PHILIP A. BRIMMER, District Judge.
The Court presided over a trial to the court from May 14 to May 24, 2012. The trial addressed one principal issue — whether the State of Colorado's limitation on per-signature compensation for petition circulators violates the First Amendment to the United States Constitution. The following constitute the Court's findings of fact and conclusions of law pursuant to Rule 52(a)(1) of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure.
Plaintiffs are petition circulators, non-profit organizations, and petition entities involved in the initiative and referendum process in the State of Colorado. They filed this 42 U.S.C. § 1983 action challenging the constitutionality of House Bill 09-1326 ("H.B. 1326"), which amends the rules and procedures pertaining to the initiative and referendum processes. On April 26, 2012, the Court granted defendant
The hybrid compensation scheme is codified at Colo.Rev.Stat. § 1-40-112(4) and states as follows: "It shall be unlawful for any person to pay a circulator more than twenty percent of his or her compensation for circulating petitions on a per signature or petition section basis." The statute does not restrict all compensation to circulators on a per-signature basis; however, as a practical matter, the twenty percent restriction limits per-signature compensation to bonuses or incentive payments. As a result, the statute requires that circulators receive the majority of their compensation in the form of hourly payments.
Plaintiffs claim that the hybrid scheme severely infringes their First Amendment rights to free speech because it decreases the pool of professional circulators who are necessary for any successful signature-gathering campaign. Plaintiffs also argue that the hybrid scheme increases the cost of signature-gathering efforts, making it more difficult to qualify measures for the statewide ballot. Finally, plaintiffs assert that there is no evidence that the hybrid scheme will reduce the rate or incidence of fraud in the initiative and referendum process. The Secretary responds that plaintiffs offer no proof that § 1-40-112(4) will actually reduce the number of available professional circulators or that the statute will increase the cost of signature-gathering efforts in Colorado.
The Court previously enjoined the Secretary from enforcing Colo.Rev.Stat. § 1-40-112(4), § 1-40-135, and § 1-40-121 to the extent that those sections applied to the hybrid scheme. See Docket No. 60 at 37. Evidence at the preliminary injunction hearing established that the statute would deter most professional circulators from working in Colorado and would raise the cost of qualifying a measure for statewide vote. The Court also found that the Secretary failed to establish that pay-per-signature compensation was connected to the likelihood of circulator fraud. Id. at 29-30.
The evidence and arguments presented at trial established the following:
The constitution of the State of Colorado permits its citizens to place propositions on the ballot through the initiative process. Colo. Const. Art. V, § 1. Proponents of a measure have two years to qualify an issue for the ballot, but may only propose Taxpayer's Bill of Rights
To qualify a measure, proponents must complete the statutorily mandated process as set forth in Colo.Rev.Stat. § 1-40-101 et seq. Proponents must first submit a draft of the proposed legislation to the Legislative Counsel Office for review and comment. Colo.Rev.Stat. § 1-40-105(1). Following a public hearing, the draft is submitted to the Title Board, to designates
The testimony from both sides established that the effect of § 1-40-112(4) is to raise the per-signature cost to a petition entity. The cost of running signature-gathering campaigns will increase because the hybrid scheme excludes some professional circulators from working in Colorado and makes the signature-gathering process significantly less efficient. The evidence, however, did not provide an easily determinable method to quantify that increase in costs.
At the preliminary injunction hearing, the Court found that petition entities
Jon Caldara, president of plaintiff The Independence Institute,
Kennedy Enterprises contracted with Lamm Consulting, a petition entity in Colorado, to gather signatures on the Healthcare Choice Measure. Scott Lamm, owner of Lamm Consulting, also testified that itinerant professionals were the first contacted to circulate that petition. Lamm relied on itinerant circulators because only seven and a half weeks remained to collect signatures after the Court enjoined § 1-40-112(4). In Lamm's words, the signature-gathering campaign had "no time to
The evidence at trial established that any campaign performed without professional circulators would likely spend additional time and resources training new circulators. Although proponents have six months to collect signatures in Colorado, testimony revealed that, due to legal challenges,
Edward Blaszak, who owns a pay-per-hour signature gathering firm in Oregon and has run pay-per-hour campaigns in other states, testified about the importance of well-trained petition circulators. Blaszak stated that the training he provides to new circulators allows them to become efficient circulators. For example, during a petition campaign, the first day at Blaszak's company includes intensive training sessions where circulators practice pitching a proposed measure to registered voters, role playing activities where circulators simulate actual conditions, and on-site training once new circulators are out in public. Moreover, Blaszak often retrains poorly performing circulators rather than terminating them so long as they continue to provide adequate effort.
Lamm, Kennedy, Blaszak, and William Huckins, one of Blaszak's circulators, testified that, although petition circulation is not a difficult concept to understand, it is not an easy task to master. Lamm opined that only one out of every ten individuals who attempts to circulate is ultimately successful, while Huckins testified that it took him a "week [to] two weeks" to acquire the necessary skills. Edward Agazarm, who has been involved in signature-gathering for 19 years, testified that new circulators are less productive because they have not acquired the skills necessary to identify eligible voters and collect a large number of signatures. Agazarm, Lamm, Blaszak, and Kennedy testified that nonprofessional circulators' lack of skills typically results in lower overall production and lower validity rates.
The evidence at trial established that § 1-40-112(4) would likely exclude some professional circulators (both itinerant professionals and low-volume professional circulators) from working in Colorado. The testimony demonstrated that itinerant professionals are driven primarily by their earning potential. Jacob Thaler and David Vaughn, two pay-per-signature itinerant professionals, testified that they would work in Colorado under § 1-40-112(4) if they could earn between $30 to $50 per hour. Jeffrey Zax, professor of economics at the University of Colorado, Boulder, testified that earning potential is an important criteria itinerant professionals consider when choosing signature-gathering campaigns.
Zax opined that itinerant professionals avoid working in pay-per-hour states such
Despite the theoretical plausibility of Zax's model,
The Court finds that the hybrid scheme will also eliminate low-volume professional circulators. Kennedy and Lamm testified that, because low-volume professional circulators collect only a few signatures during any given week, it would not be economically feasible to compensate these circulators with an hourly wage. Additionally, they testified that, because it is not feasible to pay low-volume professionals by the hour, the only alternative under the hybrid scheme would be to pay low-volume professional circulators 20¢ per signature. However, low-volume professional circulators would not find compensation of 20¢ per signature sufficient to continue signature-gathering activities. By contrast, Lamm and Kennedy testified that, under a pay-per-signature system, they can collect signatures from low-volume professional circulators without oversight because their low productivity (i.e. a net gain of five to fifteen signatures over the course of a week) garners the same compensation regardless of the length of time to collect. Kennedy and Lamm both testified that the constant flow of high-validity signatures from low-volume professional circulators can account for 20% of total signatures. These signatures are essential because the high validity rate decreases the burden of collecting "buffer" signatures.
Without access to the majority of itinerant professionals and low-volume professional circulators, petition entities will have to expend more resources training new circulators. In addition, petition entities will have to compensate circulators for more hours of work in order to generate the 20% of signatures usually provided by low-volume professional circulators. When time is of the essence, the necessarily greater reliance on new circulators under § 1-40-112(4) increases the likelihood of poor validity and thereby makes it more likely that a signature-gathering campaign will be unsuccessful.
The testimony at trial established that § 1-40-112(4) would significantly decrease the efficiency of signature-gathering campaigns. Lamm, Kennedy, and Albie Hurst, an employee of Lamm Consulting, testified that circulators in Colorado under their pay-per-signature models receive compensation only for the signatures they provide and are not compensated for training or travel time.
Kennedy testified that he has relatively low day-to-day expenses. He hires his daughters or temporary agency workers to perform office functions. On signature collection days, which happen twice a week, crew managers
Agazarm, who has participated in both pay-per-signature and pay-per-hour campaigns in the State of Oregon,
Arno, who has qualified more than 650 initiatives nationwide since 1979, testified that the cost of running a pay-per-hour drive can double the cost of a pay-per-signature campaign. Arno based this estimate on a pay-per-hour campaign he performed in Oregon after the passage of Measure 26. Arno testified that, under a pay-per-signature system, he could collect 140,000 signatures in Oregon at a rate of $1.55 per signature for a total of $217,000. However, in 2003, after the passage of Measure 26, he spent over $500,000 to collect the same number of signatures. In addition to the added costs identified by Agazarm and Kennedy, Arno testified that pay-per-hour campaigns increase costs because petition entities must hire additional field supervisors to counter shirking, pay overtime to circulators who work longer than 8 hours in a day without permission,
This testimony was consistent with Blaszak's experience conducting pay-per-hour campaigns. Blaszak testified that he compensates circulators for training and travel time and has field managers supervise circulators. Additionally, Blaszak testified that, in order to counter shirking, his circulators report signature totals twice daily. Blaszak provides bonuses in the form of movie tickets and pizza parties to increase production.
Zax acknowledged that a principal weakness of a pay-per-hour system is that circulators will attempt to shirk when given the opportunity. However, Zax opined that the 20¢ per signature incentive payment built into § 1-40-112(4) could effectively deter shirking. Zax also believed that itinerant professionals would not misrepresent their hours (i.e. collect 35 signatures in 30 minutes while reporting work for the whole hour) because petition entities and circulators could renegotiate contracts weekly if an itinerant professional's production exceeded compensation. Zax testified that the hybrid compensation model protects both itinerant circulators and petition entities from the vicissitudes of signature-gathering because itinerant professionals could potentially earn $28 per hour even when circulating in poor conditions (i.e. bad weather) and, on the other hand, petition entities would be underpaying circulators, compared to pay-per-signature compensation schemes, during periods of unusually high production.
The Secretary's argument about the flexibility and viability of the hybrid compensation scheme cannot survive careful consideration. From a theoretical perspective, there is no discernible difference between the use of a hybrid system and a pay-per-signature system. Under either system, the economic reality for itinerant professionals is that they would earn $35 for collecting 35 signatures in an hour. Moreover, although Zax argues that a hybrid system protects itinerant professionals against poor working conditions, the testimony from Arno, Kennedy, and Thaler established that itinerant professionals in a pay-per-signature system do not work in poor weather conditions. Thus, to the extent Zax's model anticipates protecting itinerant professionals from poor conditions, the testimony at trial established that this is an assurance that is not required and would not provide an incentive to attract itinerant professionals to the hybrid scheme described by Zax.
Second, the prospect of renegotiating a contract is insufficient motivation for itinerant professionals to counter shirking. Thaler and Vaughn, the two itinerant professionals at trial, testified that the prospect of providing free signatures to petition entities in exchange for future contract renegotiation was unappealing. Itinerant professionals earn on average $1 for every signature collected. Under Zax's hybrid model hypothetical, once itinerant professionals meet their negotiated signature threshold (i.e. 35 signatures in an hour), they have no incentive to gather additional signatures. As Blaszak testified, using a quota is more of a stick, meaning that circulators will work
The likely effect of the hybrid compensation scheme described by Zax is that it will not attract itinerant professionals and the lower training cost and higher productivity associated with them and, as a result, will not give petition entities the benefit that Zax noted of undercompensating such persons during periods of higher productivity.
The Court finds that Zax's hybrid model would significantly increase the costs of a signature-gathering campaign. Zax's model requires that petition entities provide hourly compensation to circulators for orientation, travel costs, and paid rest breaks which are not compensated under a pay-per-signature model. Petition entities will also have to provide additional compensation for crew managers who would have significantly greater supervisory responsibilities. Petition entities will likely have to collect signatures daily to ensure that new circulators gather an adequate number of signatures. These daily collections will increase costs in two ways: first, petition entities will have to secure the daily services of a notary; and second, petition entities will have to hire an employee to track circulator productivity and make a decision to either terminate employment, renegotiate the contract, or provide more training. Moreover, negotiating employment contracts on a frequent basis increases exposure to lawsuits for wrongful terminations, employment benefits, or other labor related claims.
Third, because the testimony indicated that only one out of ten new circulators develops into a professional circulator, petition entities will incur greater costs as they compensate unproductive circulators. For example, Blaszak testified that, even if a circulator provided only 10 signatures for a full 7-hour workday, the circulator would receive compensation of $70
Accordingly, the Court finds that the cumulative inefficiencies likely to occur as a result of § 1-40-112(4) will significantly increase the costs of running signature-gathering campaigns.
The testimony at trial did not establish whether circulators were currently employees or independent contractors under Colorado law.
The evidence at trial established that an increase in signature gathering costs is unlikely to have an effect on individuals or entities who can raise large sums to qualify a measure for the statewide ballot. However, the cost increase is likely to disproportionally impact individuals with limited resources by making measure qualification unaffordable. Caldara, Mason Tvert, and Jennifer Gratz testified that they had to suspend qualifying potential measures in 2010 because of the cost increase associated with § 1-40-112(4). Although the testimony at trial demonstrated that the per signature price is unlikely to increase to $5.50 because of § 1-40-112(4), the evidence established that the statute will likely raise prices from a baseline of $2.07 per signature to $2.50 per signature (18%) and possibly to more than $3 per signature.
Kennedy testified that he usually charges a proponent $2.07 per signature for unbundled petitions under a pay-per-signature model. See also Ex. B-43. On the other hand, Blaszak testified that he typically charges a proponent $5
In addition to raising the per-signature price of campaigns, § 1-40-112(4) deprives petition entities of the flexibility they currently enjoy when negotiating contracts. Arno, Kennedy, and Lamm testified that pay-per-signature entities can sometimes negotiate to pay circulators as little as 50¢ per signature in order to lower costs to proponents. Because overhead for petition entities under a pay-per-signature model is typically low, pay-per-signature entities can nevertheless make a profit despite significant decreases in contract prices. See Ex. A-5 at 5-6. The testimony showed that petition entities will not have this flexibility under a hybrid system as they will be forced to pass on their overhead costs to proponents in order to remain profitable.
Kathryn Mikeworth, the operations manager for the Colorado Secretary of State, testified about the signature verification process.
The Secretary's statement of sufficiency must indicate the number of signatures sampled and whether the number of valid signatures was less than 90% or less than 110%. See, e.g., Ex. 132 (Statement of Sufficiency). If the signatures provided by a proponent are insufficient, then the proponent can cure the deficiency by collecting additional valid signatures to meet the statutory threshold (76,047 valid signatures in 2008). "Cure" signatures must be provided to the Secretary no later than three months before the election is held.
The Secretary follows Rule 17.3 of the Colorado Secretary of State Election Rules to perform the line-by-line review of petition sections.
The testimony from both sides established that signature compensation schemes have no measurable impact on validity rates. Blaszak testified that his validity rate is usually around 72 to 74%,
Moreover, petition entities have an incentive to maintain high validity rates because failure to qualify an issue is detrimental to future business. For example, Lamm Consulting was replaced by another petition entity when it failed to qualify Tvert's marijuana initiative in 2010.
Finally, none of the evidence presented linked low validity rates to fraud or professional circulators. On the contrary, low validity rates were usually attributed to new circulators who did not have the skills necessary to ask the right questions. Blaszak testified that his casino initiative in Oregon failed in part because of the "condensed time-frame" in which to collect signatures and the overreliance on new circulators. In rare instances, the nature of the ballot initiative, by itself, can affect the validity rates. For example, Lamm attributed the failure of the marijuana initiative to the nature of the measure. Lamm and Hurst testified that overzealous signers of the marijuana initiative often lied about their age, whether they were registered voters, or whether they signed previous petition sections. Lamm and Hurst testified that the marijuana initiative had similar problems in Colorado in 2006 and in other states that have attempted to pass a similar measure. Accordingly, the evidence at trial established that invalid signatures are typically the result of inexperienced circulators or voter error, i.e. registered voters changing addresses without updating the voter registration card,
Ballot petition fraud is a crime in the State of Colorado. Colo.Rev.Stat. § 1-40-130. Examples of fraudulent circulator practices include forging signatures, misrepresenting
Mikeworth and Hillary Rudy, the senior legislative and policy analyst for the elections division of the Secretary of State's office, testified that, because of a lack of resources, the Secretary is unable to detect circulator fraud that occurs in the field, such as misrepresentation, surrogate fraud, false witnessing, and inducement. Rudy testified that the Secretary is also unable to detect forgeries when petition sections are reviewed because the temporary employees who are often hired to conduct validity checks do not have access to restricted SCORE databases.
The Secretary argues that pay-per-signature systems provide more of an incentive to commit fraud when compared to pay-per-hour systems or § 1-40-112(4)'s hybrid scheme. However, the evidence at trial actually proved the contrary, namely, that the incentive to commit fraud is likely stronger under a hybrid scheme when compared to a pay-per-signature system.
Huckins, Blaszak, and Zax testified that one of the benefits of working under an hourly wage system is the security of guaranteed compensation for the hours worked. Yet both Blaszak and Zax acknowledged that an employee getting below a certain number of signatures should eventually be terminated. Blaszak testified that he terminates employees who consistently fail to reach a minimum number of signatures. As Arno noted, the security of guaranteed compensation is undermined by the pressure to maintain a minimum level of production. As a result, the existence of a minimum number of signatures that an hourly employee must gather creates an incentive to commit fraud. For example, if at the end of a given workweek, a circulator employed under a hybrid system of compensation is several signatures short of her weekly quota and knows she faces termination if she does not reach the quota, that circulator has an incentive to fraudulently obtain the remaining signatures. Under this scenario, an underperforming circulator in a hybrid system faces a stark choice: either provide fraudulent signatures and retain employment, or miss the weekly quota and forgo future compensation. Moreover, it is difficult to detect these fraudulent "fill-in" signatures because the other signatures on the petition section are usually valid. Therefore, the circulator's validity rate remains high because of the small chance of sampling the "fill-in" signatures. Although a hybrid scheme may decrease the incentive to commit fraud because it guarantees compensation, it will act to encourage fraud by pressuring nonproductive circulators to meet daily or weekly quotas, whether those quotas are stated or not.
On the contrary, the incentive to commit fraud under a pay-per-signature system is the possibility of earning an extra dollar for every fraudulently collected signature. Circulators in pay-per-signature systems have no pressure to meet weekly quotas, are not at risk of losing their positions, and, in fact, pay-per-signature entities rely on low-volume professional circulators to
From a theoretical viewpoint, pay-per-hour signature gathering, rather than pay-per-signature gathering, incentivizes fraud. However, the evidence at trial of actual fraud was minimal and established that fraud occurs under both pay-per-hour
When plaintiffs challenge a State statute regulating the election process under the First Amendment, the court must first consider the "character and magnitude" of the burden the State's regulation imposes on plaintiffs' First Amendment rights and then weigh this burden against the precise interests the State contends justify the burden. Timmons v. Twin Cities Area New Party, 520 U.S. 351, 358, 117 S.Ct. 1364, 137 L.Ed.2d 589 (1997). Regulations imposing severe burdens on plaintiffs' rights are subject to strict scrutiny and must be narrowly tailored to advance a compelling State interest. Id. at 358-59, 117 S.Ct. 1364; see also Yes On Term Limits, Inc. v. Savage, 550 F.3d 1023, 1028 (10th Cir.2008) (noting that, to survive strict scrutiny, the State "has the burden
Generally, whether a regulation faces a balancing test or strict scrutiny depends on the severity of the burden the regulation places on speech. Lee, 463 F.3d at 768. Where a law appears on its face to regulate the initiative process, courts should engage in a searching inquiry to determine if, in regulating the process, a State has gone too far by instituting procedures which effectively limit underlying speech. Therefore, the essential consideration is how severe a burden a particular regulation effectively places on the underlying speech. See Timmons, 520 U.S. at 358, 117 S.Ct. 1364.
In Meyer v. Grant, 486 U.S. 414, 108 S.Ct. 1886, 100 L.Ed.2d 425 (1988), the Supreme Court observed that initiative petition circulation necessarily involved "both the expression of a desire for political change and a discussion of the merits of the proposed change." Id. at 421, 108 S.Ct. 1886. The Court explained that, because petition circulation involves the type of interactive communication concerning political change, it is appropriately described as "core political speech." Id. at 422, 108 S.Ct. 1886. The Court characterized Colorado's statute barring the use of paid circulators as "a limitation on political expression" and applied "exacting" scrutiny because the statute imposed an unacceptable burden on the exercise of First Amendment rights. Id. at 420-22, 108 S.Ct. 1886.
In Buckley v. Am. Constitutional Law Found., Inc., 525 U.S. 182, 119 S.Ct. 636, 142 L.Ed.2d 599 (1999), the Supreme Court addressed three different provisions of a Colorado ballot initiative statute which required that (1) circulators be registered voters, (2) circulators wear identification badges, and (3) proponents of an initiative report the names and addresses of all paid circulators and the amount paid to each circulator. Id. at 186, 119 S.Ct. 636. After describing petition circulation as core political speech, the Supreme Court explained that "`no litmus-paper test' will separate valid ballot-access provisions from invalid interactive speech restrictions; we have come upon `no substitute for the hard judgments that must be made.'" Id. at 192, 119 S.Ct. 636 (quoting Timmons, 520 U.S. at 359, 117 S.Ct. 1364). Without specifying whether these restrictions imposed a severe burden on speech necessitating strict scrutiny or a lesser test, the Court struck down each of the three restrictions. The Court found that the regulations discouraged participation in the petition circulation process, which limited the number of voices available to convey a proponent's message and cut down the size of the audience that could be reached. Id. at 194-95, 119 S.Ct. 636.
The reasoning employed by the Supreme Court in Buckley suggests that the level of scrutiny applicable in a case such as this depends on the extent to which the
Here, the Secretary contends that § 1-40-112(4) imposes an insignificant burden on speech and should be subject to a balancing test under Timmons. Plaintiffs, on the other hand, contend that § 1-40-112(4) is a severe burden on core political speech under Meyer and the statute should be subject to strict scrutiny.
Section 1-40-112(4) states that "[i]t shall be unlawful for any person to pay a circulator more than twenty percent of his or her compensation for circulating petitions on a per signature or petition section basis." Colo.Rev.Stat. § 1-40-112(4). Plaintiffs argue that the hybrid scheme reduces the pool of available circulators and increases the costs of running a signature-gathering campaign as it significantly decreases efficiency.
Courts faced with challenges to statutes similar to § 1-40-112(4) have reached different conclusions as to whether restrictions on per-signature compensation are subject to strict scrutiny or a balancing test. For example, in Deters, the Sixth Circuit applied strict scrutiny to a statute restricting per-signature compensation because the statute increased the cost of qualifying an initiative and likely decreased the number of professionals willing to collect signatures. 518 F.3d at 385. The Sixth Circuit found that eliminating all but one form of payment was not merely "academic" because preventing plaintiffs from providing bonuses, setting minimum signature requirements, or tying productivity to compensation stripped plaintiffs of the means to motivate circulators, thereby making qualifying initiatives more expensive. Id. Deters rejected the State of Ohio's argument that pay-per-signature compensation created an incentive to forge signatures because the State had provided no evidence to that effect. Id. at 387.
In Prete, the Ninth Circuit found that plaintiffs had not shown that pay-per-signature compensation significantly burdened their First Amendment rights because there was no evidence that the statute in question "caused a reduction in the number of available circulators or otherwise limit[ed] the size of plaintiff's audience." 438 F.3d at 965. The Ninth Circuit applied a balancing test and found that the statute was distinguishable from the statute in Meyer because it only prohibited one form of payment and allowed
In Jaeger, the Eighth Circuit upheld a ban on per-signature compensation because plaintiffs had failed to provide evidence that "payment by the hour, rather than on commission, would in any way burden their ability to collect signatures." 241 F.3d at 617-18. Similarly, the Second Circuit in Person found that the plaintiff had failed to provide evidence that the ban on pay-per-signature compensation significantly burdened his expressive activities. 467 F.3d at 143. The Second Circuit explained that it found "insufficient support for a claim that the ban on per-signature payment is akin to the complete prohibition on paying petition circulators that was deemed unconstitutional in Meyer, or that the alternative methods of payment it leaves available are insufficient." Id.; see also Bernbeck v. Gale, 2011 WL 3841602 (D.Neb. Aug. 30, 2011) (plaintiffs did not show evidence of a burden on their First Amendment rights by a pay-per-signature requirement); Citizens in Charge v. Gale, 810 F.Supp.2d 916 (D.Neb.2011) (the State had not shown how its statute promoted its interest when it relied on only three instances of fraud).
Unlike some of the aforementioned cases, the plaintiffs in this case have provided evidence showing that § 1-40-112(4) imposes a severe burden on their expressive activities. Although § 1-40-112(4) is not a categorical restriction on one form of circulator compensation as in Deters, or a categorical exclusion of circulators, see Buckley, 525 U.S. at 192-98, 119 S.Ct. 636 (exclusion of circulators not registered to vote); Meyer, 486 U.S. at 414, 108 S.Ct. 1886 (exclusion of all paid circulators); Yes On Term Limits, 550 F.3d at 1028 (exclusion of out-of-state circulators); Chandler v. City of Arvada, Co., 292 F.3d 1236, 1244 (10th Cir.2002) (exclusion of circulators that were not residents of the city), the effect of the hybrid scheme is nevertheless significant as it excludes a key component of circulators from the initiative process. Although § 1-40-112(4) allows for incentive payments to motivate circulators, the benefits of the incentive payments are outweighed by the exclusion of the most effective circulators and the additional costs the statute imposes on signature-gathering activities. See Deters, 518 F.3d at 383 (although the availability of other payment methods might reduce the burden, the extent to which the more effective means are foreclosed is an important consideration).
As discussed above, the statute is likely to eliminate low-volume professional circulators from participating in the initiative process and likely to deter most itinerant professionals from working in Colorado. Their absence will make it significantly more difficult for proponents to qualify measures for the ballot. Without low-volume professional circulators and itinerant professionals, proponents will have to rely on volunteers and untrained paid circulators who are unlikely to "get the job done." Thus, the effect of § 1-40-112(4) will be the exclusion from the initiative process of those who, through experience and self-selection, are the most efficient and effective circulators. See Meyer, 486 U.S. at 424, 108 S.Ct. 1886 ("The First Amendment protects appellees' right not only to advocate their cause but also to select what they believe to be the most effective means for so doing."). To the extent § 1-40-112(4) prevents proponents from using individuals who would most effectively convey their message to the public, the statute places a substantial burden on the proponents' First Amendment rights, even if the statute only restricts proponents from using some, but not all, circulators. See Krislov v. Rednour, 226 F.3d 851, 862 (7th Cir.2000) (finding that a circulator residency restriction imposed a significant burden on plaintiff's First
The testimony at trial established that the effect of § 1-40-112(4) will be to raise the per signature cost for a ballot petition campaign by at least 18%. The effect of raising the per signature cost by 18% will be to restrict participation in the initiative process for proponents with limited resources. See Meyer, 486 U.S. at 423, 108 S.Ct. 1886 (statute is a burden on speech as it limits proponents' "ability to make the matter the focus of statewide discussion"). Gratz testified that, after the Colorado Civil Rights Initiative failed in 2008, donors were deterred from pursuing a petition campaign in the 2010 general election because of the anticipated increase in costs once the Colorado Assembly enacted H.B. 1326. Caldara said that, although some proponents could afford the high costs of a campaign, he would be unable to fund future signature-gathering campaigns because of the increases in costs. Tvert testified that, because of the large number of signatures required to qualify an issue for the ballot, even minor increases in the price of a single signature could significantly raise the costs of a signature-gathering campaign from $200,000 to $300,000. Finally, Kennedy testified that even a 25¢ increase in the per signature price could have the effect of pricing proponents out of running initiatives, especially in a tough economic climate. The Court finds that an 18% cost increase is significant. By raising the cost of signature-gathering activities, § 1-40-112(4) will have the inevitable effect of reducing the total quantum of speech on a public issue. Id.
Accordingly, the Court finds that § 1-40-112(4) imposes a severe burden on petition proponents and strict scrutiny applies. As the Tenth Circuit stated in Chandler, "petition circulation ... is core political speech, because it involves interactive communication concerning political change," and consequently, First Amendment protection for this activity is "at its zenith." 292 F.3d at 1241 (quotations and alteration omitted). "[W]here the government restricts the overall quantum of speech available to the election or voting process ... [such as] where the quantum of speech is limited due to restrictions on... the available pool of circulators or other supporters of a candidate or initiative," strict scrutiny applies. Yes on Term Limits, 550 F.3d at 1028 (quotations and citations omitted).
To survive strict scrutiny, the Secretary has the burden of proving that the hybrid scheme is narrowly tailored to serve a compelling State interest. Yes on Term Limits, 550 F.3d at 1028 (citation omitted). The Secretary argues that § 1-40-112(4) furthers the State of Colorado's compelling interest in maintaining the integrity of the initiative process by reducing the incentive to commit fraud, increasing the validity of signatures, and maintaining public confidence in the initiative process.
The Court finds that the State of Colorado has a compelling interest in ensuring the reliability and honesty of the referendum and initiative process. See Buckley, 525 U.S. at 187, 119 S.Ct. 636 (there must be substantial regulation of elections if they are to be fair and honest and if some sort of order, rather than chaos, is to accompany the democratic process); Am. Constitutional Law
Additionally, the Court finds that the evidence relied upon by the Colorado General Assembly in enacting § 1-40-112(4) does not entitle the statute to deference.
Furthermore, there are less restrictive means to accomplish the State's goal of protecting the integrity of the initiative process. Rudy and Mikeworth testified that, because of a lack of resources, the Secretary is unable to detect a significant amount of circulator fraud. However, the Supreme Court has never held the lack of public resources to be sufficient justification for a regulation to survive strict scrutiny. Cf. Ohio Citizen Action v. City of Englewood, 671 F.3d 564, 575 (6th Cir. 2012) (noting that the "[Supreme] Court has never held the efficient allocation of public resources to be an interest sufficient to survive heightened scrutiny"). There are alternatives that would address the problems targeted by § 1-40-112(4) without imposing a severe burden on plaintiffs' First Amendment rights. As the Supreme Court noted in Buckley, Colorado retains several safeguards to protect the integrity of the initiative process and diminish corruption. See, e.g., Colo.Rev. Stat. § 1-40-106 (making it a crime to forge signatures); Colo.Rev.Stat. § 1-40-130 (making false witnessing, surrogate fraud, and false witnessing punishable by a fine of up to $1500 or imprisonment for not more than a year). "These provisions seem adequate to the task of minimizing the risk of improper conduct in the circulation of a petition," especially since there has been little evidence that § 1-40-112(4) will have any effect on the incidence of fraud. Meyer, 486 U.S. at 427, 108 S.Ct. 1886; see also Riley v. Nat'l Fed'n of the Blind of N.C., 487 U.S. 781, 800, 108 S.Ct. 2667, 101 L.Ed.2d 669 (1988) (noting that "the State may vigorously enforce its antifraud laws to prohibit professional fundraisers from obtaining money on false pretenses or by making false statements"). Second, Colorado could publicly disclose petition sections, which would communicate information to the public without burdening plaintiffs' First Amendment rights. See Doe v. Reed, ___ U.S. ___, 130 S.Ct. 2811, 2820, 177 L.Ed.2d 493 (2010) ("The signer [of the petition] is in the best position to detect these types of fraud, and public disclosure can bring the issue to the signer's attention"). These more narrowly tailored options are in keeping with the First Amendment directive that government not infringe on the freedom of speech absent compelling necessity, and then, only by means precisely tailored. Burdick v. Takushi, 504 U.S. 428, 439, 112 S.Ct. 2059, 119 L.Ed.2d 245 (1992).
Given the availability of other effective and less burdensome statutory tools to safeguard the State's interest, the Court concludes that § 1-40-112(4) poses an undue restriction on plaintiffs' First Amendment rights. While the Secretary has provided evidence that fraud has occurred when the pay-per-signature method is used, he has not isolated the cause of circulator fraud as being the pay-per-signature method. Consequently, the State has failed to provide evidence that its regulation is narrowly (or even reasonably)
Given the Secretary's failure to show that pay-per-signature compensation incentivizes fraud to a greater extent than pay-per-hour compensation, the statute also fails the balancing test that courts have applied. See, e.g., Burdick, 504 U.S. at 434, 112 S.Ct. 2059 (noting that courts should balance "the character and magnitude of the asserted injury" to the rights protected by the First Amendment against "the precise interests put forward by the State as justifications for the burden imposed" by the regulation); Tashjian v. Republican Party of Conn., 479 U.S. 208, 213, 107 S.Ct. 544, 93 L.Ed.2d 514 (1986) (same). As noted above, the State has a legitimate interest in ensuring the reliability and honesty of the referendum and initiative process. See Buckley, 525 U.S. at 187, 119 S.Ct. 636. Colorado's law does not survive a balancing test, however, because the hybrid scheme does not sufficiently relate to the State's legitimate interest in reducing fraud or corruption. See Deters, 518 F.3d at 387. Although the State is permitted "considerable leeway" in regulating the electoral process, this latitude is premised on the requirement that legislative choices not produce "undue hindrances to political conversations and the exchange of ideas." Buckley, 525 U.S. at 191-92, 119 S.Ct. 636. This leeway does not apply here because the precise interest that the State identifies — fraud reduction — is not furthered by the statute. Moreover, the burden imposed by the statute, as discussed above, will likely reduce the number of qualifying initiatives and make it more difficult for proponents to attract financial support. The net effect will be to encumber the petition process unjustifiably and thereby reduce the "unfettered interchange of ideas for the bringing about of political and social changes." Meyer, 486 U.S. at 421, 108 S.Ct. 1886 (citation omitted). Thus, on balance, the State's legitimate interest in reducing fraud is outweighed by the burden imposed on plaintiffs' First Amendment rights. See Anderson v. Celebrezze, 460 U.S. 780, 789, 103 S.Ct. 1564, 75 L.Ed.2d 547 (1983) ("In passing judgment, the Court must not only determine the legitimacy and strength of each of those interests; it also must consider the extent to which those interests make it necessary to burden the plaintiff's rights").
Having found that Colo.Rev.Stat. § 1-40-112(4) is an unconstitutional infringement of plaintiffs' First Amendment rights, the Court next addresses plaintiffs' request for a permanent injunction and declaratory judgment that the statute is unconstitutional.
To obtain permanent injunctive relief, a party must satisfy the following four factors: (1) that it has suffered an irreparable injury; (2) that remedies available at law, such as monetary damages, are inadequate to compensate for that injury; (3) that, considering the balance of hardships between the plaintiff and defendant, a remedy in equity is warranted; and (4) that the public interest would not be disserved by a permanent injunction. Monsanto Co. v. Geertson Seed Farms, ___ U.S. ___, 130 S.Ct. 2743, 2756, 177 L.Ed.2d 461 (2010) (citation omitted).
Addressing the first factor, plaintiffs have shown that, unless the statute is enjoined, they will likely face irreparable injury. Elrod v. Burns, 427 U.S. 347, 373-74, 96 S.Ct. 2673, 49 L.Ed.2d 547 (1976); see also Dombrowski v. Pfister, 380 U.S. 479,
With respect to the second factor, plaintiffs have no adequate remedies at law because damages cannot replace the loss of protected First Amendment rights. See Nat'l People's Action v. Vill. of Wilmette, 914 F.2d 1008, 1013 (7th Cir.1990) ("[I]njunctions are especially appropriate in the context of first amendment violations because of the inadequacy of money damages"); see also Legend Night Club v. Miller, 637 F.3d 291, 297 (4th Cir.2011).
With regard to the balance of the equities, "[s]peech is an essential mechanism of democracy, for it is the means to hold officials accountable to the people." Citizens United v. Federal Election Comm'n, 558 U.S. 310, 130 S.Ct. 876, 898, 175 L.Ed.2d 753 (2010). Plaintiffs have a fundamental interest in being able to express their desire for political change and actively work toward achieving that goal through the ballot initiative process that the Colorado Constitution has provided. The State is unlikely to be harmed because, as discussed above, there is no evidence that there would be any less fraud under § 1-40-112(4)'s hybrid compensation scheme than under a pay-per-signature scheme. Therefore, the equities also tilt in plaintiffs' favor.
Based on the foregoing, the Court finds that plaintiffs have met their burden of showing that they are entitled to a permanent injunction of the enforcement of Colorado Revised Statutes § 1-40-112(4). Plaintiffs are also entitled to a permanent injunction of any ancillary statute which enforces § 1-40-112(4), namely, Colorado Revised Statutes §§ 1-40-135 and 1-40-121 to the extent that those sections apply to the restriction on per-signature compensation found in § 1-40-112(4).
Therefore, it is