiterated the longstanding proposition that "[r]eliance . . . is an essential element of the § 10 (b) private cause of action."
Recognizing the difficulties of proving direct reliance, in
The presumption of reliance is, however, just that — a presumption. It is rebuttable.
Plaintiffs allege that the corrective disclosure that revealed the fraud occurred on March 17, 2011. Each of the lead plaintiffs, Nancy and Robert George and Randall Whitman, made post-disclosure purchases.
Plaintiff Nancy George made four post-disclosure purchases. She made a purchase in August 2011, then again two weeks after the original complaint was filed in this matter (November 2011), and again on March 1, 2012, shortly after the amended complaint was filed. Nancy George made yet another purchase on February 25, 2013, six weeks after the instant motion for class certification was filed. At her deposition Nancy George testified that she had purchased stock following the Class Period, and that she had made a profit.
Nancy George provided investing advice to her husband, Robert George. Robert George purchased CAAS securities on five occasions following the issuance of the alleged corrective disclosure on March 17, 2011. His last purchase was in March 2012.
Finally, Randall Whitman made several purchases of CAAS securities — his first was the day after the March 17, 2011, corrective disclosure.
Thus, each of the named plaintiffs increased their holdings of CAAS securities after each had allegedly learned of the fraud. In total, the named plaintiffs made thirteen post-disclosure purchases.
Each of the three named plaintiffs also engaged in significant "in-and-out" trading activity during the Class Period. Nancy George engaged in at least three in-and-out transactions. Defendants assert that she made a profit on these sales. Robert George, her husband, made at least six in-and-out transactions — buying and selling over 10,000 shares. Defendants assert that some of these transactions were at a profit. For his part, Randall Whitman engaged in more in-and-out transactions than Nancy and Robert George combined: a total of fifteen in-and-out transactions during the class period. At his deposition, Randall Whitman conceded that sometimes he would purchase shares of CAAS stock on one day and sell it the next. As discussed below, whether the in-and-out purchases resulted in a trading profit is not determinative of the issue on this motion — rather, the point is that the parties will spend significant time and resources on this issue, overwhelming common issues.
A plaintiff seeking to certify a class must prove by a preponderance of the evidence that its proposed class meets the requirements of Rule 23(a) and, if those requirements are met, that the class is maintainable under at least one of the subdivisions of Rule 23(b).
Rule 23(a) states that a party may be a class representative only if:
Fed. R. Civ. P. 23(a).
The subdivision of Rule 23 that plaintiff seeks to certify a class under is (b)(3), which allows certification "if the questions of law or fact common to class members predominate over any questions affecting only individual members, and . .. a class litigation is superior to other available methods for fairly and efficiently adjudicating the controversy." Fed. R. Civ. P. 23(b)(3);
Rule 23 is not a mere pleading standard. "A party seeking class certification must affirmatively demonstrate his compliance with the Rule."
Class certification is appropriate if, inter alia, "the class is so numerous that joinder of all members is impracticable." Fed. R. Civ. P. 23(a)(1). A class of more than forty members "presumptively satisfies the numerosity requirement."
Commonality is also uncontested on this motion. Even a single question of law or fact will suffice to satisfy the commonality requirement.
Here, the question of whether defendants' disclosures are legally adequate is itself a sufficient common question to satisfy Rule 23. That question is common to all members of the proposed class.
In the Second Circuit, typicality is satisfied when "each class member's claim arises from the same course of events and each class member makes similar legal arguments to prove the defendant's liability."
To satisfy the "adequacy" requirement, plaintiffs must prove both that the interests of the named plaintiffs are not antagonistic to other members of the class, and that plaintiffs' attorneys are qualified, experienced, and able to conduct the litigation.
Defendants argue that plaintiffs cannot meet the typicality or adequacy requirements because their claims are subject to unique defenses. The presence of unique defenses may, in certain cases, defeat class certification.
In
In
Here, as discussed above, all three named plaintiffs continued to make purchases of the securities at issue following the alleged "truthful" disclosure. A named plaintiff who has engaged in a post-disclosure purchase is subject to the defense that the alleged misstatements or omissions were really not a factor in the purchasing decision but rather that other investment considerations drove the decision. Defendants may assert that the disclosure of the fraud was irrelevant to the named plaintiffs as demonstrated by their pattern of continued purchasing. In fact, defendants have stated an intention to aggressively pursue this line of inquiry. This will require that each of the named plaintiffs expend considerable time on unique defenses — precisely the situation the case law does not condone.
In addition to these post-disclosure purchases, each of the named plaintiffs was an in-and-out trader during the class period. At oral argument on this motion, counsel for plaintiff argued that excluding in-and-out purchasers would make no sense in many securities cases given the number of institutional investors who routinely made in-and-out trades. This argument misses the point and ignores the law. First, none of the three named plaintiffs in this case is an institutional investor. Second, as set forth above, a number of courts have found that in-and-out traders may be subject to unique defenses, making them inadequate class representatives.
As in-and-out traders, the named plaintiffs again subject themselves to unique inquiries regarding their trading patterns and why they made investment decisions, whether the fraud was in fact irrelevant to their purchasing and sale decisions, and whether on individual trades they profited. These inquiries will also require considerable time and resources and indeed threaten to become the focus of the litigation.
Given the trading patterns of the three named plaintiffs, it is certain that defendants will search out every individual angle and defense in relation to them. Given their factual circumstances, these three named plaintiffs are neither typical nor adequate.
In addition to having to meet each of the requirements of Rule 23(a) by a preponderance of the evidence (which the named plaintiffs have here failed to do), plaintiffs must also meet the requirements of Rule 23(b)(3), referred to as the "predominance" requirement. They have failed to carry this burden.
Predominance tests whether the proposed class is sufficiently cohesive to warrant adjudication by representation.
"Class-wide issues predominate if resolution of some of the legal or factual questions that qualify each class member's case as a genuine controversy can be achieved through generalized proof, and if these issues are more substantial than the issues subject only to individualized proof."
Class certification is only warranted if plaintiffs can establish by a preponderance of the evidence a class-wide presumption of reliance by virtue of the presence of an efficient market critical to the fraud-on-the-market theory.
In the absence of this presumption of reliance on a market that absorbs the alleged material misstatements and omissions, questions as to whether any particular investor in fact relied on any particular misstatement or omission come to the fore and may overwhelm the common questions. In such a situation, resolution through representative class action is neither feasible nor a superior means of adjudication.
In order for the fraud-on-the-market theory to apply, plaintiffs must demonstrate that the securities at issue traded in an efficient market. In the absence of an efficient market, it is not clear that the assumptions underlying the fraud-on-the-market theory can or should apply; whether certain material information (including the alleged misstatements or omissions) was impounded into the stock price cannot be assumed to have occurred.
Here, defendants assert that plaintiffs have failed to carry their burden of showing by a preponderance of the evidence that CAAS securities traded in an efficient market. In the absence of reliance on a demonstrated efficient market, each class member would be required to demonstrate his or her own reliance on the particular misstatements or omissions; the need for such individualized showings would overwhelm common issues.
Courts have generally described three forms of the efficient market hypothesis — the third of which, as noted below, has now been widely discredited:
In seeking class certification, plaintiffs relying on the fraud-on-the market theory to establish reliance bear the burden of proving market efficiency by a preponderance of the evidence. To defeat the presumption of reliance, defendants do not, therefore, have to show an inefficient market. They must, however, demonstrate that plaintiffs' proffered proof of market efficiency falls short of the mark. That is precisely what defendants have done here.
In analyzing market efficiency, courts generally refer to a series of factors set forth in
Both plaintiffs and defendants submitted expert declarations in connection with the motion for class certification. Plaintiffs submitted initial and reply declarations from Kenneth N. Kotz, a Vice President of Forensic Economics in Rochester, New York.
The Court initially held oral argument on the motion for class certification on May 7, 2013. The Court then held an evidentiary hearing on May 30, 2013, at which the parties examined and cross-examined the proffered experts. The evidentiary hearing was particularly useful in this matter to assist the Court in understanding the parties' analyses and to assess the credibility of the analytical work performed. The Court finds that, as Garrett opined, Kotz did not perform analyses which are sufficiently supportive of CAAS securities trading in an efficient market. Plaintiffs have therefore failed to carry their burden on this issue by a preponderance of the credible evidence. Accordingly, plaintiffs are unable to rely on CAAS securities trading in an efficient market in order to obtain the presumption of reliance. As a result, reliance would need to be proven on an individualized basis, defeating predominance. Class certification is also denied on this basis.
Kotz testified that his definition of an efficient market is one in which all publicly available information is quickly impounded into the stock price. (Tr. 48.) This is consistent with the definition set forth in the case law.
The first analysis that Kotz performed purported to test the speed of price reaction in the CAAS stock to new information. In this test, Kotz first identified the days on which CAAS stock had the largest excess returns, identified by their tstatistics. He then looked to see whether there was a statistically significant return on the following day. If the following day did not have a statistically significant return, he opined that it was an indication of an efficient market. In this test Kotz assumes that the largest returns associated with the CAAS stock are a proxy for news events that resulted in an impact on the stock price. At the evidentiary hearing, Kotz conceded that "this test pays no attention to what news, if any, was released" on the days with the largest returns (or t-statistics associated with the largest returns). (Tr. 51-52.)
This test suffers from a fatal logical flaw: it purports to test whether or not information is efficiently impounded into the CAAS stock price without looking at whether the days in which there was price movement had any news actually associated with them (it takes the event out of "event study."). At the evidentiary hearing, Garrett testified that in Kotz 1, Kotz looked at the thirteen days with the highest t-statistics and assumes that those are days associated with information releases, and then looks at the subsequent thirteen days to see if they have a statistically significant stock price change. (
In Kotz 2, he compares the proportion of statistically significant "news" and "no news" days. Kotz starts with any days during the Class Period during which there were "headlines" relating to CAAS. (
In this test, Kotz performs "an objective assessment of whether price movements are associated with trading volumes." (Apr. 8, 2013 Kotz Reply Decl. ¶ 26, ECF No. 102 ("Kotz Reply").) He concedes that it does not analyze specific news but instead concentrates on daily traded share volume and the magnitude of excess returns. (
Garrett testified that this test has no support in the academic literature, and Kotz conceded as much in paragraph 27 of his reply declaration and at the evidentiary hearing. (Tr. 57.)
Garrett testified credibly and comprehensibly that this test does not support a conclusion of an efficient market and that "[i]t's equally consistent with an efficient market and a herd of wildebeests — when the wildebeests roam into the market, there's more stock price change." (
Kotz 4(a) most closely approximates an event study — but even so, it suffers from serious and fatal methodological flaws. In this test, Kotz states that he predefined events for CAAS that were expected to impact the stock price: analyst rating changes and earnings guidance releases. (Kotz Reply ¶ 32.) He identified sixteen such events during the Class Period.
Kotz opines that even though there are sixteen identified events, not all are expected to be associated with statistically significant excess returns. He points to language in a case from the district court in Pennsylvania as supportive of this position.
Out of the sixteen days identified, Kotz found seven that had statistically significant stock movement. (
In addition, Kotz testified on cross-examination that of the sixteen identified days, one quarter had stock movement that was actually directionally inconsistent. (
As Garrett testified, the market should react to new material information. The Court agrees with and credits his criticism of Kotz 4(a) in that it does not make a determination of material or non-material — and therefore must assume that when 50% of the identified days do not have statistically significant returns the days simply must not matter. However, those days might in fact be days on which there was something material, and in that event, a lack of price movement could well signify an inefficiency. Kotz 4(a) does not account for this possibility. (
(
Even assuming that the methodology was proper, showing that only seven out of sixteen days resulted in a market reaction is an insufficient foundation upon which to pronounce market efficiency. (
In this test, based on the t-statistics of certain days during the Class Period, Kotz identified the days in which the largest single day price movements occurred. At the evidentiary hearing, Kotz conceded that he started his analysis with the days in which he had identified the largest t-statistics and then went back to see what if any news was associated with those days that might explain the stock price movement. (
Of the top ten days (with the highest t-statistics), Kotz then found that on four there was no relevant news concerning China Automotive or the Chinese automotive industry in general, two days involved only the Chinese automotive industry in general, and four out of the ten days actually involved news relating to China Automotive.
At the evidentiary hearing the Court was able to explore the bases for Kotz's and Garrett's opinions. The Court finds that Garrett provided complete and sound examples of the methodological shortcomings of each of Kotz's tests. In contrast, the Court found that Kotz could not explain or defend why his methodology made analytical sense given the definition of market efficiency.
None of the tests utilized by Kotz provides a reliable basis upon which to rest an opinion or evidence of market efficiency. On that basis alone, plaintiffs have failed to carry their burden of proof on the issue of market efficiency and therefore predominance. But more than that, the Court finds that Kotz's results are in fact more supportive than not of market inefficiency. While defendants do not bear the burden of showing market inefficiency, the Court cannot help but note the numerous days during the Class Period when news events did not result in price movement, or statistically significant price movement was not associated with a news event. Taken with the methodological flaws, this cannot be ignored.
Plaintiffs have not proven market efficiency by a preponderance of the evidence.
Plaintiffs' motion for class certification fails for the various, independent reasons set forth above.
SO ORDERED.