GREGORY F. KISHEL, CHIEF UNITED STATES BANKRUPTCY COURT
The origin of this adversary proceeding is amply familiar from locally-generated case law. E.g., In re Petters Co., Inc., 401 B.R. 391 (Bankr.D.Minn.2009), aff'd, 620 F.3d 847 (8th Cir.2010); In re Petters Co., Inc., 440 B.R. 805 (Bankr.D.Minn.2010); In re Petters Co., Inc., 506 B.R. 784 (Bankr.D.Minn.2013); In re Petters Co., Inc., 548 B.R. 551 (Bankr.D.Minn.2016). See also In re Polaroid Corp., 472 B.R. 22 (Bankr.D.Minn.2012), aff'd, 779 F.3d 857 (8th Cir.2015). The Plaintiff, as trustee,
Before the great financial downturn of 2007-2008, there had been no litigation effort of this sort and magnitude locally. There was no local case law, state or federal, in treatment of the theories that the Trustee was invoking. Because the Trustee sued out more than 200 adversary proceedings on his theory, a "common issues" procedure was ordered to present various threshold questions as matters of law toward filling that gap. This was staged through the vehicle of motions for dismissal that dozens of defendants had filed. The procedure resulted in three "common issues" memoranda, In re Petters Co., Inc., 494 B.R. 413; In re Petters Co., Inc., 495 B.R. 887; and In re Petters Co., Inc., 499 B.R. 342 (all Bankr.D. Minn. 2013) (respectively, the First, Second, and Third Memoranda).
Among those rulings, a "Ponzi scheme presumption" on actual fraudulent intent was adopted, 495 B.R. at 912; "reasonably equivalent value" was held to be lacking in the ostensible payment of interest to lenders into a Ponzi scheme, 499 B.R. at 359; and the statutorily-required financial distress of a transferor-entity — insolvency, insufficiency of capital or intent to incur debt beyond repayment ability — was properly pled, and could be proven, by the transferor's operation of a Ponzi scheme and its funding of payments to the transferee through the operation of the scheme, i.e. with money lent by later investors, diverted from the purposes for which the lending was intended, 495 B.R. at 924-925. These rulings were based on various guiding principles in the earlier case law from federal courts that had presided over similar litigation.
The rulings were applied after that common memorialization, when the motions for dismissal were denied for the majority of the Trustee's fraudulent-transfer actions. That was done in the adversary proceedings that featured lesser amounts in controversy and similar, more straightforward transactional histories within their fact-pleading. After that, the rulings were to be applied on motions for summary judgment that the Trustee contemplated bringing en masse after a coordinated discovery process.
A smaller number of the Trustee's fraudulent-transfer actions were carved out of that coordinated treatment, due to the "unique issues" posed by fact-pleading of more complicated transactional structures and processes, variance in the nature of the original liabilities running between the Debtors and their particular defendants, and so forth. This adversary proceeding was among the latter group.
As the litigation docket was queuing up to go forward in earnest on these two tracks, the Minnesota Supreme Court issued Finn v. Alliance Bank, 860 N.W.2d 638 (Minn.2015). Finn came out of a lawsuit brought in the Minnesota state courts by a court-appointed receiver, in a different remediation effort similar to the Trustee's and styled under the same substantive authority, MUFTA. In Finn, however, the receiver-plaintiff was denied
The receiver-plaintiff in Finn had argued for the use of a "Ponzi scheme presumption" from the same federal case law that gave the basis for the common-issues rulings here. He argued that the presumption had to be given "conclusive" effect. And for the application of his urged analysis and the operation of the presumption, the receiver did not see any distinction between transfers in consequence of investment into legitimate, real business transactions and those on investment induced by false pretenses; the common originator-entity and the similarity of the transactions' structures was enough for him.
The Finn court outlined a Ponzi scheme presumption in three components, which it gleaned from the prior federal case law. The components went to the intent of the transferor (i.e. actually fraudulent or not); the transferor's solvency at the time of the transfer; and whether the transferor received a reasonably equivalent value for the interest-component of the payment made to the investor.
The Finn court ruled on the viability of the presumption under MUFTA in all three parts. It then treated the concept of reasonably equivalent value as it applied to the record before it; and it made less prominent rulings on the adequacy of pleading for a claim under MUFTA premised on facts involving a Ponzi scheme. The tone and articulation of most of Finn's rulings suggested that they were formulated as a response to the common issues memoranda issued in the PCI litigation docket.
Defense counsel here quickly questioned the viability of this court's rulings in light of Finn. They pressed to bring a challenge at an early date. In light of the gravity of the issue, this adversary proceeding was chosen as a sole, free-standing vehicle to bring the issue into the litigation docket in the PCI cases. A motion for dismissal by the Opportunity Finance defendants
When the hearing was convened for that presentation, James A. Lodoen, Adam C. Ballinger, and Mark D. Larsen appeared for the Trustee. Joseph G. Petrosinelli
Finn's most salient rulings lie in its rejection of the Ponzi scheme presumptions. The Finn court organized the bulk of its discussion around the viability of the presumptions; the tripartite rejection is its one ruling on general principles of law.
A presumption operates as an evidentiary device. "Through presumptions, the existence of one fact is presumed from proof of another. . . . The `true presumption' creates an inference that is mandatory unless rebutted." John Calvin Jeffries, Jr. and Paul B. Stephan III, Defenses, Presumptions, and Burden of Proof in the Criminal Law, 88 Yale L.J. 1325, 1335-1336 (1979). "A presumption informs the [finder of fact] that once a party has proved A, the basic fact, the jury can or must presume B, the presumed fact." Connecticut v. Johnson, 460 U.S. 73, 96, 103 S.Ct. 969, 74 L.Ed.2d 823 (1983). The viability of a presumption "depends on how closely facts X and Y are related by experience and common sense." Jeffries and Stephan, 88 Yale L.J. at 1336.
It was inevitable that the Finn court's discussion, tone, analysis, and conclusions about the Ponzi scheme presumptions were channeled by the specific structure and operation of the Ponzi scheme before it. The perpetrator of the scheme in Finn had conducted business in the real estate finance sector, originating loans for the funding of real estate transactions and then finding institutional lenders to "participate in" the loans.
The appeal in Finn involved two groups of participant-banks. A number of banks, there collectively called "the Respondent Banks," each purchased fractional participation interests in loans that the perpetrator had originated, loans "that were real, not fraudulent," 860 N.W.2d at 642, that "were neither fictitious nor oversold," 860 N.W.2d at 643. In a different transaction, Alliance Bank took the assignment of the lender's rights on one originated loan in full, again a loan "real, not fictitious, and. . . not oversold." Id. The appeal in Finn did not involve any bank that had taken participant status as to a falsely-pretensed,
To make out a case for avoidance under MUFTA, the receiver had asserted an irrebuttable or "conclusive" presumption, Finn, 860 N.W.2d at 645-649, that would compel specific findings in his favor "as a matter of law" on summary judgment. The findings would meet various factual elements of the receiver's prima facie case, and negate an affirmative defense asserted by the transferee-defendants. Finn, 860 N.W.2d at 645-646.
Multiple federal courts had previously recognized a Ponzi scheme presumption.
It started by pointing to the lack of a Ponzi-scheme presumption on the face of MUFTA. Finn, 860 N.W.2d at 646-647 ("MUFTA does not contain a provision allowing a court to presume anything based on the mere existence of a Ponzi scheme"). Then, implicitly, it declined to independently recognize the presumption by judicial action.
The Finn court performed its analysis from a specific perspective. Its frame of reference sprung from a specific notion of the scope of MUFTA's application, and a tightly-defined focus for MUFTA's remedy of avoidance:
Id.
Thus, the Finn court held, there could be no presumption, "conclusive[], as the Receiver would have it — that fraudulent intent accompanies all transfers in furtherance of a Ponzi scheme," i.e. that "the scheme's operator invariably intends to cheat all investors." Id. (emphasis added).
The quoted characterization of the presumption plus later observations suggest a more fundamental reason for the Finn court's disfavor: the proffered, general factual context — the mere presence of a Ponzi scheme within a perpetrator's broader business operation — did not entail the invariability in regular human behavior that justifies the adoption of presumptions in the law of evidence and their use in judicial fact-finding. E.g., ". . . a debtor could have assets or legitimate business operations aside from the Ponzi scheme." Finn, 860 N.W.2d at 649.
Yes, the perpetrator in Finn had obtained money from other lenders on separate ostensible transactions that were either presented on a completely false pretense — i.e., there were no such transactions — or on genuine transactions that it "oversold" — i.e., the perpetrator pulled in more money in the aggregate from multiple independent partial participants than the amount of principal it had originally lent as originator. Finn, 860 N.W.2d at 642. However, none of the receiver's opponents in the lawsuits before the Minnesota appellate courts were in this group of defrauded participants. Finn, 860 N.W.2d at 652 (noting that there was "no dispute that [all] the [participant] banks . . . purchased non-oversold participation interests in actual loans to real borrowers . . ." (emphasis in original)).
The Finn court clearly believed that the judicial imposition of a presumption of pervasive intent to defraud creditors was not defensible, where the receiver's ultimate argument for it was reduced to an abstract happenstance: the genuine deals at bar used the same structures as the ostensible but phony ones pretensed to those other investors, and the perpetrator had been involved in all of the participations as the nominal originator, whether actual or ostensible.
Under prior case law from the federal courts, this evidentiary device ran broadly across fraudulent-transfer litigation. It went to a plaintiff's case in chief under the statutory rubric of constructively-fraudulent transfer, Minn. Stat. §§ 513.44(a)(2) and 513.45(a), for which an essential element is the absence of a reasonably equivalent value received by the debtor for the transfer it made. It also applied to the affirmative defense to avoidance under either theory of fraudulence — Minn. Stat. § 513.48(a), under which a defendant may avoid liability by proving that it had taken the transfer from the debtor "in good faith and for a reasonably equivalent value." See, in general, In re Petters Company, Inc., 499 B.R. at 353-363 (adopting analysis set forth comprehensively in Scholes v. Lehmann, 56 F.3d 750 (7th Cir.1995), in part on principles first framed in In re Indep. Clearing House Co., 77 B.R. 843 (D.Utah 1987).
When parsing out Finn's holdings, it is crucial to remember that the Finn court rejected all three component presumptions because the debtor-transferee transactions in the case took place almost completely outside the fraud-pervasive part of that debtor's business operations, the roost for the Ponzi scheme as traditionally considered.
Whether the very same dollars could be traced through to the defendant-banks as ultimate transferees, the Finn court attached decisive significance to the genuineness of the underlying deals in their own, separate right. It pointedly observed that in any event the actual income-generation from commercially-reasonable transactions featuring real-life underlying investments enabled the satisfaction of the bank-transferees.
In the posture of debtor and transferee before it, the Finn court saw a legitimacy that undercut the justification for a "conclusive," pervasive presumption of fraudulent intent and theft: if, as there, a Ponzi scheme perpetrator could separately carry on legitimate business through the same structure of deal as it falsely pretensed independently to victim-investors, incurring transaction-specific debt and paying it with transaction-generated proceeds, it would not be defensible to presume that every last one of the perpetrator's similarly-structured transactions with its investors was fraudulent and predatory. There was no reason to excuse the receiver from the burden of proof otherwise imposed on a proponent of avoidance remedies, as to specific transfers. Cf. Finn, 860 N.W.2d at 648-649 (rejecting presumption that perpetrator of Ponzi scheme is insolvent throughout period of operation of scheme), 651 (criticizing analytic structure through which lack of reasonably-equivalent value in receipt of interest from Ponzi scheme perpetrator would be deemed to every single transaction in which perpetrator had engaged, and rejecting presumption of fact as to same).
The Finn court used these conclusions to categorically reject all three components of a Ponzi scheme presumption.
Finn does not reject the Ponzi scheme presumption of fraudulent intent on a lack of defensible basis for the presumption's action, or on any consideration of the facts before it. Rather, it points to the lack of textual provision for it in MUFTA, and the statute's contemplation that each transfer by a financially-distressed debtor be analyzed on its own circumstances for the presence or absence of fraudulent intent. 860 N.W.2d at 647. With the presumption rejected, that analysis
A plaintiff may still plead and prove intent with the aid of an inference, by bringing forward enough indicia of fraud, in surrounding circumstance — the badges-of-fraud approach specifically provided in MUFTA. Minn.Stat. § 513.44(b); Finn, 860 N.W.2d at 647; Citizens State Bank Norwood Young America v. Brown, 849 N.W.2d 55, 60 (Minn.2014). And lodged somewhat unobtrusively in the text of Finn, 860 N.W.2d at 654, is a ruling: a prima facie case for an actual-fraud claim on transfers by a Ponzi-scheme perpetrator is adequately pled when a pattern of prior fraudulent inducement directed at a particular class of investors, committed by the transferor, is described; the perpetrator was running a Ponzi scheme to defraud just such investors; and the perpetrator made the subject transfers to the defendants sued, with the intent to hinder, delay, or defraud other creditors of the perpetrator. 860 N.W.2d at 654.
From this ruling on the adequacy of pleading, it is clear that a case for avoidance on an actual-fraud theory can be framed and made as to transfers to investors that had infused into the main, rolling transactional sequence of a Ponzi scheme's operation, and that were made with an intent that other creditors not receive the benefit of the funds so transferred. That intent logically would align with the use of funds snaffled from later investors, diverted away from the investment uses represented to them when they were induced to lend, and hence taken away from any expected function toward their repayment.
It would require an inference to actually satisfy the intent element for a transfer within such a transactional matrix; but, clearly, Finn contemplates that it can be made. 860 N.W.2d at 647. The finding would not be through the compelled, shortened arc of a presumption; but the inference could hit the legal mark of the intent element in this way. See analysis in In re Petters Co., Inc., 548 B.R. at 563-565, cf. Ritchie Capital Mgmt., LLC v. Stoebner, 779 F.3d at 861-863.
Thus, an actual-fraud theory for avoidance is adequately pled for the Ponzi scheme context, when facts are recited to put the challenged transfer into the central processes of such a scheme: the pretense of an active investment operation, projected on the hallmark of a specific sort of economic opportunity; debt to investors incurred by the schemer, on an earlier fraudulent-inducement with the pretense of a real-life business proposal and the ends to which their infusions would be directed there; further fraudulent inducements to new generations of investors; the repayment of earlier debt using funds misdirected from the cash infusions of later investors; and ultimately, real economic harm to the last investors, who are left unpaid when the scheme collapses due to its inability to take in enough new money. If a complaint recites this much to put a challenged transfer into a specific place in the main churn of a Ponzi scheme, it adequately states an actionable claim for avoidance under an actual-fraud theory. In re Petters Co., Inc., 548 B.R. at 564. Finn holds essentially that, albeit in more skeletal fashion. 860 N.W.2d at 654.
As noted earlier, Finn prescribed a perspective for the application of the statute: MUFTA compels proponents to prove all essential elements as to each subject transfer, as of the date of each transfer. This perspective drove the rejection of the second component presumption, a compelled inference that a Ponzi scheme is insolvent from its inception.
The first was on a separation-of-powers/judicial restraint rationale — recognizing such a presumption would require the court "to add language to MUFTA, something we cannot do." Id.
860 N.W.2d at 649.
One could take issue with this reasoning, considering the subject matter. The federal case law inferentially deemed an operational insolvency to the perpetrator of a Ponzi scheme, on the thought (not ill-founded) that such schemes by their basic structure quickly pile up unsatisfied debt in amounts increasingly beyond their current means to satisfy, because they have no real external business from which to generate a profit and all invested funding is diverted to the payoff of prior investors and the perpetrator's self-enrichment. In re Petters Co., Inc., 495 B.R. at 922-925.
This thought was not specifically classified as a presumption in the Second Memorandum, and certainly not a "conclusive" one as the receiver in Finn insisted on. 495 B.R. at 924. Nonetheless, for the pleading-centered purposes of the common-issues treatment, the allegation of insolvency by the place of a transfer in the central operation of a Ponzi scheme was deemed sufficient. 495 B.R. at 925.
Finn again goes beyond the context of pleading to reach the substantive viability of a presumption on the insolvency element. It bars the bare reliance on a presumption as sufficient to plead or prove insolvency under MUFTA's definition, for any particular transfer made by the perpetrator of a Ponzi scheme. Since Finn mandates a transfer-by-transfer approach
The defense here drives at just such an exacting requirement for recitation. But even in the wake of Twombly and Iqbal,
Finn's discussion of the element of reasonably equivalent value presents the largest challenge as to its scope of application. The text of the opinion goes beyond the internal viability of a presumption based on an invariable cause-and-effect relationship between two facts. It makes a substantive legal assessment of the reasonable equivalence of value received from the payment of contractual interest on a preexisting debt. These pronouncements on law are sandwiched into the analysis of whether the presumption (a fact-finding device) is viable. The rejection of the presumption is the most salient function of Finn — evidenced in the way that all of Finn's observations are channeled toward three categorical pronouncements of rejection, 860 N.W.2d at 647, 649, and 653. But the analysis on reasonably equivalent value for the presumption later segues over into a treatment of substance.
Analytically, this creates a sense of disjunction. One wonders why the discussion went into weighty substantive principles, when the mission undertaken was to correct a plaintiff's over-reliance on a vaguely-framed shortcut of judicature to make out a substantial part of his prima facie case, and his curious insistence that it had to be "conclusive."
But nonetheless, the discussion is there, built out in some detail; and it is there whether it was well-put or was even necessary to do the job of appellate correction of trial-court error. The discussion is salient enough that it prompted the defense here to adopt it for an attempted hammer-blow at the Trustee's whole theory of suit in avoidance. That is the genesis of most of the imbroglio at bar.
As a broad threshold, that much could not be disputed reasonably. But in opening its analysis, the Finn court did qualify these observations — that they operated "[a]bsent the existence of a Ponzi scheme. . . ." Id. Finn could have expressly reached a broader question: whether "value" was present anywhere, let alone in reasonably-equivalent measure, when a contractually-structured debt for principal and interest was incurred and then satisfied by the perpetrator of a Ponzi scheme, on an investment transaction that is pretensed on a fraudulent inducement. However, in Finn the actual issue was more narrow and on a more abstracted plane: whether a lack of reasonably equivalent value so invariably lay in a perpetrator's payment of interest on a debt to an investor, that a presumption should be imposed, to "effectively negate a transferee's good-faith defense to an actual-fraud claim and conclusively establish a crucial element of a constructive-fraud claim." Finn, 860 N.W.2d at 650. The issue before the Finn court was whether a lack of value and reasonable equivalence, in that relative sense, had to be presumed "as a matter of law," as between the interest paid to all investors that lent to the perpetrator of a Ponzi scheme, and the satisfaction of the perpetrator's obligation to pay such interest or "profit" under the terms of the parties' original contractual undertaking, regardless of the legitimacy of the underlying investment.
The Finn court rejected this third component presumption. Clearly, it did so because the range of factual landscapes to which the presumption would be applied lacked the invariability in essence and outcome in real human experience, that would justify a presumption's constraining operation in adjudication. Supra, 6.
The federal courts that previously held that reasonably equivalent value was lacking in the payment of "false profits" out of a Ponzi scheme had done so on application of equitable principles. Through the lens of equity, those courts had rejected the legal enforceability of contractual promises to repay a fraudulently-incurred debt as contrary to public policy; they recast the parties' rights after the fact on an equitable theory of restitution, allowing a recipient sued under the constructive-fraud theory to keep the amount of its original, repaid principal investment under the classification of equitable restitution; and they compelled the surrender of the remaining monies received — that paid under the classification of contractual interest — as the fruit of an unenforceable contract. In re Petters Co., Inc., 499 B.R. at 355-359 (citing analysis in Scholes v. Lehmann, 56 F.3d 750, 756-759 (7th Cir.1995)). With contractual terms thus overridden in a final adjudication under principles of equity, the past payment of interest was not linked to cognizable antecedent debt and thus could not embody value under the statutory definition that was reasonably equivalent under the statutory contemplation.
This much all resonated with a patent fact: for payments received and made that
The Finn court actually acknowledged the reality of that central incident of a Ponzi scheme's core operation; it termed this recognition a "factual observation" and did not gainsay it. Finn, 860 N.W.2d at 652. But it rejected this notion of a presumption of lack of reasonably equivalent value that would apply to every single transaction in which a Ponzi-scheme perpetrator was a participant. In the Finn court's estimation, such a universally-scoped presumption was not viable because it was inflexible: it would apply despite the obvious possibility that "not every Ponzi scheme lacks a legitimate source of earnings." Id. So the Finn court held that the transferees before it could not be bound by the toils of such a presumption.
After that, the Finn court freed all of the transferees before it from liability in avoidance under the constructive-fraud theory. It performed a case-specific analysis to support its conclusion that the receiver could not make out a lack of reasonably equivalent value as to any of them. As to the suit involving multiple participants on loans, the case failed on the receiver's pleading. In his complaint, the receiver had averred that the "profits . . . paid" by the debtor were not reasonably equivalent in value for what it received, "because [the perpetrator was] engaged in a Ponzi scheme"; but the receiver had pled nothing more than that as to a lack of reasonably equivalent value in the specific exchanges under consideration.
As to Alliance Bank, the receiver's case failed on the defendant's motion for summary judgment. The court stated that without the benefit of a presumption of lack of reasonably equivalent value premised on the invalidation of "all contracts made with a Ponzi-scheme operator," the receiver had "essentially provid[ed] no reason to invalidate the participation agreement other than the fact that it was a part of a greater Ponzi scheme." Id. (emphasis added). Thus, the satisfaction of the contractual debt (including interest), as a matter of fact, provided "value" as a matter of law.
However, the cited precedent repeatedly defined the shelter by using a modifying predicate that implied an exclusion from its protection — one that would be triggered on the presence of intentional wrongdoing, dishonesty or fraud of some sort. See Finn, 860 N.W.2d at 651 (citing Skinner v. Overend, 190 Minn. 456, 252 N.W. 418, 418-419 (1934), which was later cited in Kummet v. Thielen, 210 Minn. 302, 298 N.W. 245, 246 (1941) for proposition that "a transfer . . . honestly made in payment of an antecedent debt . . . [is] not fraudulent" (emphasis added)); 860 N.W.2d at 652 (quoting Thompson v. Schiek, 171 Minn. 284, 213 N.W. 911, 912 (1927), re: "[p]ayment of an honest debt. . . not [being] fraudulent under the general statutes against fraudulent conveyances" (emphasis added)); 860 N.W.2d at 653 (citing Aretz v. Kloos, 89 Minn. 432, 95 N.W. 216, 219 (1903) for principle that payment to "a bona fide creditor" constitutes fair consideration to transferor-debtor "in the absence of actual fraud" (emphasis added)).
Finn uses the main proposition from this precedent to drive its outcome. The Finn court recognized something undeniable: as a matter of possibility within general human experience, the business operations of a Ponzi scheme's perpetrator are not invariably or intrinsically rotten top-to-bottom and side-to-side — even in the specific line of endeavor that the perpetrator fraudulently sells to its victims. A perpetrator could negotiate and consummate genuine business — contractually separate from the main, rolling churn of its scheme. That could be the case at the beginning of an investment concern's operations, before circumstances change and the operator makes bad choices that cause it to become the perpetrator of a Ponzi scheme. The Finn court cited this as a factual possibility, and the possibility cannot be denied.
On that recognition, the Finn court rejected the third component of the Ponzi scheme presumption. It concluded that reasonably equivalent value could not be lacking as a matter of law for any component of payments made on debt contracted in connection with real, consummated underlying deals even though their financing had been obtained through the involvement of a Ponzi scheme's perpetrator.
When it treated the presumption on reasonably equivalent value, however, the Finn court went beyond the defensibility of the presumption as an evidentiary device for fact-finding. It went into the legal dimension of the statutory element itself, and made a proposition the hingepin of its analysis: reasonably equivalent value had to be attributed to such a payment, when made on legally-enforceable debt associated
After that, the Finn court found further justification in principles from longstanding Minnesota jurisprudence: the mere transfer to one creditor of funds from a debtor's limited means is not subject to later avoidance under fraudulent-transfer law at the behest of other creditors not similarly favored. The rationale is that simply preferring one bona fide creditor is not itself avoidable as fraudulent as to any other creditor, under nonbankruptcy law. Finn, 860 N.W.2d at 653. (For brevity, this phenomenon and doctrine will be termed "permissible preference," from here on.)
The rejection of the presumption was the first step toward addressing the dispositional dimension of the appeals in Finn. The receiver had argued in the trial court and on appeal that he satisfied his burdens of pleading and proof on the issue of reasonably equivalent value, by relying on the presumption. With the presumption rejected, the Finn court went on to the case-specific tasks before it: whether the trial court had properly granted summary judgment against Alliance Bank on the record and argument before it, including the assertion of the Ponzi scheme presumption on the receiver's actual- and constructive-fraud theories; and whether the Respondent Banks had properly supported their motion for dismissal by denying the viability of the presumption and pointing out that the receiver's other fact-pleading was inadequate to independently support relief under actual- and constructive-fraud theories. 860 N.W.2d at 653.
In doing that, Finn loops back around and uses much of the policy-oriented analysis for the rejection of the presumption, for concrete effect in gauging the substantive adequacy of the cases for avoidance that the receiver had presented. This gets confusing, in the way it pushes the abstract into the broader determination of whether a remedy is available under MUFTA for a harm that identifiable creditor-parties unquestionably suffered.
Finn uses a distinct conceptual structure to bar the use of MUFTA-based remedies against the transferees before it. It casts those parties as no more than the recipients of a permissible preference. But in its strength and length, Finn's phraseology toward that end is deceptive. It unfortunately lends itself to the argument that the analysis is categorical — that the reasoning in Finn compels the same outcome whenever a Ponzi-scheme perpetrator and an investor transact through the same bare documentary structure for lending or investment to support exchanges of funds, i.e. on any debtor-creditor relationship under documentary trappings for which a loan was being repaid. Under such a categorical approach, it
However, the argument for a categorical application is belied by the qualification that appears in the precedent on which the Finn court relies. That authority cannot be ignored when Finn is parsed for the scope of its pronouncements for possible application to an alternate situation. It is easy to pass over, but it is there: preferences in favor of a bona fide creditor are valid in the absence of actual fraud. Id. (citing Aretz v. Kloos, 89 Minn. 432, 95 N.W. 216, 219 (1903)). "MUFTA does not prohibit a debtor from making a preferential transfer in favor of one bona fide creditor over another so long as the transfer is not fraudulent." Id.
The Finn court did not highlight the fraud-centered qualifier of its cited precedent, or even acknowledge its presence in any pointed way.
This is the effect that the defense here would give to Finn as a whole. That is a dubious assumption, not the least because it would attribute little or no judicial restraint to the Finn court.
Read in the most principled light, and attributing judicial restraint to the court that issued it, Finn does not establish a broad, all-encompassing, and binding rule of decision for application to any and every payment made by the perpetrator of a Ponzi scheme to any or all of its investors or creditors. The facts on which the Finn court ruled did not have the nuance that runs across the Petters Company avoidance litigation, as the Trustee here pleads it.
Finn's analysis, its quoted precedent, and its outcome, it stands for only one proposition in an unequivocal way: in the context of a perpetrator's business operation
Finn's discussion is driven with determination toward a specific outcome for the parties before it, and toward an unequivocal fate for the presumptions being judged. Given that, it is too facile to expand that one undeniable thought to a categorical rule for application throughout the operations of a Ponzi scheme perpetrator: as long as an investor or lender into the business operations of a Ponzi-scheme purveyor makes its investment or lending under regular documentation of a facial tenor that is consistent with legal enforceability, all satisfaction of debt through the purveyor's repayment according to the document's terms gives reasonably equivalent value to the purveyor.
That extension, however, is just not borne out — not the least because Finn tacitly acknowledged the fraud-centered exclusion from the shelter given to a permissible preference, that longstanding Minnesota precedent still features.
The Trustee seeks to avoid transfers made in satisfaction of contractually-memorialized debt that, de facto, was not associated in its inception with real-life transactions in the merchandise-factoring or "diversion" activity for which the Debtors were ostensibly soliciting financing. Rather, as the Trustee pleads it here, the payments in suit were directly and inextricably part of pervasively-fraudulent conduct on the part of the transferor that was making payment, with that fraud running from the inception of the underlying debt to its satisfaction by the payments that the Trustee seeks to avoid. Finn's pronouncements on the matter of reasonably equivalent value do not as a matter of law bar the Trustee on these theories. That outcome is fully justified by the very precedent in Minnesota state law on which the Finn court bases its bedrock analysis.
First, a fundamental verity must be recognized. The Finn court did not acknowledge this, but only because the facts there did not require it: a Ponzi scheme is a rolling fraud, involving a linear sequence of victims. Its maintenance requires two separate instances of chicanery on the perpetrator's part, as to any particular victim-participant.
In the first instance, a lender or investor is gulled into advancing money by a fraud in the inducement: the perpetrator's representation that the infused funds will be directed toward a particular investment vehicle, use, or purpose, the execution of which will generate profit or capital gain for the lender or investor. The injury of that deception occurs when the infused funds are not used for that purpose; the
The second instance of fraud as to any particular transaction is committed at the time that such a lender or investor is contractually due its realization on the fraudulently-pretensed transaction, and is paid. Here is where the rolling takes place: a second lender or investor (or more than one such if the perpetrator's needs require) is gulled in a similar fashion, into infusing on the pretense of an investment in a different transaction. Its later-made cash infusion is diverted to the satisfaction of earlier lenders' claims. The perpetration of fraud replicates, but the brunt of the perpetration rolls to a new generation of victim.
But under the facts before it — with no fraud to taint the original creation of the transferees' rights to payment from the debtor, or the repayment in satisfaction of them — the Finn court invoked only the main principle — repayment on "honest," valid debt gives reasonably equivalent value. On a fraud-free template, its reasoning went both to rejecting the presumption and sheltering the transfers before it from avoidance under either theory.
Finn does not acknowledge the actual-fraud exclusion from reasonably-equivalent value for dishonestly-incurred debt or fraudulently-enabled payment. But there is only one implication from its use of the full text of the precedent as quoted: the exclusion is still a feature of Minnesota law. Finn does not delete the references to the exclusion from its quotations from past case law. The opinion does not cast a bit of doubt on the continuing vitality of the exclusion, generally or in context.
For the purposes of the Trustee's avoidance litigation here, it is crucial to recognize
This is where the fraud exclusion to the permissible-preference construct rightly comes into play. The cumulation of fraudulent inducement pled here materially distinguishes the Trustee's avoidance litigation from the facts in Finn.
The old-time language of Finn's cited authority has special resonance here. One could quibble about what the court in Thompson v. Schiek meant in its reference to an "honest debt," the contractually regular payment of which could not be a fraudulent transfer, 213 N.W. at 912. But the phrase is best read in consonance with the times when the Minnesota Supreme Court originally used it — as denoting a debt incurred for legitimate purposes in the application of the credit or cash proceeds, and with pure intent not to defraud anyone — not to hoodwink the creditor in the inducement to lend or extend, not to victimize anyone else later when the debtor is to use its financial means to meet the obligation at the time of the satisfaction. A debt incurred and satisfied in the main sequence of a Ponzi scheme fails muster on every one of those considerations.
The same thought applies to the notion of a transfer, i.e. a payment, "honestly made" on an antecedent debt, as envisioned in Skinner v. Overend, 252 N.W. at 418-419 and Kummet v. Thielen, 298 N.W. at 246. A payment made with the knowing use of money misappropriated after fraud, to satisfy a debt originally contracted through a like fraud, would simply not have been considered "honestly made" in the first half of the 20th century.
This analysis dovetails with another part of Finn's articulation, that "any legally-enforceable right to payment against [sic] the debtor is sufficient to qualify as an antecedent debt under MUFTA," Finn, 860 N.W.2d at 651 — a payment in satisfaction of which would then qualify as value and reasonably equivalent value within the meaning of MUFTA. The outcome in Finn was driven by the receiver's inability to identify or prove a basis on
So: contrary to the defense's insistence here, in the case of a loan it is not enough that the dollars changed hands according to the facial tenor of the note, and a like amount plus interest just went back later. The older decisions make repeated references to debts honestly contracted in the first place and repaid with honest intent through honest means. These prominent pronouncements broaden the considerations beyond the abstract flow of money technically consistent with contractual terms. This is entirely consistent with the context in which the pronouncements were made, the application of fraudulent-transfer remedies — which lie in favor of third-party creditors that are divorced from the chicanery of a debtor-transferor, the possible complicity of a transferee, or both, but which nonetheless are harmed by such malfeasance. The older opinions impose a qualification, fair-and-square circumstances in payment, as the prerequisite for deeming reasonably equivalent value to the satisfaction of preexisting debt. That qualification bears right into the purpose of fraudulent-transfer remedies.
This is underlined by two different substantive approaches to that point of legal enforceability.
The first is that obligations of payment in either of the two lending or investment transactions in the sequence of a Ponzi scheme could be subject to the legal defense of unenforceability as to part or all of the obligations of the non-debtor party, for some part of the sequence up to final consummation, when all debt is paid off and both parties walk away. The unenforceability would come about as a result of the debtor's fraud in the inducement, and this would be a matter of law, not equity.
One can envision several scenarios where unenforceability could have been raised by a lender like the Opportunity Finance defendants at different points in the sequence of a lending transaction, on the very ground that Tom Petters had fraudulently induced them to lend. The argument could have been asserted properly to undo executory rights or obligations under the lending relationship:
In arguing for reasonable equivalence, the Opportunity Finance defendants insist that the note-debtors within the Petters enterprise structure were all legally bound to pay by the facial terms of their notes, and the inquiry goes no further than that. They say this point is cemented because PCI and the SPE-subsidiaries all got the money from the associated loans; and thus they were under a legally-enforceable duty of repayment.
This parses the concept of legal enforceability in a micro-focus. Finn's cited authority for the issue clearly enables a court to look beyond the face of the documents and the past flow of the funds alone.
These conclusions alone are enough to confine Finn to the specific transactional situations before the court there, where there was no proof that the circumstances were anything other than fair and square, or even any allegation to that effect. The Finn court did not make rulings of general applicability as to the nature of reasonably equivalent value across the entire breadth of a Ponzi scheme purveyor's business dealings.
Thus Finn itself does not bar the Trustee here from maintaining suit in avoidance on the grounds of constructive fraud; it cannot be said that reasonably equivalent value matched to a Debtor's transfer, as a matter of law.
Finn looks askance at the root-source of this analysis in Scholes v. Lehmann and its companion federal jurisprudence. 860 N.W.2d at 652. But however much it jibes at several of the foundational principles of the analysis, 860 N.W.2d at 652-653, Finn does so only in the service of one end: rejecting the Ponzi scheme presumption as to reasonably equivalent value. 860 N.W.2d at 653. That end-use gets rid of a fact-finding shortcut; but it did so only in a case brought on facts where a finding of reasonably equivalent value would have been amply supported outside of the context of receivership or bankruptcy. It says nothing about the alternate situation in the thick of a Ponzi scheme. There, the immediate, instinctive reaction of the Finn court, "well of course not!," just does not happen.
Finn cannot be read as a categorical rejection of the analysis previously adopted in In re Petters Co., Inc., 499 B.R. at 355-359. The Finn court had every opportunity to say the Second Memorandum erred in that substantive analysis. It never did so. Reading Finn to say that would be textually unsupported. Deeming it to read that way would mean that Finn went far beyond the appellate obligation to frame its ruling to address the specific facts before the court at that time, and none others. Finn therefore gives no reason to deny the continuing vitality of Scholes v. Lehmann and the other authority on which the Second Memorandum's ruling were based. There is still a viable theory for an equitable override that denies value to the interest component of repayment on debt owing by the perpetrator of a Ponzi scheme, incurred in transactions in the main sequential operation of the scheme, in an action for avoidance under MUFTA.
The analysis here was long, and may rightly be termed turgid. But it is offered to make sense of Finn's rulings in their original form, the true reach of which was somewhat obscure from the order of analysis and the syntactical sensibility of the opinion's text. The conclusion is that Finn does not vitiate the Trustee's case here, for recovery of at least the ostensible interest-component that the Debtors paid to the Opportunity Finance defendants and other investor-lenders into the Petters enterprise structure that the Trustee has sued in avoidance.
That conclusion is based on several component rulings, which are reprised here in parallel form to enable ready access for the Trustee's other proceedings in litigation. As follows:
As the parties contemplated and requested, these rulings are memorialized here without concrete application to the Opportunity Finance defendants' pending motion for dismissal or DZ Bank's pending motion for judgment on the pleadings. That application will be made later, after rulings on the balance of the multiple additional issues raised and presented by those defendants. The rulings in this memorialization will also be used in disposition of the related issues for the Trustee's pending motions for partial summary judgment in other adversary proceedings, when they are presented for decision on their merits. Ave atque vale.
860 N.W.2d at 642. For the present discussion, the impersonal pronoun will be used to signify the perpetrator, in the collective persons of the active individual and his corporate vehicle.
Peterson v. Somers Dublin, Ltd., 729 F.3d 741, 748 (7th Cir.2013).