CARMAN, Judge:
This action is before the Court following the final results of redetermination pursuant to remand ("Remand Results"), filed by the Department of Commerce ("Commerce") on December 20, 2010. (ECF No. 43.) Plaintiff Shandong Rongxin Import & Export Company ("Shandong") challenges
In China First Pencil Co. v. United States, 34 CIT ___, 721 F.Supp.2d 1369 (2010), the Court sustained-in-part and remanded-in-part Commerce's final determination in the 2006-2007 administrative review of the antidumping duty order on Certain Cased Pencils from the People's Republic of China ("PRC"). The above captioned case was consolidated with China First shortly before the Court issued its opinion; after Commerce issued the Remand Results, Shandong was the only party seeking to challenge the Remand Results. Accordingly, the Court severed the cases and issued a judgment in China First Pencil Co. v. United States, Court No. 09-00325. Shandong now proceeds on its own.
The Court has jurisdiction over this matter pursuant to 19 U.S.C. § 1516a(a)(2) and 28 U.S.C. § 1581(c).
In determining the dumping margin in this case, Commerce calculated the normal value of the subject merchandise on the basis of the values of certain factors of production in "a market economy country or countries considered to be appropriate by [Commerce]." 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(1). The purpose of this statute is "to assess the price or costs of factors of production of [the subject merchandise in a surrogate market economy country,] in an attempt to construct a hypothetical market value of that product in [the nonmarket economy country]." Nation Ford Chem. Co. v. United States, 166 F.3d 1373, 1375 (Fed. Cir.1999) (internal quotations omitted). In deciding how to appropriately value factors of production, Commerce is required to "utilize, to the extent possible, the prices or costs of factors of production in one or more market economy countries that are— (A) at a level of economic development comparable to that of the nonmarket economy country, and (B) significant producers of comparable merchandise." 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(4). When Commerce elects to calculate normal value pursuant to this method, one of the factors of production for which it must establish a value is labor, or the wage rate. 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(3).
In Dorbest Ltd. v. United States, 604 F.3d 1363, 1372 (Fed.Cir.2010), the Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit ("CAFC") invalidated the regulation in which Commerce had established its preferred method for valuing labor as a factor of production. The CAFC held that the agency's regression-based methodology produced a value for labor that failed to utilize data only from countries that are at a level of economic development comparable to that of the nonmarket economy country, and that are significant producers of comparable merchandise, as required by 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(4). See id. Because the final determination challenged in China First was issued prior to the CAFC
As a threshold matter, Commerce determined that when valuing labor as a factor of production, data from several countries is preferable to data from a single country. While the agency normally values most other factors of production by using figures from a single surrogate country, Commerce continues to find, as it did before the CAFC invalidated its regression-based analysis in Dorbest, that labor is different. Remand Results at 10-11; see also 19 C.F.R. § 351.408(c)(2). According to Commerce, labor is distinguished from other factors of production because it demonstrates wide variability, even between countries with similar gross national income per capita ("GNI"). Remand Results at 10. Commerce justifies this view by citing "many socio-economic, political and institutional factors, such as labor laws and policies unrelated to the size or strength of an economy, that cause significant variances in wage levels between countries," and by noting that "labor is not traded internationally." Id. at 11 (citing International Labor Organization, Global Wage Report: 2009 Update, at 5, 7 and 10 (2009), available at http://www.ilo.org/ wcmsp5/groups/public/@dgreports/@ dcomm/documents/publication/wcms_ 116500.pdf (last visited April 21, 2011).) Accordingly, Commerce valued labor by calculating a simple average of certain specific wage rate data from the group of countries the agency determined to be both economically comparable to the PRC and significant producers of comparable merchandise. Id.; see also Remand Determination of 2006-2007 Administrative Review of the Antidumping Duty Order on Certain Cased Pencils from the People's Republic of China: Industry-Specific Wage Rate Selection ("Wage Rate Memo"), October 13, 2010 (AR 2707) at 4-5.
To identify which countries are at a level of economic development comparable to the PRC, Commerce began with the Surrogate Country Memo, in which it had identified five countries as potential surrogates from which the agency would be able to derive values for all the other factors of production, besides labor. Wage Rate Memo at 2. Commerce ranked the five countries in order of ascending GNI: India, the Philippines, Indonesia, Colombia, and Thailand. Id. Using the lowest-GNI country (India) and highest-GNI country (Thailand) as "bookends," Commerce turned to the World Bank's 2009 World Development Report to identify every country with a GNI between the two, thus establishing the first and broadest basket of countries—44 that the agency deemed to be economically comparable to the PRC. Id.; see also id. at Attach. 2.
Commerce then determined which of these 44 countries were significant producers of comparable merchandise by identifying every country that exported any quantity of comparable merchandise (defined as exports under HTS 9609.10.00) between 2005 and 2007. Id. at 3. This produced a narrower basket of countries-30 that, in the agency's view, satisfy the
The next step in Commerce's process was to assess which of these 30 countries had made available adequate data that could be averaged together to produce a single surrogate value for labor. Deciding which data would suffice for this purpose required the agency to make a series of choices. First, Commerce decided that it would rely on earnings or wages data reported to the International Labor Organization ("ILO").
When countries report any type of industry-specific data to the ILO, including the wages and earnings data of interest in this proceeding, they do so according to a uniform code known as the ISIC.
Finally, Commerce filtered and, in some cases, adjusted the data provided by these 10 countries, in order "to arrive at a single earnings or wage rate for each country." Id. at 4-5. First, the agency prioritized the use of earnings data when available, and wages data when not. Id. at 5. Second, the agency only considered data with combined male and female coverage. Id. Third, the agency used earnings or wages data most contemporaneous to 2007; if it had to use data from an earlier year, the agency inflated it with the use of the relevant Consumer Price Index to approximate 2007 price levels. Id. Fourth, Commerce "selected from the following categories [of workers], in the following hierarchy: 1) wage earners; 2) employees; 3) salaried employees; and 4) total employment." Id. Finally, Commerce chose hourly data where available; if a country reported data only on a daily, weekly, or monthly basis, the agency converted that data to an hourly figure assuming "8 working hours per day, 5.5 working days a week, and 24 working days per month." Id. After massaging the data in accordance to the foregoing parameters, Commerce calculated a final simple average industry-specific wage rate of $0.97 per hour. Id.
Well, it was almost final. Before issuing the Remand Results, Commerce noticed that three of the countries it had included in the final group of 10 (because they met the dual requirements of § 1677b(c)(4), and had provided all relevant data in the right ISIC code revision) were nonmarket economies. Analysis Memorandum, December 6, 2010 (AR 2753) at 3. Because the surrogate value for labor in an NME proceeding cannot be based on labor values from other nonmarket economies, Commerce reduced the final group to seven countries, with a simple average wage rate of $1.07/hour.
Shandong's primary argument is that Commerce should have only used wage data from India, rather than from a basket of countries, to value labor as a factor of production. (Pl.'s Cmts. 4-20.) Plaintiff argues that by valuing labor from a group of countries, while valuing all other factors of production from a single surrogate country, "Commerce has acted in an arbitrary and capricious manner." (Id. at 6.) Plaintiff cites 19 C.F.R. § 351.408(c)(2) and claims that "Commerce has a clear policy of obtaining as many surrogate values from a single country as possible." (Id. at 12 (emphasis in original).) What Plaintiff does not acknowledge, however, is that this regulation explicitly identifies labor as an exception to the "normal" approach. 19 C.F.R. § 351.408(c)(2) ("Except for labor, [Commerce] normally will value all factors in a single surrogate country.")
While Shandong's only explicit argument is that Commerce was required to use labor data from one country (India) rather than a group of countries, there are portions of its brief which might be read to argue in the alternative that even if using
Shandong's other major dispute with the Remand Results is on the issue of which countries constitute "significant producers of comparable merchandise" within the meaning of 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(4)(B). (Id. at 20.) Plaintiff argues that Commerce's interpretation of the term "significant producers" to include any country with any quantity of exports in the relevant time period is an impermissible construction of the statute. (Id. at 21.) Plaintiff states that for Commerce "to conclude that any country that registers exports of a product, no matter how commercially inconsequential, represents a `significant producer' of that product . . . simply cannot withstand any real scrutiny." (Id. at 21.) Plaintiff points to the fact that the share of world trade held by many of the countries Commerce deemed "significant producers" is astonishingly minuscule, including, for instance, .00266% for Ukraine, .00356% for Ecuador, and.00756% for Egypt. (Id. at 22.) Plaintiff also notes that according to the statute's legislative history, "the term `significant producer' includes any country that is a significant net exporter," (quoting Conference Report to the 1988 Omnibus Trade & Competitiveness Act, H.R.Rep. No. 100-576, at 590, 1988 U.S.C.C.A.N. 1547, 1623 (1988)), and points out that Commerce "has previously relied on countries being a net exporter in order to qualify as a significant producer," (citing Certain Non-Frozen Apple Juice Concentrate from the People's Republic of China, 69 Fed.Reg. 65, 148 (Nov. 10, 2004) and accompanying Issues and Decision Memo). (Id. at 24.)
Defendant responds to Shandong's first argument by maintaining that Commerce's reliance on data from multiple countries to produce a surrogate value for labor is supported by substantial evidence on the record and is otherwise in accordance with law. (Def.'s Resp. to Remand Cmts. by Pl. Shandong Rongxin Import & Export Co. Ltd. ("Def.'s Resp.") 5-12.) Defendant points to the record evidence, which demonstrates wide variability of wages among countries with relatively comparable gross national income, and notes that Commerce cited several characteristics which distinguish labor from other production inputs. (Id. at 7.) Defendant highlights that Shandong's position that Commerce must use a single country to value labor is explicitly contradicted by statute, regulation, and CAFC case law. (Id. at 8-9 (citing 19
The United States also defends Commerce's view that a country is a "significant producer" if it exports any quantity of comparable merchandise in the relevant period. (Id. at 12-16.) Arguing under a Chevron framework, Defendant asserts that the term "significant producer" is ambiguous and undefined in the statute. (Id. at 13 (citing Chevron U.S.A., Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc., 467 U.S. 837, 104 S.Ct. 2778, 81 L.Ed.2d 694 (1984)).) Defendant's view is that the legislative history is unhelpful, because it only indicates that the term "significant producer includes" a net exporter, but offers no specific metric or definition. (Id. (emphasis added and internal quotation omitted).) Thus, moving to the second prong of Chevron, Defendant asserts that Commerce is entitled to substantial deference. Defendant explains that Commerce's motivation for defining "significant producer" in this way was "to maximize the size of the ultimate basket of countries for data purposes while still accounting for this criterion." (Id. at 14.) But, pointedly, Defendant does not explain how treating a country with any quantity of exports actually accounts for this criterion.
The Court finds groundless Shandong's argument that Commerce was obligated to utilize data from a single country to value labor. This argument is untenable in the face of a statute, agency regulation, and CAFC case law which all explicitly permit the agency to utilize data from multiple countries. 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(4) (instructing Commerce to "utilize, to the extent possible, the prices or costs of factors of production in one or more market economy countries") (emphasis added); 19 C.F.R. § 351.408(c)(2) (explicitly excepting labor from Commerce's normal approach of valuing factors of production in a single surrogate country); and Dorbest, 604 F.3d at 1372 (describing a possible "subset of . . . countries" that would satisfy the dual requirements of § 1677b(c)(4)). Additionally, Commerce is well justified in averaging wage rates to produce a single surrogate value, with record evidence establishing both the existence of variation in wages among similarly economically developed countries, and the reasons for it. (See Remand Results at 10-11 (citing International Labor Organization, Global Wage Report: 2009 Update, (2009) at 5, 7, and 10.)) Commerce is therefore acting reasonably when it treats labor differently from other factors of production. Accordingly, Commerce's decision to utilize data from multiple countries is supported by substantial evidence on the record, and is otherwise in accordance with law.
The Court is less sanguine, however, about the reasons Commerce cites for excluding Indian labor data, which was reported under ISIC-Rev.2, from the group of countries ultimately providing the labor rate, all of which reported data under ISIC-Rev.3. While the agency has made clear that it prefers "to use data from a single ISIC revision to ensure consistency
Commerce has broad discretion to determine which criteria it will use to sort and prioritize the data it uses in making its determination. The Court's role is to ensure that Commerce's sorting and prioritizing decisions are reasonable and consistently applied. In this case, the Court finds that most of Commerce's sorting and prioritizing decisions are well justified, such as the decision to use earnings data if available, and wages data if not, and the choice only to utilize data reported for both sexes. The decision to insist that data be reported under a common ISIC revision, however, is not supported by substantial evidence on the record. On remand, if Commerce still wishes to omit all labor data that a qualifying country reported under ISIC-Rev.2, it must explain why the need for consistency across ISIC revisions predominates over the need for a broad basket of countries to value labor. Alternatively, if Commerce determines that the chief value is to have the broadest feasible basket of countries, Commerce is instructed to review which qualifying countries have reported data under a prior ISIC revision which satisfy the agency's other requirements.
The final issue of concern for the Court is Commerce's construal of the term "significant producer" to mean any country with any level of exports under the relevant HTS subheading. See Remand Results at 20. Commerce's justification for this is pure speculation: the agency claims that "a country's ability to export comparable merchandise is indicative of substantial production because it is likely producing merchandise at a level that surpasses its internal consumption." Id. There is nothing on the record to support this theory
The term "significant" in 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(4) is not statutorily defined, and is inherently ambiguous. Significant has among its definitions "having meaning" and "having or likely to have influence or effect." Webster's Third New International Dictionary 2116 (1993). Because the term is ambiguous, Commerce is entitled to broad deference in its construal of the term, and the Court's question "is whether [Commerce's] answer is based on a permissible construction of the statute." Chevron, 467 U.S. at 842-43, 104 S.Ct. 2778. Commerce's interpretation of "significant" encompasses countries which almost certainly have no domestic production—at least not any meaningful production, capable of having influence or effect—and is therefore an impermissible construction of 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c)(4). On remand, if Commerce wishes to continue to rely on export statistics as a proxy for significant production, it must include some additional mechanism to ensure that it does not propagate the fiction that countries with a few dollars of exports are engaged in significant production. Alternatively, Commerce is free to adopt an altogether different approach to identifying significant production.
In conclusion, for the reasons stated herein, the Court affirms Commerce's decision to rely on data from multiple countries to value labor as a factor of production pursuant to 19 U.S.C. § 1677b(c), and it is hereby