PHILLIPS, Circuit Judge.
Cox Cable subscribers cannot access premium cable services — features such as interactive program guides, pay-per-view programming, and recording or rewinding capabilities — unless they also rent a set-top box from Cox. Dissatisfied with this arrangement, a class of plaintiffs in Oklahoma City ("Plaintiffs") sued Cox under the antitrust laws. They alleged that Cox had illegally tied cable services to set-top-box rentals in violation of § 1 of the Sherman Act, which prohibits illegal restraints of trade. See 15 U.S.C. § 1.
Though a jury found that Plaintiffs had proved the necessary elements to establish a tying arrangement, the district court disagreed. In granting Cox's Fed. R. Civ. P. 50(b) motion, the court determined that Plaintiffs had offered insufficient evidence for a jury to find that Cox's tying arrangement "foreclosed a substantial volume of commerce in Oklahoma City to other sellers or potential sellers of set-top boxes in
In assessing the district court's ruling, we first examine how the Supreme Court's treatment of tying arrangements has evolved. Next, we turn to how we and other circuit courts have applied this precedent and how tying law has evolved in the circuit courts. Finally, we analyze the district court's assessment of what the evidence showed in light of the evolving state of the law. Ultimately, we agree with the district court that Plaintiffs failed to show that Cox's tying arrangement foreclosed a substantial volume of commerce in the tied-product market, and therefore the tie did not merit per se condemnation. Because we agree with the district court on the foreclosure element, we affirm.
We review de novo a district court's ruling on a Rule 50(b) motion, drawing all reasonable inferences in favor of the nonmoving party and applying the same standard as applied in the district court. Lantec, Inc. v. Novell, Inc., 306 F.3d 1003, 1023 (10th Cir. 2002). The standard of review for Rule 50 motions "mirrors the standard" for summary-judgment motions under Rule 56(c). Farthing v. City of Shawnee, 39 F.3d 1131, 1139 n.10 (10th Cir. 1994) (quoting Anderson v. Liberty Lobby, Inc., 477 U.S. 242, 250, 106 S.Ct. 2505, 91 L.Ed.2d 202 (1986)). Under Rule 50(b), the district court may allow judgment on the jury's verdict, order a new trial, or enter judgment as a matter of law for the moving party. We may grant judgment as a matter of law only when "a party has been fully heard on an issue during a jury trial and the court finds that a reasonable jury would not have a legally sufficient evidentiary basis to find for the party on that issue." Fed. R. Civ. P. 50(a)(1). In other words, "[j]udgment as a matter of law is appropriate only if the evidence points but one way and is susceptible to no reasonable inferences which may support the nonmoving party's position." Auraria Student Hous. at the Regency, LLC v. Campus Vill. Apartments, 843 F.3d 1225, 1247 (10th Cir. 2016) (quoting Elm Ridge Expl. Co. v. Engle, 721 F.3d 1199, 1216 (10th Cir. 2013)).
Considering its expansive reach, the Sherman Act contains remarkably little text and hasn't been amended since it was enacted in 1890. Thus, antitrust law's various doctrines are almost entirely judge-made; courts have created these doctrines based on their own interpretations of the Sherman Act's statutory language and background. For this reason, the statute's limited language goes only so far, and theory must fill in the gaps. So to understand how and why tying arrangements came to be condemned by antitrust law, we must dive into their theoretical underpinnings.
A tie exists when a seller exploits its control in one product market to force buyers in a second market into purchasing a tied product that the buyer either didn't want or wanted to purchase elsewhere. Jefferson Par. Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2, 12, 104 S.Ct. 1551, 80 L.Ed.2d 2 (1984), abrogated on other grounds by Ill. Tool Works Inc. v. Indep. Ink, Inc., 547 U.S. 28, 126 S.Ct. 1281, 164 L.Ed.2d 26 (2006). For example, "[a] supermarket that will sell flour to consumers only if they will also buy sugar is engaged in tying. Flour is referred to as the tying product, sugar as the tied product." Id. at 33, 104 S.Ct. 1551 (O'Connor, J., concurring). Courts typically apply a per se rule to tying claims.
Early in the Sherman Act's history, the Supreme Court decided that "tying" two products together disrupted the natural functioning of the markets and violated antitrust law. See Int'l Salt, 332 U.S. at 396, 68 S.Ct. 12. It analyzed tying claims under the per se rule: if a plaintiff could show that a tying arrangement existed, the tie was illegal per se. Id. But the way courts view ties has evolved substantially since tying arrangements first attracted attention in antitrust law. Thus, today's per se rule against tying is dramatically more nuanced than the typical per se rule. See Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 1720a (explaining the per se tying rule's multitude of deviations from typical per se rule application). Though the typical antitrust per se rule requires no analysis of market conditions or effects, the Supreme Court has declared that the per se rule for tying arrangements demands a showing that the tie creates "a substantial potential for impact on competition." Jefferson Par., 466 U.S. at 16, 104 S.Ct. 1551. Today's plaintiffs must therefore do more than show that a tie exists to trigger the application of the per se rule; they must also meet certain threshold requirements — including that the tie had the substantial potential to
From the Supreme Court's tying cases, circuit courts have pulled several elements needed to prove per se tying claims, though these elements differ across the circuits. To succeed on a per se tying claim in the Tenth Circuit, a plaintiff must show that "(1) two separate products are involved; (2) the sale or agreement to sell one product is conditioned on the purchase of the other; (3) the seller has sufficient economic power in the tying product market to enable it to restrain trade in the tied product market; and (4) a `not insubstantial' amount of interstate commerce in the tied product is affected." Suture Express, Inc. v. Owens & Minor Distrib., Inc., 851 F.3d 1029, 1037 (10th Cir. 2017) (quoting Sports Racing Servs., Inc. v. Sports Car Club of Am., Inc., 131 F.3d 874, 886 (10th Cir. 1997)).
If a plaintiff fails to prove an element, the court will not apply the per se rule to the tie, but then may choose to analyze the merits of the claim under the rule of reason. See Fortner Enters, Inc. v. U.S. Steel Corp., 394 U.S. 495, 500, 89 S.Ct. 1252, 22 L.Ed.2d 495 (1969) (explaining that failure to satisfy per se requirements isn't always fatal to a tying claim and that a plaintiff "can still prevail on the merits whenever he can prove, on the basis of a more thorough examination of the purposes and effects of the practices involved, that the general standards of the Sherman Act have been violated"). The fight in this case is over the fourth element. Plaintiffs claim that "this element only requires consideration of the gross volume of commerce affected by the tie," and that they "met this requirement by the undisputed evidence that Cox obtained over $200 million in revenues from renting [set-top boxes] during the class period." Appellants' Opening Br. at 29. In other words, Plaintiffs would have us infer that because Cox makes a substantial amount of money on set-top-box rentals, the tie necessarily has the requisite potential for anticompetitive effects in the set-top-box market. But both Cox and the district court maintain that this element requires a showing that the tie actually foreclosed some amount of commerce, or some current or potential competitor, in the market for set-top boxes.
Plaintiffs' argument reflects an outdated view of the law. As we explain below, recent developments in the way courts treat tying arrangements validate the district court's order and support Cox's interpretation of tying law's foreclosure element.
Two Supreme Court cases, Jefferson Parish and Fortner Enterprises, establish that proof of foreclosure is necessary to prove a per se tying claim. But when the Supreme Court first addressed tying arrangements, it concluded that they served "hardly any purpose beyond the suppression of competition." E.g., Standard Oil Co. of Cal. v. United States, 337 U.S. 293, 305, 69 S.Ct. 1051, 93 S.Ct. 1371 (1949). At that time, the Court placed tying arrangements in the class of "agreements or practices which because of their pernicious effect on competition and lack of any redeeming virtue are conclusively presumed to be unreasonable and therefore illegal without elaborate inquiry as to the precise harm they have caused or the business excuse for their use." N. Pac. Ry. Co. v. United States, 356 U.S. 1, 5, 78 S.Ct. 514, 2 L.Ed.2d 545 (1958). Still, even at this early juncture, the Court seemed to recognize that, unlike price-fixing and market division between competitors, "there is
This case primarily concerns the foreclosure element of tying claims, which stems from Fortner. In Fortner, the Supreme Court stated that "[t]he requirement that a `not insubstantial' amount of commerce be involved makes no reference to the scope of any particular market or to the share of that market foreclosed by the tie." 394 U.S. at 501, 89 S.Ct. 1252. But the Court then clarified that "normally the controlling consideration is simply whether a total amount of business, substantial enough in terms of dollar-volume so as not to be merely de minimis, is foreclosed to competitors by the tie." Id. To reach this holding, the Court relied on an earlier case in which it stated that "it is `unreasonable, per se, to foreclose competitors from any substantial market' by a tying arrangement." Id. (quoting Int'l Salt, 332 U.S. at 396, 68 S.Ct. 12).
After Fortner, the Court again addressed tying claims in Jefferson Parish. There, the Court modified its view of tying arrangements. It explained that the rule prohibiting ties aims to prevent sellers from using their power in one market to gain control in a separate market. 466 U.S. at 12, 104 S.Ct. 1551. It also emphasized that antitrust law protects competition, not competitors or even consumer choice or price. Id. at 14-15, 104 S.Ct. 1551. As the Court stated,
Id. (footnote and citations omitted); see also Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 1726c ("Interference with customer choice is not itself the concern of tying law; rather, the relevant interference is the one that results from an anticompetitive effect in the tied market — namely, from the threat of increased concentration, higher prices, or perhaps an increase in the social costs of preexisting power in the tying market."). Thus, the Court realized "that every refusal to sell two products separately cannot be said to restrain competition." Jefferson Par., 466 U.S. at 11, 104 S.Ct. 1551.
Attempting to screen out tying arrangements that posed no danger to competition, the Jefferson Parish Court enumerated several threshold requirements necessary to trigger application of the per se rule against tying. From these requirements, circuit courts have shaped the elements
So, as outlined above, Jefferson Parish modified Fortner. And most recently, the Supreme Court modified the law even further by prohibiting courts from inferring market power over the tying product from a seller's patent on that product. Ill. Tool Works Inc., 547 U.S. at 31, 126 S.Ct. 1281. Though that decision isn't factually relevant to our case and bears on a different element, it signifies that "[o]ver the years,... [the Supreme] Court's strong disapproval of tying arrangements has substantially diminished." Id. at 35, 126 S.Ct. 1281. This attitude is on display in Jefferson Parish, where the Court stated without qualification that "we have refused to condemn tying arrangements unless a substantial volume of commerce is foreclosed thereby." 466 U.S. at 16, 104 S.Ct. 1551.
So, even if tying plaintiffs show that a tie affected a substantial dollar volume of sales, they must still show that the tie meets Jefferson Parish's threshold requirements to trigger the per se rule. In other words, the tying arrangement must be the type of tie that could potentially harm competition in the tied-product market. If "no portion of the market which would otherwise have been available to other sellers has been foreclosed," then no amount of tied sales could cross the threshold to per se condemnation. Id.; Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 1721d (explaining that if there are no rival sellers of the tied product or if the buyer would not have bought the tied product even from a different seller, then, "[n]otwithstanding a substantial dollar volume of sales ... the foreclosure is zero and therefore fails to cross the per se `threshold.'" (quoting Jefferson Par., 466 U.S. at 16, 104 S.Ct. 1551)). Thus, though the per se rule against tying doesn't require an exhaustive analysis into a tie's anticompetitive effects in the tied product market, the rule "can be coherent only if tying is defined by reference to the economic effect of the arrangement." Jefferson Par., 466 U.S. at 21 n.33, 104 S.Ct. 1551.
Circuit courts have undergone a similar theoretical shift. They first picked up on the peculiar nature of tying claims in Coniglio v. Highwood Servs., Inc., 495 F.2d 1286, 1292 (2d Cir.), cert. denied, 419 U.S. 1022,
Other circuits have since taken up this mantle — some have done so explicitly and others implicitly. See Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 1722a (listing circuits requiring anticompetitive effects to succeed on tying claims). The Fifth Circuit explicitly required Coniglio's anticompetitive effects in Driskill v. Dallas Cowboys Football Club, Inc., 498 F.2d 321, 323 (5th Cir. 1974), in which a Dallas Cowboys fan brought the exact same claim as the plaintiff in Coniglio. The Eleventh Circuit then cited Driskill in granting summary judgment to a condominium vendor that required condominium buyers to lease individual interest in common areas. Commodore Plaza at Century 21 Condo. Ass'n v. Saul J. Morgan Enters., Inc., 746 F.2d 671, 672 (11th Cir.), cert. denied, 467 U.S. 1241, 104 S.Ct. 3512, 82 L.Ed.2d 820 (1984). The court stated, "In this case, as in Driskill, the plaintiffs failed to make any showing of coercion or anticompetitive effects." Id.
Building on this growing trend, the First Circuit has stated that tying claims "must fail absent any proof of anti-competitive effects in the market for the tied product." Wells Real Estate, Inc. v. Greater Lowell Bd. of Realtors, 850 F.2d 803, 815 (1st Cir.), cert. denied, 488 U.S. 955, 109 S.Ct. 392, 102 L.Ed.2d 381 (1988). The court moderated this holding, stating that plaintiffs need not prove "the actual scope of anti-competitive effects in the market," but ultimately adopted Jefferson Parish's reasoning in stating that "as a matter of practical inferential common sense," the plaintiff had to "make some minimal showing of real or potential foreclosed commerce caused by the tie." Id. at 815 n.11.
Similarly, the Seventh Circuit has declined to apply the per se rule to condemn ties that pose no danger to competition. See Ohio-Sealy Mattress Mfg. Co. v. Sealy, Inc., 585 F.2d 821 (7th Cir.1978), cert. denied, 440 U.S. 930, 99 S.Ct. 1267, 59 L.Ed.2d 486 (1979). In Ohio-Sealy, the court acknowledged that it was "not free to inquire whether such tying in any given case injures market competition," but still stated that "if a given tying arrangement has no potential to foreclose access to the tied product market, it does not exemplify the vice that led the [Supreme] Court to declare tying a [p]er se [o]ffense." Id. at 835.
So, like the Supreme Court, the circuit courts generally recognize that a tie should not be condemned under the per se rule unless it has the potential to harm competition.
Similarly, we have acknowledged that even under a per se rule, we must at least make a threshold determination of potential harm to competition before we can condemn a tying arrangement under the Sherman Act. In Fox Motors, Inc. v. Mazda Distributors (Gulf), Inc., 806 F.2d 953, 955 (10th Cir. 1986), we integrated this caveat to the per se rule into the fourth element of a per se tying claim. There, a company that imported Mazda cars and distributed them to car dealerships refused to sell the dealerships a popular car model, the RX-7, unless the dealers sold a sufficient amount of the less-popular car model, the GLC. Id. at 955-56. The dealerships sued, alleging that the distributor's allocation method constituted a per se illegal tie under § 1 of the Sherman Act. Id. at 956. While acknowledging that the Supreme Court has deemed certain tying arrangements illegal per se, we specified that tying arrangements pose no risk of foreclosing competition in the tied-product market unless certain elements are present. See id. at 957.
Specifically, we held that tying arrangements must "foreclose to competitors of the tied market a `not insubstantial' volume of commerce." Id. at 957 (emphasis added) (quoting Fortner, 394 U.S. at 499, 89 S.Ct. 1252). In Fox Motors, "[t]he record contain[ed] no indication that the alleged tying arrangement, as distinct from consumer demand, influenced the level" of competition in the tied-product market. Id. at 958. Therefore, even though proof of anticompetitive effects was not an explicit element of tying claims in the Tenth Circuit, we still concluded that the tying arrangement "simply [did] not imply a sufficiently great likelihood of anticompetitive effect." Id. Because the tie failed to foreclose any competing car manufacturers, it didn't meet Jefferson Parish's threshold requirements for per se treatment. Id. Thus, we incorporated proof of actual or likely anticompetitive effect into the foreclosure element of tying claims. In doing so, we heeded Jefferson Parish's warning that some tying arrangements simply don't pose the same level of risk as those behaviors whose potential to harm competition is so pronounced as to deserve per se condemnation without regard to their actual impact on the market.
Courts have also acknowledged that some industries or products are sufficiently distinct that per se treatment is inappropriate. This is especially true in the world of technology, where courts are often unfamiliar with the products and market structure, and thus can't be certain of the potential for anticompetitive effects.
Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Tech. Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451, 486-87, 112 S.Ct. 2072, 119 L.Ed.2d 265 (1992) (Scalia, J., dissenting). The D.C. Circuit applied this principle in United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34 (D.C. Cir. 2001). Though the factual circumstances of that case are quite different from our own, we find the D.C. Circuit's reliance on Eastman Kodak and Jefferson Parish illuminating. There, the court faced a novel tying arrangement in which Microsoft had integrated the internet web browser, Internet Explorer, into Windows, its computer operating system. Id. at 45. Noting that some business relationships "represent entire, novel categories
A recent Second Circuit case, Kaufman v. Time Warner, 836 F.3d 137 (2d Cir. 2016), builds on Microsoft and is even more relevant to our analysis because it concerns the same tie by a different cable company. Similar to our case, the plaintiffs were a class of Time Warner Cable subscribers who were forced to rent set-top boxes to receive premium cable services. Though tying claims in the Second Circuit differ from ours by explicitly requiring a showing of anticompetitive effects in the tied-product market, the court's analysis in Kaufman is still very useful. See id. at 141. The court thoroughly explained the technology behind premium cable and set-top boxes and demonstrated why the tying arrangement at issue didn't trigger the application of the per se rule.
To start, the court explained that cable providers sell their subscribers the right to view certain packages of programming. Id. at 144. But the content creators — companies like HBO that produce television shows — require the cable companies to prevent viewers from stealing their content. Id. Set-top boxes solve this problem — cable providers "code their signals to prevent theft," and cable boxes receive the providers' coded signals and "unscramble" them. Id. "Unsurprisingly, providers do not share their codes with cable box manufacturers.... Therefore, to be useful to a consumer, a cable box must be cable-provider specific, like the keys to a padlock." Id.
After explaining the function of set-top boxes, the Second Circuit turned to the regulatory environment and the history of the cable industry's use of set-top boxes. Significantly, the court pointed out that "[a]ntitrust analysis must always be attuned to the particular structure and circumstances of the industry at issue" because "the existence of a regulatory structure designed to ... perform[] the antitrust function" might "diminish[] the likelihood of major antitrust harm." Id. at 145 (second and third alterations in original) (quoting Verizon Commc'ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 411-12, 124 S.Ct. 872, 157 L.Ed.2d 823 (2004)). The court described the Federal Communication Commission's ("FCC") attempts over the past twenty years to disaggregate set-top boxes from the delivery of premium cable, and stated that the FCC's failure is at least partly attributable to shortcomings in the new technologies designed to make premium cable available without set-top boxes. See id. at 146 ("[A] new approach that would work with two-way services [failed because it] was not sophisticated enough to
The court also pointed out that one FCC regulation actually caps the price that cable providers can charge customers who rent set-top boxes.
In sum, it is now clear that before applying the per se rule to tying arrangements, courts must carefully analyze the tie to ensure that it meets Jefferson Parish's threshold requirements. If it does not, the court may further analyze the tie using the rule of reason to determine whether it actually harms or threatens to harm competition.
This case comes down to what it means to foreclose a "not insubstantial" volume of commerce. As we discussed, a per se tying claim has four elements, and we have concluded that the fourth element — foreclosure — requires proof of actual or potential anticompetitive effects in the tied-product market. Based on the Supreme Court's tying cases and our own precedent, Plaintiffs failed to show that the tie had the substantial potential to foreclose competition. See Jefferson Par., 466 U.S. at 15-16, 104 S.Ct. 1551; Fox Motors, 806 F.2d at 957-58.
The jury found that Plaintiffs had met their burden of showing that Cox's tie had foreclosed a substantial amount of commerce in the set-top-box market. The jury-verdict form asked, "Has the alleged tying arrangement foreclosed a substantial volume of commerce in the Oklahoma City subsystem to other sellers or potential sellers of set-top boxes in the market for set-top boxes?" Joint App. vol. III at 614. The jury circled "Yes." Id. But a careful review of the record in light of post-Jefferson Parish law reveals that the record does not support the jury's conclusion. Rather, just as the district court found, Cox's tie didn't foreclose any commerce, nor did it prevent or even discourage other competitors from entering the market. Therefore, Cox's tie didn't meet the foreclosure element's threshold requirements necessary to trigger the per se rule against tying.
Plaintiffs vehemently argue that they presented enough evidence to show that Cox's tie affected a substantial volume of commerce. But before we can reach the evidence, we must address Plaintiffs' claim that the law and the foreclosure-of-commerce
The jury instruction on the foreclosure-of-commerce element, Jury Instruction 19, contained two paragraphs:
Joint App. vol. III at 601 (emphasis added). Upon Cox's renewed Rule 50(b) motion, the district court concluded that Plaintiffs had failed to prove the foreclosure element of their tying claim because "Plaintiff[s] failed to offer evidence from which a jury could determine that any other manufacturer wished to sell set-top boxes at retail or that Cox had acted in a manner to prevent any other manufacturer from selling set-top boxes at retail." In re Cox Enters., 2015 WL 7076418, at *1.
Plaintiffs contend that nothing in the jury instructions required them to offer such evidence. Instead, they seize upon the last sentence of the jury instruction, arguing that to prevail on the foreclosure element, they needed to show only that Cox made a substantial amount of money on its set-top-box leases. We acknowledge that reading the last sentence in isolation could lead a jury to believe that plaintiffs met the foreclosure element just by showing that the defendant made a substantial amount of money on the tied product. But, though inartfully drawn, the instruction must be read as a whole.
When read in context, the first paragraph of Jury Instruction 19 restricts the meaning of its last sentence. The dollar amount of Cox's set-top-box leases that is relevant to the foreclosure element must have been achieved by the tie. This is important — the foreclosure must result from the tie itself, not from any other anticompetitive conduct (which would be a different claim altogether), or from any external factors unrelated to the tie. But the total dollar amount of the leases doesn't matter if Cox's tie wasn't the reason its customers leased set-top boxes from Cox. In other words, Jury Instruction 19 properly explains that making money from a tying arrangement doesn't violate § 1 of the Sherman Act unless the defendant, by doing so, has actually or potentially foreclosed or injured competition in the tied-product market.
This interpretation of the jury instruction accords with the Supreme Court's tying-law precedent. See Jefferson Par., 466 U.S. at 15-16, 104 S.Ct. 1551 ("Per se condemnation — condemnation without inquiry into actual market conditions — is only appropriate if the existence of forcing is probable. Thus, application of the per se rule focuses on the probability of anticompetitive consequences. Of course, as a threshold matter there must be a substantial potential for impact on competition in order to justify per se condemnation."). It also accords with our own tying-law precedent. See Fox Motors, 806 F.2d at 959 (declining to condemn the alleged tying arrangement because it didn't foreclose competing manufacturers and therefore "cannot be characterized as a tying arrangement of the kind presumptively condemned under the antitrust laws").
As we discussed above, the question of whether to apply the per se rule to tying claims has become increasingly complex as courts have begun to question whether tying arrangements actually deserve per se condemnation. See Ill. Tool Works, 547 U.S. at 35, 126 S.Ct. 1281 (noting that "strong disapproval of tying arrangements has substantially diminished"); Jefferson Par., 466 U.S. at 35, 104 S.Ct. 1551 (O'Connor, J., concurring) ("The time has... come to abandon the `per se' label and refocus the inquiry on the adverse economic effects, and the potential economic
Turning to the district court's order granting Cox's Rule 50(b) motion, the district court found that Cox hadn't foreclosed any commerce because, through no fault of Cox's, no manufacturers sold or even wanted to sell set-top boxes directly to consumers. In re Cox Enters., 2015 WL 7076418, at *1. Plaintiffs argue that they presented more than enough evidence to show that the lack of competition in the set-top-box market resulted from Cox's tying arrangement. We acknowledge that we must not disregard the jury's verdict. But in light of our analysis of the foreclosure element, we agree with the district court that Plaintiffs failed to present evidence sufficient to show that Cox's alleged tie foreclosed a substantial volume of commerce in the market for set-top boxes. In other words, "the evidence points but one way and is susceptible to no reasonable inferences which may support [Plaintiffs'] position." Auraria Student Hous., 843 F.3d at 1247 (quoting Elm Ridge Expl. Co., 721 F.3d at 1216). We therefore conclude that the tie did not trigger the application of the per se rule.
Similar to Fox Motors and Microsoft, our case simply doesn't merit per se condemnation. Four factors support our conclusion. First, Cox was an intermediary between set-top-box manufacturers and cable customers. Second, Cox had no competitors in the set-top-box market. Third, all cable companies similarly tie premium cable services to set-top-box rentals, suggesting that net efficiencies and technological constraints — rather than desire to gain monopoly power in the tied-product market — necessitated the tie. Finally, the FCC's regulatory involvement in set-top boxes further diminishes the possibility that Cox's tie could harm competition in that market.
We begin with the significant fact that Cox does not manufacture the set-top boxes that it rents to customers. On appeal, Plaintiffs completely failed to address this unique market structure. Cox acts as an intermediary between the set-top-box manufacturers and the consumers that use them. That Cox purchases the boxes from manufacturers — and does not make the boxes itself — means that what it later does with the boxes has little or no effect on competition between set-top-box manufacturers in the set-top-box market. See Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 1709e4 (when sellers simply buy a product from existing manufacturers and resell them to tied customers at a profit, "the tie neither limits the marketing opportunities of the several manufacturers of the second product nor impairs the vitality of competition in their market. Each of those manufacturers remains free to compete for the patronage or blessing of the tying defendant....").
In fact, competition in the set-top-box market might continue to be robust because set-top-box manufacturers must continue to innovate and compete with each other to maintain their status as the preferred manufacturer for as many cable
Though the risk of foreclosing competition increases when the seller's customers — here, Cox's premium cable subscribers — are the only purchasers of the tied product, the risk is offset in this case because if they chose to, set-top-box manufacturers could sell their wares directly to cable customers. But none do. If enough customers demanded to buy set-top boxes or set-top-box alternatives directly from manufacturers, the manufacturers could have chosen to sell them directly; Cox's tie did not preclude them from doing so. In fact, Cox presented testimony from the executives of several set-top-box manufacturers confirming that Cox had no impact on their decisions not to sell set-top boxes at retail or directly to consumers.
Second, that no manufacturers chose to sell their products to consumers, either directly or at retail, means that Cox has no existing rivals in the set-top-box market (as the district court pointed out). Though Plaintiffs maintain that they don't need to prove the existence of any competitors in the tied-product market, they allege that Cox's tie likely caused the lack of competitors in the set-top-box market. Even if Cox had created an effective tie — and it very well might have done so — the lack of competitors in the set-top-box market doesn't prove that the tie foreclosed commerce or harmed competition in that market.
Plaintiffs alternatively argue that numerous actual and potential competitors existed in the retail market for set-top boxes. To support their claim, Plaintiffs point to evidence that many manufacturers were certified to offer CableCard-enabled products at retail. But in doing so, Plaintiffs again ignore that representatives of these manufacturers testified that they chose not to sell their set-top boxes at retail for reasons unrelated to Cox's tie. Plaintiffs also argue that TiVo wanted to sell a set-top box at retail but couldn't move forward with this plan due to a falsely manufactured "indemnification issue" on Cox's part. Appellant's Opening Br. at 25.
But contrary to Plaintiffs' contention, the record suggests instead that both Cox and TiVo thought their first attempt at TiVo boxes that integrated Cox's premium cable services operated too slowly to offer to customers, and that after the indemnification issue stalled their second project (which was not close to completion in any case), Cox and TiVo moved on to a third initiative to continue trying to make TiVo's box compatible with Cox's premium cable services. Finally, Plaintiffs point out that many other manufacturers were interested in the set-top-box market, and that a few companies offered Tru2Way products for sale at retail. But Plaintiffs failed to show that Cox's tie, as opposed to consumer choice, defeated these products or kept their manufacturers from selling them.
So here, we have no foreclosure, and zero-foreclosure ties present no antitrust concerns. See Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 1723a ("When there are no rival sellers of the tied product, then the alleged tie might affect a substantial volume of commerce in the tied product and yet not foreclose anyone."). Because set-top-box manufacturers choose not to sell set-top boxes at retail or directly to consumers, "no rival in the tied market could be foreclosed by" Cox's tie, and therefore "the
Plaintiffs contend that the zero-foreclosure rule applies only where consumers don't want the tied product or where no other seller is capable of selling the tied product for reasons unrelated to the tie. This argument misreads the case law. Though some courts have found that no rival sellers exist when no other sellers are capable of selling the tied product, see Coniglio, 495 F.2d at 1291, nowhere did those courts state that this was the only occasion where the lack of rival sellers would excuse a tie. Here, the record shows that Cox's tie didn't cause the lack of competitors in the set-top-box market because several manufacturers testified that Cox's actions had no impact on their decision to enter the retail market. This removes the tie from the category of tying claims deserving per se condemnation.
Third, as the D.C. Circuit found so significant in Microsoft, all cable companies rent set-top boxes to consumers. See Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 86; see also Kaufman, 836 F.3d at 144 ("[T]he Complaint lacks any allegation that there have ever been separate sales of set-top boxes and cable services ... in the United States, even in markets where cable providers face competition...."). This suggests that tying set-top-box rentals to premium cable is simply more efficient than offering them separately. Microsoft, 253 F.3d at 88 ("[B]undling by all competitive firms implies strong net efficiencies."); see also Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 1729e2 ("[T]he most likely inference to be drawn from similar ties imposed by each firm in a market, whether concentrated or unconcentrated, is that competition rather than oligopoly has forced the tie."). Here, technology requirements dictate that consumers rent or buy set-top boxes to receive all of Cox's services. See Kaufman, 836 F.3d at 144 ("A cable box must be designed to receive the signal from a particular provider, which requires the provider's cooperation. And because providers code their signals to prevent theft, a cable box must also be able to unscramble the coded signal of the particular provider."). Plaintiffs point out that efficiency and technology aren't the only reasons for Cox's tying arrangement, because cable companies make a hefty profit on set-top-box rentals. But the mere fact that Cox profited from set-top-box rentals doesn't justify applying the per se rule. See Carl Sandburg, 758 F.2d at 208 ("[P]laintiff does not establish the requisite economic interest in the tied product market merely by alleging that the tying seller is receiving a profit from the transaction as a whole."). Tying law is concerned with protecting competition; "high prices standing alone are not the evil that antitrust tying law condemns." Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 1724a.
Still, Plaintiffs also suggest that this profit-making potential drove Cox to propagate its tie by refusing to support technologies that allowed or would allow customers to access Cox's services without renting set-top boxes from Cox. Even if such support was required,
Moreover, when Tru2Way became available, Cox told customers in its annual notice that it was preparing to support, and then in a later notice that it did support, the technology. Plaintiffs fault Cox for hiding that information in brochures that no one reads, but we decline to hold Cox liable under the Sherman Act simply because customers failed to read Cox's annual published statements. Moreover, Cox has no duty to support new technology by affirmatively pushing it on consumers. See Christy Sports, 555 F.3d at 1197. Accepting that the CableCard and Tru2Way technologies — along with the televisions or TiVo boxes customers needed to use those technologies — qualified as substitutes for set-top boxes, we still could not say that Cox's tie had any detrimental effect on their vitality. Consumers were free to pursue those technologies instead of renting set-top boxes from Cox, but even the FCC concluded that they failed for reasons unrelated to cable companies' tying arrangements. See 81 Fed. Reg. at 14,033.
Plaintiffs also point to evidence that Cox refused to support one customer who had purchased a set-top box on eBay. Their argument assumes that in doing so, Cox foreclosed what could have been a thriving, second-hand set-top-box market by refusing to provide cable to customers who purchased their set-top boxes from such marketplaces. We agree with Plaintiffs that this refusal implicates the concern of tying law: that by refusing to support a customer who actually did purchase a set-top box from someone other than Cox, the cable company used its monopoly power in the premier cable market to foreclose competition in the set-top-box market. But Cox, in turn, presented compelling evidence justifying its refusal. Based on Cox's experience and knowledge, no set-top box
Fourth, the regulatory environment of the cable industry precludes the possibility that Cox could harm competition with its tie.
Plaintiffs do not contest the goals of antitrust tying law. Indeed, the fatal flaw in their argument is that it elevates form over function and fails to acknowledge the reasoning behind the Supreme Court's threshold requirements for triggering the per se rule against tying. Instead of explaining why the tie is dangerous despite Cox's lack of competitors in the set-top-box market, Plaintiffs insist that they need to show only that set-top-box rentals accounted for a substantial dollar amount. They insist that the "tying arrangement[] [is] illegal in and of [itself], without any requirement that the plaintiff make a showing of unreasonable competitive effect." Foremost Pro Color, Inc. v. Eastman, Kodak Co., 703 F.2d 534, 540 (9th Cir. 1983), overruling recognized by Chroma Lighting v. GTE Prods. Corp., 111 F.3d 653 (9th Cir. 1997). They urge that we must presume anticompetitive effects based on nothing more than the dollar amount of Cox's set-top-box sales. See Digidyne Corp. v. Data Gen. Corp., 734 F.2d 1336, 1338 (9th Cir. 1984).
But as thoroughly discussed above, "the Supreme Court has continued to add more real-market analysis to the requirements of a per se tying claim." Suture Express, 851 F.3d at 1038. In doing so, it has informed us that not all ties threaten to harm competition such that they must be declared illegal per se. And here, Cox's tie has no potential to foreclose competition in the set-top-box market, and therefore fails to meet Jefferson Parish's threshold requirements
Plaintiffs also contend that the district court improperly applied the rule of reason to their claim instead of using a per se analysis. As discussed above, the per se analysis for tying arrangements differs from other types of per se antitrust claims because tying arrangements often pose no risk to competition. Because we conclude this tie falls outside the realm of the traditional per se analysis, the district court rightly refused to condemn Cox's tie as illegal per se. And we don't have to apply the rule of reason unless Plaintiffs also argued that the tie was unlawful under a rule of reason analysis. See Fox Motors, 806 F.2d at 959 n.3. Because Plaintiffs argued that tying arrangements must be analyzed under the per se rule, we need not address whether Cox's tie would be illegal under a rule of reason analysis.
For the foregoing reasons, we affirm the district court's order granting Cox judgment as a matter of law under Rule 50(b).
BRISCOE, Circuit Judge, dissenting.
After a nine-day jury trial in this antitrust case, the district court instructed the jury as to the elements of a per se tying claim. Those instructions correctly stated the law. The jury found for plaintiffs on each element and awarded $6.313 million in damages to the plaintiffs. The evidence presented at trial was sufficient to support the jury's conclusion on each element. Nevertheless, the district court granted the defendant's renewed motion for judgment as a matter of law, and the majority affirms that decision, vacating the jury's verdict.
I respectfully dissent. I would reverse the grant of judgment as a matter of law and reinstate the jury verdict against the defendant on the issue of liability. Were we to reach the issues raised by defendant in its cross-appeal, I would remand for a new trial as to damages under a package approach instruction.
According to the Supreme Court, the law is and always has been that "certain tying arrangements pose an unacceptable risk of stifling competition and therefore are unreasonable `per se.'"
In
Our first inquiry is whether the products in question are actually separate products that may be illegally tied. This question has also been framed by the Supreme Court as a question of whether "a substantial volume of commerce is foreclosed" by the tie.
This threshold question is necessary because "[i]f only a single purchaser were `forced' with respect to the purchase of a tied item, the resultant impact on competition would not be sufficient to warrant the concern of antitrust law."
According to the Supreme Court, "the answer to the question whether one or two products are involved turns not on the functional relation between them, but rather on the character of the demand for the two items."
Only once has the Supreme Court held that two products were not separate. "In
In addition, courts of appeals have found that tying arrangements are not deserving of per se condemnation when no other seller could potentially sell the product. These are cases in which the seller has a natural monopoly over both the tied and tying products.
Similarly, when the tied product is completely unwanted by the buyer such that no market exists for that product, there can be no per se illegal tying arrangement.
Although courts have framed this inquiry as several various elements of a tying claim, the essential inquiry is the same: Has the seller linked two distinct product markets in a way that could impair competition in the tied market? This is the threshold inquiry described by the Supreme Court in
When two separate products are tied, courts must next consider whether the seller has "sufficient economic power with respect to the tying product to appreciably restrain free competition in the market for the tied product."
The Supreme Court has instructed us to answer two questions: First, has the seller linked two separate product markets? Second, has the seller used its market power in the tying product market to coerce buyer behavior in the tied product market? Each Circuit, including ours, defines the elements of a tying claim slightly differently. We have required plaintiffs to show:
With that framework in mind, I turn to the evidence presented in this case. Because there is no small amount of disagreement as to what is meant by the Tenth Circuit's expression of the elements, and because the Tenth Circuit's expression of the test is presumptively within the bounds set by the Supreme Court, I will focus on the elements as the Supreme Court has described them. The evidence presented at trial was sufficient to support a jury finding that Cox linked the otherwise separate product markets for premium cable services
The evidence presented at trial was sufficient to support a jury finding that Cox conditioned the sale of Advanced TV services on rental of a set-top box from Cox. Throughout the relevant period, Cox's website stated: "In order to receive interactive TV services offered by Cox, such as the interactive programming guide, on-demand, pay-per-view, and all-digital programming options, you must rent a digital receiver."
Further, Colleen Langer, Vice President of Marketing for Cox, testified that the Cox website for ordering cable "would force you to say what type of box do you want." J.A. vol. XXVII, at 4014-15. When asked to elaborate, she stated:
This coercion was not limited to internet sales. Charles Wise, Vice President of Customer Care for Cox, testified that, when customers call for services, "[t]he service representative communicates to the customer that the services that they desire either require a DCR or require a Set-Top box for those advanced features, and then they're communicated to what the cost of the package is and what the cost of the equipment is."
This arrangement, conditioning the provision of premium cable services on the rental of a set-top box, will merit per se condemnation only if premium cable services and set-top boxes are two separate products from the perspective of buyers. They are.
As an initial matter, Cox stipulated that, based on the nature of consumer demand for premium cable services and set-top box rental, these were separate products.
First, there was evidence that other sellers did offer the products separately. Lawrence Harte testified as an expert witness for the plaintiffs and provided his conclusion that other cable companies did provide cable services separate from set-top box rental or purchase.
More directly to this point, there was an incident in which a customer acquired a Motorola set-top box on eBay and tried to use it to receive Cox Advanced TV services. Cox's response to that incident indicates that it was capable of connecting the box, but decided not to do so. On March 5, 2009, Christine Martin sent an e-mail describing a customer complaint. She stated:
J.A. vol. XXXVII, at 5000. In a reply e-mail to Christine Martin that same day, Delbert Biggs wrote:
Second, Cox charged customers separately for service and for set-top box rental. J.A. vol. LI, at 6326-27. And Cox viewed rental revenue and service revenue separately. J.A. vol. XLI, at 5328.
Third, there was evidence that set-top boxes are not fungible. Harte offered testimony about the various features that set-top boxes can include, such as "Netflix and
Because premium cable services and set-top boxes were sold separately by other sellers, could be sold separately by additional other sellers, were billed separately to buyers, and were not fungible, they were separate products, as Cox stipulated.
To the extent the majority concludes otherwise, it appears to do so on the basis that, as a technical matter, it does not believe that Advanced TV from Cox cannot be provided without a set-top box from Cox. For this conclusion, it relies upon factual findings from the Second Circuit in
Evidence supporting these findings presumably was presented to the court in
The majority concludes, "plaintiffs failed to show that Cox's tie, as opposed to consumer choice, defeated these products or kept their manufacturers from selling them." Maj. Op. at 1108. It asserts that "[i]f enough customers demanded to buy set-top boxes or set-top-box alternatives directly from manufacturers, the manufacturers could have chosen to sell them directly; Cox's tie did not preclude them from doing so."
The evidence presented to the jury was sufficient for it to conclude that premium cable services and set-top boxes were separate products from the perspective of buyers, and that this is not a case of "zero foreclosure" because other sellers were able to sell the products separately.
The plaintiffs also presented ample evidence that Cox controlled a substantial share of the market for video services in Oklahoma City. According to Cox's calculations, from the third quarter of 2009 to the third quarter of 2011, Cox controlled between 68% and 71.5% of the market for video services in Oklahoma City. J.A. vol. XLII, at 5375-76. Those calculations did not take into account "over-the-top" services Cox provides, which are streaming video services such as Hulu and Netflix, but Jennifer Rich, Director of Competitive Strategy for Cox, testified that only 1.5% of customers had "chosen over-the-top video instead of paid TV." J.A. vol. XXVII, at 4114. She also testified that 35% to 40% of Cox customers subscribed to over-the-top services in addition to cable services.
Satisfied that the evidence presented at trial was sufficient to support the jury verdict, I must make one additional point which perhaps explains why my views differ from those of the majority. When considering a motion for judgment as a matter of law, it is not our job to decide the case anew, but to uphold the jury verdict unless "the evidence points but one way and is susceptible to no reasonable inferences supporting the party for whom the jury found."
I respectfully dissent. I would reverse the grant of judgment as a matter of law, reinstate the jury's verdict on the issue of
Similarly, because we affirm the district court, we decline to address the issues that Cox raises in its cross-appeal. Specifically, Cox asked us to review Plaintiffs' failure to define a viable tying product, the proper geographic market for the tying product, and a valid theory of damages, as well as Plaintiffs' failure to address the impact of the National Cooperative Research and Production Act, whether certain class members should have been excluded from the claim, whether the "verdict in this case provides a permissible basis for awarding damages to the individual class members," and whether we must remand for a new trial "because the jury instructions did not accurately convey the essential elements of a tying claim." Appellee's Response Br. at 4.
As we explained above, the foreclosure element of a per se tying claim in our circuit requires a showing that the tie had the potential to or actually did harm competition in the tied-product market. Having "been fully heard on [the] issue ... there is no legally sufficient evidentiary basis for a reasonable jury to find for [Plaintiffs]" under the law. Fed. R. Civ. P. 50(a)(1). In other words, the record shows that Cox's tie was not the sole — or even the primary — reason that Plaintiffs couldn't purchase set-top boxes or their alternatives from other manufacturers. See In re Cox Enters., 2015 WL 7076418, at *1 ("Plaintiff[s] failed to offer evidence from which a jury could determine that any other manufacturer wished to sell set-top boxes at retail or that Cox had acted in a manner to prevent any other manufacturer from selling set-top boxes at retail."). Therefore, the tie didn't foreclose competition in the tied-product market and the district court properly granted Cox judgment as a matter of law under Rule 50(b).