Elawyers Elawyers
Ohio| Change

Prometheus Radio v. FCC, 03-3388 (2004)

Court: Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit Number: 03-3388 Visitors: 33
Filed: Jun. 24, 2004
Latest Update: Mar. 02, 2020
Summary: Opinions of the United 2004 Decisions States Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit 6-24-2004 Prometheus Radio v. FCC Precedential or Non-Precedential: Precedential Docket No. 03-3388 Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_2004 Recommended Citation "Prometheus Radio v. FCC" (2004). 2004 Decisions. Paper 537. http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_2004/537 This decision is brought to you for free and open access by the Opinions of t
More
                                                                                                                           Opinions of the United
2004 Decisions                                                                                                             States Court of Appeals
                                                                                                                              for the Third Circuit


6-24-2004

Prometheus Radio v. FCC
Precedential or Non-Precedential: Precedential

Docket No. 03-3388




Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_2004

Recommended Citation
"Prometheus Radio v. FCC" (2004). 2004 Decisions. Paper 537.
http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_2004/537


This decision is brought to you for free and open access by the Opinions of the United States Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit at Villanova
University School of Law Digital Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in 2004 Decisions by an authorized administrator of Villanova
University School of Law Digital Repository. For more information, please contact Benjamin.Carlson@law.villanova.edu.
                                                                       PRECEDENTIAL

        UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS FOR THE THIRD CIRCUIT

   Nos. 03-3388, 03-3577, 03-3578, 03-3579, 03-3580, 03-3581, 03-3582, 03-3651,
 03-3665, 03-3675, 03-3708, 03-3894, 03-3950, 03-3951, 03-4072, 03-4073 & 04-1956

                          PROMETHEUS RADIO PROJECT

                                           vs.

                  FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION;
                       UNITED STATES OF AMERICA


                   Prometheus Radio Project, Petitioner in No. 03-3388
                      Media General, Inc., Petitioner in No. 03-3577
             National Association of Broadcasters, Petitioner in No. 03-3578
   Network Affiliated Stations Alliance, ABC Television Affiliates Association, CBS
            Television Affiliates Association and NBC Television Affiliates,
                                Petitioners in No. 03-3579
            Fox Entertainment Group, Inc. and Fox Television Stations, Inc.,
                                Petitioners in No. 03-3580
                          Viacom Inc., Petitioner in No. 03-3581
National Broadcasting Company, Inc., and Telemundo Communications Group, Inc.,
                                Petitioners in No. 03-3582
                Sinclair Broadcast Group, Inc., Petitioner in No. 03-3651
                        Media Alliance, Petitioner in No. 03-3665
            Paxson Communications Corporation, Petitioner in No. 03-3675
National Council of the Churches of Christ in the United States, Petitioner in No. 03-3708
                      Tribune Company, Petitioner in No. 03-3894
            Paxson Communications Corporation, Petitioner in No. 03-3950
             Emmis Communications Corporation, Petitioner in No. 03-3951
          Center for Digital Democracy and Fairness & Accuracy in Reporting,
                                Petitioners in No. 03-4072
               Clear Channel Communications, Petitioner in No. 03-4073
 American Hispanic Owned Radio Association, Civil Rights Forum on Communications
 Policy, League of United Latin American Citizens, Minority Business Enterprise Legal
    Defense and Education Fund, Minority Media and Telecommunications Council,
  National Asian American Telecommunications Association, National Association of
 Latino Independent Producers, National Coalition of Hispanic Organizations, National
        Council of La Raza, National Hispanic Media Coalition, National Indian
     Telecommunications Institute, National Urban League, Native American Public
     Telecommunications, Inc., PRLDEF-Institute for Puerto Rican Policy, UNITY:
 Journalists of Color, Inc. and W omen’s Institute for Freedom of the Press, Petitioners in
                                      No. 04-1956


                          On Petition for Review of An Order of
                        the Federal Communications Commission
                                    (FCC No. 03-127)




                                Argued February 11, 2004

        Before: SCIRICA, Chief Judge, AM BRO and FUENTES, Circuit Judges

                                   (Filed June 24, 2004)

Andrew Jay Schwartzman, Esquire (Argued)
Cheryl A. Leanza, Esquire
Media Access Project
1625 K Street, N.W., Suite 1118
Washington, DC 20006
      Counsel for Prometheus Radio Project, Center for Digital Democracy and
      Fairness and Accuracy in Reporting

Shelby D. Green, Esquire
Pace University School of Law
78 North Broadway
White Plains, NY 10603
      Counsel for National Council of the Churches of Christ in the United States

Samuel L. Spear, Esquire
Spear Wilderman Borish Endy Spear & Runckel
230 South Broad Street, Suite 1400
Philadelphia, PA 19102
      Counsel for Prometheus Radio Project

Angela J. Campbell, Esquire (Argued)
James A. Bachtell, Esquire
Karen Henein, Esquire
Institute for Public Representation

                                             2
Georgetown University Law Center
600 New Jersey Avenue, N.W., Suite 312
Washington, DC 20001
      Counsel for Media Alliance and Office of Communication of the United Church of
      Christ, Inc.

Glen B. Manishin, Esquire (Argued)
Stephanie A. Joyce, Esquire
Kelley Drye & Warren LLP
8000 Towers Crescent Drive, Suite 1200
Vienna, VA 22182
      Counsel for Consumers Union and Consumer Federation of America

Robert A. Long, Jr., Esquire
Kevin C. Newsom, Esquire
Heidi C. Doerhoff, Esquire
Covington & Burling
1201 Pennsylvania Avenue, N.W.
Washington, DC 20004-1401
      Counsel for CBS Television Network Affiliates Association, NBC Television
      Affiliates and Network Affiliated Stations Alliance

Wade H. Hargrove, Esquire
Mark J. Prak, Esquire
Brooks, Pierce, Mclendon, Humphry & Leonard
1600 Wachovia Capitol Center
150 Fayetteville Street Mall
Raleigh, NC 27601
      Counsel for ABC Television Affiliates Association

Henk Brands, Esquire (Argued)
Patrick S. Campbell, Esquire
John H. Longwell, Esquire
Paul, Weiss, Rifkind, Wharton & Garrison LLP
1615 L Street, N.W., Suite 1300
Washington, DC 20036
       Counsel for Fox Entertainment Group, Inc., Fox Television Stations, Inc. and
       Viacom Inc.




                                           3
Michael K. Kellogg, Esquire
Mark L. Evans, Esquire
Kellogg, Huber, Hansen, Todd & Evans, PLLC
1615 M Street, N.W., Suite 400
Washington, DC 20036
      Counsel for National Broadcasting Company, Inc. and Telemundo
      Communications Group, Inc.

Donald B. Verrilli, Jr., Esquire (Argued)
Ian Heath Gershengorn, Esquire
Elaine J. Goldenberg, Esquire
Jenner & Block, LLC
601 Thirteenth Street, N.W., 12 th Floor
Washington, DC 20005

Henry L. Baumann, Esquire
Jack N. Goodman, Esquire
Jerianne Timmerman, Esquire
National Association of Broadcasters
1771 N Street, N.W.
Washington, DC 20036
       Counsel for National Association of Broadcasters

John R. Feore, Jr., Esquire
Michael D. Hays, Esquire
Kenneth D. Salomon, Esquire
M. Anne Swanson, Esquire
Theodore L. Radway, Esquire
Jason E. Rademacher, Esquire
Dow, Lohnes & Albertson, PLLC
1200 New Hampshire Avenue, N.W., Suite 800
Washington, DC 20036-6802
       Counsel for Millcreek Broadcasting, LLC, Media General, Inc., Simmons Media
       Group and Paxson Communications Corporation




                                            4
John E. Fiorini III, Esquire †
Helgi C. Walker, Esquire † *
Eve Klindera Reed, Esquire† *
Andrew G. McBride, Esquire*
Richard J. Bodorff, Esquire*
James R. Bayes, Esquire ††
Kathleen A. Kirby, Esquire ††
Richard E. Wiley, Esquire †† (Argued)
Martha E. Heller, Esquire ††
Wiley Rein & Fielding LLP
1776 K Street, N.W.
Washington, DC 20006
      †
        Counsel for Emmis Communications Corporation
      * Counsel for Clear Channel Communications, Inc.
      ††
           Counsel for Newspaper Association of America, Belo Corporation,
           Gannett Co., Inc. and Morris Communications Company, LLC

Kathryn R. Schmeltzer, Esquire (Argued)
Barry H. Gottfried, Esquire (Argued)
Tony Lin, Esquire
Paul A. Cicelski, Esquire
Scott R. Flick, Esquire
Christopher J. Sadowski, Esquire
Shaw Pittman LLP
2300 N Street, N.W.
Washington, DC 20037
       Counsel for Sinclair Broadcast Group, Inc. and Univision Communications Inc.

Miguel A. Estrada, Esquire (Argued)
Michael J. Edney, Esquire
Gibson, Dunn & Crutcher LLP
1050 Connecticut Avenue, N.W.
Washington, DC 20036
      Counsel for Clear Channel Communications, Inc.




                                            5
Carter G. Phillips, Esquire (Argued)
R. Clark W adlow, Esquire
Richard D. Klingler, Esquire
James P. Young, Esquire
Anita L. Wallgren, Esquire
Sidley Austin Brown & Wood LLP
1501 K Street, N.W.
Washington, DC 20005

Crane H. Kenney, Esquire
Tribune Company
435 N. Michigan Avenue
Chicago, IL 60611
      Counsel for Tribune Company

Jerome M. Marcus, Esquire (Argued)
Jonathan Auerbach, Esquire
Berger and Montague, P.C.
1622 Locust Street
Philadelphia, PA 19103

Dianne Smith, Esquire
Capitol Broadcasting Company, Inc.
2619 Western Blvd. 27606, Box 12000
Raleigh, NC 27605
      Counsel for Capitol Broadcasting Company, Inc.

David Honig, Esquire
Nicolaine Lazarre, Esquire (Argued)
Fatima Fofana, Esquire
Julie Smith, Esquire
Minority M edia and Telecommunications Council
3636 16 th Street N.W., #B-366
Washington, DC 20010
        Counsel for American Hispanic Owned Radio Association, Civil Rights Forum on
       Communications Policy, League of United Latin American Citizens, Minority
       Business Enterprise Legal Defense and Education Fund, Minority Media and
       Telecommunications Council, National Asian American Telecommunications
       Association, National Association of Latino Independent Producers, National
       Coalition of Hispanic Organizations, National Council of La Raza, National
       Hispanic Media Coalition, National Indian Telecommunications Institute,

                                          6
     National Urban League, Native American Public Telecommunications, Inc.,
     PRLDEF-Institute for Puerto Rican Policy, UNITY: Journalists of Color, Inc. and
    Women’s Institute for Freedom of the Press

Stephen D. Gavin, Esquire
Katrina C. Gleber, Esquire
Patton Boggs LLP
2550 M Street, N.W.
Washington, DC 20037
       Counsel for Nassau Broadcasting Holdings, Inc., and Nassau Broadcasting II,
       LLC

David A. Irwin, Esquire
Irwin, Campbell & Tannenwald
1730 Rhode Island Avenue, N.W., Suite 200
Washington, DC 20036
        Counsel for Family Stations, Inc., Sunbelt Communications Company, Press
        Communications, LLC and Diversified Communications

James L. Winston, Esquire
Rubin, Winston, Diercks, Harris & Cooke
1155 Connecticut Avenue, N.W., 6 th Floor
Washington, DC 20036
      Counsel for National Association of Black Broadcasters, Inc. and
      Rainbow Push Coalition, Inc.

R. Hewitt Pate, Assistant Attorney General
Makan Delrahim, Deputy Assistant Attorney General
Catherine G. O’Sullivan, Esquire
Nancy C. Garrison, Esquire
James J. Fredricks, Esquire
United States Department of Justice
Antitrust Division
601 D Street, N.W .
Patrick Henry Building
Washington, DC 20530
       Counsel for United States of America

John A. Rogovin, General Counsel (Argued)
Daniel M. Armstrong, Associate General Counsel
Jacob M. Lewis, Associate General Counsel (Argued)

                                          7
C. Grey Pash, Jr., Esquire
Nandan M. Joshi, Esquire
Federal Communications Commission
445 12 th Street, S.W.
Washington, DC 20554
       Counsel for the Federal Communications Commission




                                          OPINION OF THE COURT




                                                  Table of Contents




I.   Background . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16

        A.        The 1934 Communications Act and Early Broadcast Ownership

                  Regulation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16

        B.        Deregulation Initiatives             . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18

        C.        The Telecommunications Act of 1996 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19

        D.        Regulatory Review Since 1996 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20

        E.        The Commission’s 2003 Report and Order . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22

        F.        The Order’s Modification of Broadcast Media Ownership Rules . . . . . . 24

                  1.        Local Television Ownership . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24

                  2.        Local Radio Ownership . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25

                  3 & 4. Newspaper/Broadcast and Radio/Television Cross-Ownership . . 26

                  5.        National Television Ownership . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27


                                                              8
                  6.        Dual Network Rule . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28

         G.       Procedural History of the Current Appeals . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28

         H.       Subsequent Legislation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29

II.       Jurisdiction and Standard of Review . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30

         A.       Standard of Review Under the Administrative Procedure Act . . . . . . . . . 30

         B.       Standard of Review Considerations Under Section 202(h) . . . . . . . . . . . 32

                  1.        “Determine whether any such rules are necessary in the public

                            interest.” . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34

                  2.        “Repeal or modify any regulations it determines to be no longer

                            in the public interest.” . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40

         C.       Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43

III. Mootness and the National Television Ownership Rule . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43

IV. Cross-Ownership Rules . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46

         A.       Regulatory Background and the 2002 Biennial Review . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47

         B.       The Commission’s decision not to retain a ban on newspaper/broadcast

                  cross-ownership is justified under § 202(h) and is supported by record

                  evidence. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48

                  1.        Newspaper/broadcast combinations can promote localism. . . . . . . 49

                  2.        A blanket prohibition on newspaper/broadcast combinations is

                            not necessary to protect diversity. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51

         C.       The Commission’s decision to retain some limits on common ownership

                                                               9
               of different-type media outlets was constitutional and did not violate

               § 202(h). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52

               1.        Continuing to regulate cross-media ownership is in the public

                         interest. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53

               2.        Continuing to regulate cross-media ownership does not violate

                         the Fifth Amendment. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54

               3.        Continuing to regulate cross-media ownership does not violate

                         the First Amendment. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55

      D.       The Commission did not provide reasoned analysis to support the

               specific Cross-Media Limits that it chose. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57

               1.        Overview of the Commission’s Diversity Index Methodology . . . 58

               2.        The Commission did not justify its choice and weight of

                         specific media outlets. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62

               3.        The Commission did not justify its assumption of equal

                         market shares. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69

               4.        The Commission did not rationally derive its Cross-Media

                         Limits from the Diversity Index results. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 72

               5.        The Commission should provide better notice on remand. . . . . . . 76

V.   Local Television Ownership Rule . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78

      A.       Regulatory Background and the 2002 Biennial Review . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78

      B.       We uphold several threshold challenges to the Commission’s overall

                                                           10
               regulatory approach. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 80

               1.        Limiting local television station ownership is not duplicative of

                         antitrust regulation. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81

               2.        Media other than broadcast television may contribute to viewpoint

                         diversity in local markets. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 82

               3.        Consolidation can improve local programming. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84

               4.        The Commission adequately noticed its decision to allow

                         triopolies. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 85

      C.       We uphold the Commission’s decision to retain the top-four

               restriction. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 86

      D.       We remand the specific numerical limits for the Commission’s further

               consideration. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 90

      E.       We remand the Commission’s repeal of the Failed Station Solicitation

               Rule. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 94

VI.   Local Radio Ownership Rule . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 96

      A.       Regulatory Background and the 2002 Biennial Review . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97

      B.       We uphold the Commission’s new definition of local markets. . . . . . . . . 99

               1.        The Commission justified using Arbitron Metro markets. . . . . . . 100

               2.        The Commission justified including noncommercial stations. . . . 106

      C.       We uphold the Commission’s transfer restriction. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 107

               1.        Transfer restriction is “in the public interest.” . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 108

                                                            11
                2.        Transfer restriction is reasoned decisionmaking. . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109

                3.        Transfer restriction is constitutional. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 110

       D.       We affirm the attribution of Joint Sales Agreements. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 112

                1.        Attribution of JSAs is “necessary in the public interest.” . . . . . . 113

                2.        Attribution of JSAs is reasoned decisionmaking. . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113

                3.        Attribution of JSAs is constitutional. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 114

       E.       We remand the numerical limits to the Commission for further

                justification. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 115

                1.        The Commission’s numerical limits approach is rational and in

                          the public interest. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 118

                2.        The Commission did not support its decision to retain the

                          existing numerical limits with reasoned analysis. . . . . . . . . . . . . 119

                          a.        The Commission did not sufficiently justified “five

                                    equal-sized competitors” as the right benchmark. . . . . . . . 120

                          b.        The Commission did not sufficiently justified that the

                                    existing numerical limits actually ensure that markets

                                    will have five equal-sized competitors. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 121

                          c.        The Commission did not support its decision to retain the

                                    AM/FM subcaps. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 124

VII.   Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 124




                                                            12
AM BRO, Circuit Judge

       In these consolidated appeals we consider revisions by the Federal

Communications Commission to its regulations governing broadcast media ownership

that the Commission promulgated following its 2002 biennial review. On July 2, 2003,

the Commission announced a comprehensive overhaul of its broadcast media ownership

rules. It increased the number of television stations a single entity may own, both locally

and nationally; revised various provisions of the regulations governing common

ownership of radio stations in the same community; and replaced two existing rules

limiting common ownership among newspapers and broadcast stations (the

newspaper/broadcast cross-ownership rule and the radio/television cross-ownership rule)

with a single set of “Cross-Media Limits.” See Report and Order and Notice of Proposed

Rulemaking, 18 F.C.C.R. 13,620 (2003) (the “Order”).

       Several public interest and consumer advocacy groups (collectively, the “Citizen

Petitioners”)1 petitioned for judicial review of the Order in various courts of appeals,


  1
    For convenience we will use this designation throughout our opinion to refer, jointly
or severally, to the petitioners and intervenor who raise anti-deregulatory challenges to
the Order, including Prometheus Radio Project, Media Alliance, National Council of the
Churches of Christ in the United States, Fairness and Accuracy in Reporting, Center for
Digital Democracy, Consumer Union and Consumer Federation of America, Minority
Media and Telecommunications Council (representing numerous trade, consumer,
professional, and civic organizations concerned with telecommunications policy as it
relates to racial minorities and women), and Office of Communication of the United
Church of Christ (“UCC”) (intervenor).
        The Network Affiliated Stations Alliance, representing the CBS Television
Network Affiliates Association, the NBC Television Affiliates, and the ABC Television
Affiliates, and Capitol Broadcasting Company, Inc. (intervenor) also raised anti-

                                             13
contending that its deregulatory provisions contravened the Commission’s statutory

mandates as well as the Administrative Procedure Act, 5 U.S.C. §§ 551 et seq. (the

“APA”). Associations of networks, broadcasters, and newspaper owners 2 also challenged

the Order, arguing that pro-regulatory revisions as well as the absence of further

deregulation violate the Telecommunications Act of 1996, Pub. L. No. 104-104, 110 Stat.

56 (1996) (the “1996 Act”), the APA, and the United States Constitution. The Judicial

Panel on Multidistrict Litigation, acting pursuant to the random selection procedures of

28 U.S.C. § 2112(a), consolidated the petitions in this Court. On September 3, 2003, we

stayed implementation of the rules pending our review.

       For the reasons stated below, we affirm the power of the Commission to regulate

media ownership. In doing so, we reject the contention that the Constitution or § 202(h)

of the 1996 Act somehow provides rigid limits on the Commission’s ability to regulate in




deregulatory challenges to the national television ownership rule (see infra Parts I.F.5,
III).
  2
   Rather than identifying these petitioners and intervenors individually when discussing
their positions throughout this opinion, we refer to them collectively as the “Deregulatory
Petitioners.” They include: Clear Channel Communications, Inc.; Emmis
Communications Corporation; Fox Entertainment Group, Inc.; Fox Television Stations,
Inc.; Media General Inc.; National Association of Broadcasters; National Broadcasting
Company, Inc.; Paxson Communications Corporation; Sinclair Broadcast Group;
Telemundo Communications Group, Inc.; Tribune Company; Viacom Inc.; Belo
Corporation (intervenor); Gannett Corporation (intervenor); Morris Communications
Company (intervenor); Millcreek Broadcasting LLC (intervenor); Nassau Broadcasting
Holdings (intervenor); Nassau Broadcasting II, LLC (intervenor); Newspaper Association
of America (intervenor); and Univision Communications, Inc. (intervenor).


                                             14
the public interest. But we must remand certain aspects of the Commission’s Order that

are not adequately supported by the record. Most importantly, the Commission has not

sufficiently justified its particular chosen numerical limits for local television ownership,

local radio ownership, and cross-ownership of media within local markets. Accordingly,

we partially remand the Order for the Commission’s additional justification or

modification, and we partially affirm the Order. The stay will continue pending our

review of the Commission’s action on remand.3

                                     I.   Background

A.       The 1934 Communications Act and Early Broadcast Ownership Regulation

         In 1934 Congress authorized the Commission to grant licenses for private parties’



     3
    Our dissenting colleague asserts several times (indeed it is a principal theme) that we
somehow substitute our own policy judgment for that of the Commission. Our response
is simple. It is impossible to substitute our policy judgment for that of the Commission
when we have no view on its policies save that it act with reason. The proof for this
statement is that we do not reverse, but remand (and only in part).
       Differences with our dissenting colleague touch only some of the many issues
presented on appeal. He believes that the Commission’s work, while in part flawed,
comes close enough to merit our approval. Our response: not yet. He believes that any
imperfections and failings by the Commission can be rectified at the next quadrennial
review without the need for a court-ordered remand. Our response: to do so is to abdicate
the role assigned to us (see our standard of review discussion at Part II infra), a role,
incidentally, our colleague does not deny. What we do is not novel, as it reprises many of
the same reasoned analysis concerns expressed by the D.C. Circuit Court of Appeals in
Fox Television Stations v. FCC, 
280 F.3d 1027
(D.C. Cir. 2002), modified on reh’g, 
293 F.3d 537
(D.C. Cir. 2003), and Sinclair Broadcast Group Inc. v. FCC, 
284 F.3d 148
(D.C. Cir. 2002).
       The bottom line: the Commission gets another chance to justify its actions. Once
that occurs and the case returns to us, we may yet close the loop of agreement with our
colleague.

                                              15
exclusive use of broadcast frequencies. Recognizing that the finite radiofrequency

spectrum inherently limits the number of broadcast stations that can operate without

interfering with one another, Congress required that broadcast licensees serve the public

interest, convenience, and necessity. Communications Act of 1934, 47 U.S.C. § 309(a);

see also 
id. §§ 307(a),
310(d), 312.

       “In setting its licensing policies, the Commission has long acted on the theory that

diversification of mass media ownership serves the public interest by promoting diversity

of program and service viewpoints, as well as by preventing undue concentration of

economic power.” FCC v. Nat’l Citizens Comm. for Broad., 
436 U.S. 775
, 780 (1978)

(“NCCB”). The Commission’s early regulations reflected its presumption that a single

entity holding more than one broadcast license in the same community contravened

public interest. See Genesee Radio Corp., 5 F.C.C. 183, 186–87 (1938). In 1941, the

Commission announced that it would not license more than one station in the same area to

a single network organization. See Nat’l Broad. Co. v. United States, 
319 U.S. 190
,

206–08, 224–27 (1943) (upholding the rule). At the same time, the Commission

prohibited common ownership of stations within the same broadcast service (AM radio,

FM radio, and television) in the same community. See Rules Governing Standard and

High Frequency Broadcast Stations, 5 Fed. Reg. 2382, 2384 (June 26, 1940) (FM radio);

Rules Governing Standard and High Frequency Broadcast Stations, 6 Fed. Reg. 2282,

2284–85 (May 6, 1941) (television); Rules Governing Standard and High Frequency

Broadcast Stations, 8 Fed. Reg. 16065 (Nov. 27, 1943) (AM radio). Regulations limiting

                                            16
an entity to the common ownership of seven AM radio stations, seven FM radio stations,

and seven television stations survived judicial scrutiny in 1956. See United States v.

Storer Broad. Co., 
351 U.S. 192
(1956). In the 1970s the Commission adopted its first

cross-ownership bans, which prohibited, on a prospective basis, the common ownership

of television and radio stations serving the same market, as well as combinations of radio

or broadcast stations with a daily newspaper in the same community. Amendment of

Sections 73.35, 73.240 and 73.636 of the Commission Rules Relating to Multiple

Ownership of Standard, FM and Television Broadcast Stations, 22 F.C.C.2d 306, ¶ 5

(1970); Amendment of Sections 73.34, 73.240 and 73.636 of the Commission’s Rules

Relating to Multiple Ownership of Standard, FM, and Television Broadcast Stations, 50

F.C.C.2d 1046 (1975). The Supreme Court upheld the newspaper/broadcast cross-

ownership ban as a “reasonable means of promoting the public interest in diversified mass

communications.” 
NCCB, 436 U.S. at 802
.

B.     Deregulation Initiatives

       The 1980s saw a deregulatory trend for media ownership. The Commission raised

its national ownership limits to permit common ownership of 12 stations in each

broadcast service (though still prohibiting station combinations that would reach more

than 25% of the national audience). Amendment of Section 73.3555 (formerly 73.35,

73.240, and 73.636) of the Commission’s Rules Relating to Multiple Ownership of AM,

FM, and Television Broadcast Stations, 100 F.C.C.2d 74 ¶¶ 38, 39 (1985). The

Commission also determined that UHF television stations should not be deemed to have

                                            17
the same audience reach as VHF stations,4 due to “the inherent physical limitations of [the

UHF] medium,” and therefore applied a 50% “discount” to UHF audiences as counted

under the national audience limitation. 
Id. ¶¶ 42–44.
In other words, UHF stations count

only half of their audiences in determining compliance with the national television

ownership rule.

       In 1989 the Commission eased its “one to a market” radio/television cross-

ownership rules by allowing waiver requests for radio/television cross-ownership in the

25 largest television markets. The Commission stated that it would look favorably upon

requests for waivers where there would be 30 independently owned broadcast “voices”

remaining in the market after consolidation. Amendment of Section 73.3555 of the

Commission’s Rules, the Broadcast Multiple Ownership Rules, 4 F.C.C.R. 1741, ¶ 1

(1989). In 1992, the Commission relaxed local and national radio ownership restrictions

and adopted a tiered approach to radio concentration that allowed a single entity to own

more radio stations in the largest markets (up to three AM and three FM stations, subject

to a local audience reach limitation of 25% and a national cap of 30 AM stations and 30

FM stations) and fewer in the smallest markets. Revision of Radio Rules and Policies, 7

F.C.C.R. 6387, ¶ 27 (1992).



  4
   VHF (Very High Frequency) stations (channels 2 to 13), which broadcast on
frequencies between 30 and 300 MHz, can reach households up to 76 miles away. UHF
(Ultra High Frequency) stations (channels higher than 13), which broadcast between 300
and 3000 MHz—reach only 44 miles, and, consequently, far fewer non-cable households
than VHF stations. Order ¶ 586.

                                            18
C.     The Telecommunications Act of 1996

       In 1996 Congress overhauled the Communications Act by enacting the

Telecommunications Act of 1996. The 1996 Act contemplated a “pro-competitive, de-

regulatory national policy framework designed to accelerate rapidly private sector

development of advanced telecommunications and information technologies and services

to all Americans by opening all telecommunications markets to competition.” S. Rep.

No. 104–230, at 1–2 (1996). The 1996 Act eliminated all limits on national radio

ownership and raised the national television audience reach cap from 25% to 35%. 1996

Act §§ 202(a), (c)(1)(B), 110 Stat. at 110–11. Congress also eased local radio ownership

limits, establishing a four-tier sliding scale limit of numerical caps that allowed for as

many as eight co-owned radio stations in the largest markets. 
Id. § 202(b)(1),
110 Stat. at

110.

       The 1996 Act did not contain a new local television rule, but it directed the

Commission to “conduct a rulemaking proceeding to determine whether to retain, modify,

or eliminate” its existing local television ownership limitations. 
Id. § 202(c)(2),
110 Stat.

at 111. It also expanded the applicability of the one-to-a-market radio/television cross-

ownership restriction waiver to the fifty largest markets. 
Id. § 202(d),
110 Stat. at 111.

       Finally, the 1996 Act instructed the Commission to review biennially its broadcast

ownership rules “to determine whether any of such rules are necessary in the public

interest as the result of competition.” 
Id. § 202(h),
110 Stat. at 111–12. Section 202(h)

also required the Commission to “repeal or modify any regulation it determines to be no

                                              19
longer in the public interest.” 
Id. D. Regulatory
Review Since 1996

         In 1999 the Commission responded to Congress’s directive under § 202(c) of the

1996 Act to review its local television rule and announced that it would relax its

prohibition on the common ownership of television stations with overlapping signals.

The Commission’s new rule would allow two commonly owned television stations (a

television station “duopoly”) in the same Designated Market Area (“DMA” or “market”)

as long as (1) neither station was ranked among the four largest (“top-four”) stations in

the market and (2) eight independently owned stations remained in the market post-

merger. Review of the Commission’s Regulations Governing Television Broadcasting, 14

F.C.C.R. 12,903, ¶ 8 (1999) (“1999 Television Rule Review”). In the same rulemaking,

the Commission also relaxed the one-to-a-market radio/television cross-ownership

restriction and allowed radio/television station combinations to exist within three-tiered

limits that depend on the size of the market. 
Id. ¶ 9.5
         Meanwhile, in 1998 the Commission began the first biennial review of its

broadcast ownership regulations as required under § 202(h). In 2000 it announced that it

would retain the national television ownership rule (the 35% limit provided in the 1996



     5
   These limits allowed an entity to own one television station (or two if permitted under
the new local television rule) and (1) up to six radio stations in markets where at least 20
independent voices would remain post-merger, (2) up to four radio stations in markets
where at least 10 independent voices would remain post-merger, or (3) one radio station
notwithstanding the number of independent voices in the market. 
Id. 20 Act)
and its cable/broadcast cross-ownership rule after determining that both rules

remained “necessary in the public interest.” 1998 Biennial Regulatory Review—Review

of the Commission’s Broadcast Ownership Rules and Other Rules Adopted Pursuant to

Section 202 of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 15 F.C.C.R. 11,058, ¶ 4 (2000)

(“1998 Biennial Regulatory Review”).6 On appeal, however, the United States Court of

Appeals for the D.C. Circuit held that the Commission had not sufficiently explained its

reasons for retaining either of these rules. Fox Television Stations v. FCC, 
280 F.3d 1027
, 1043–44, 1051–52 (D.C. Cir. 2002) (“Fox I”), modified on reh’g, 
293 F.3d 537
(D.C. Cir. 2002) (“Fox II”). As for the national television ownership rule, the Court

determined that the agency had taken a “wait and see” approach in evaluating its

competition and diversity effects, which was impermissible in light of § 202(h)’s mandate

to repeal or modify rules found no longer necessary in the public interest. 
Id. at 1042.
It

remanded the rule to the Commission for additional justification. 
Id. at 1049.
The Court

vacated the cable/broadcast cross-ownership rule, however, finding that the

Commission’s decision to retain it was arbitrary and capricious and contrary to § 202(h).

Id. at 1053.

  6
    The Commission also announced that it would propose modification of the
newspaper/broadcast cross-ownership rule and the dual network rule (which allows a
broadcast station to affiliate with more than one network except that stations may not
affiliate with more than one of the four largest networks: ABC, CBS, Fox, and NBC, see
47 C.F.R. § 73.658(g)). The Commission also found that the local radio rule was
necessary in the public interest, but announced that it would seek further comments on
alternative methods for defining radio station markets. 1998 Biennial Regulatory Review
¶ 4.

                                             21
       A few months later, the same Court reviewed the local television multiple-

ownership rule. Sinclair Broad. Group, Inc. v. FCC, 
284 F.3d 148
(D.C. Cir. 2002). The

petitioner challenged the “eight independent voices” exception, contending that it lacked

foundation or connection to the Commission’s goal of promoting diversity in local

markets. 
Id. at 152.
The Court determined that the Commission had adequately justified

its decision to retain the local television rule under the APA and § 202(h), but that it had

not provided a rational basis for the exclusion of non-broadcast media from the eight

voices exception. 
Id. at 165.
It remanded the rule for the Commission’s further

justification. 
Id. at 169.
E.     The Commission’s 2003 Report and Order

       In September 2002 a Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (the “Notice”) announced

that the Commission would review four of its broadcast ownership rules pursuant to

§ 202(h): the 35% national audience reach limit remanded in Fox; the local television rule

remanded in Sinclair; the radio/television cross-ownership rule; and the dual network

rule. 2002 Biennial Regulatory Review Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 17 F.C.C.R.

18,503, ¶ 6 (2002). The Notice also advised that the Commission was incorporating into

its biennial review pending proceedings on two additional rules: its rule limiting radio

station ownership in local markets and its rule prohibiting newspaper/broadcast cross-

ownership. 
Id. ¶ 7.
       The Commission established a M edia Ownership Working Group (“M OW G”),

which commissioned twelve studies ranging from consumer surveys to economic

                                             22
analyses of media markets. These reports were released for public comment in October

2002. Interested parties filed thousands of pages of comments, consisting of legal, social,

and economic analyses, empirical and anecdotal evidence, and industry and consumer

data to respond to the issues identified in the Commission’s Notice. Notably, nearly two

million people weighed in by letters, postcards, e-mails, and petitions to oppose further

relaxation of the rules. Statement of Commissioner Jonathan S. Adelstein, Dissenting, 18

F.C.C.R. 13,974, 13,977 (July 2, 2003). The Commission also heard public comment at a

February 2003 “field hearing” in Richmond, Virginia.7

            On June 2, 2003, the Commission adopted the Order modifying its ownership rules

to provide a “new, comprehensive framework for broadcast ownership regulation” by a

vote of 3–2.8 Order ¶ 3. The Order was released on July 2, 2003.

F.          The Order’s Modification of Broadcast Media Ownership Rules

            After reaffirming the Commission’s three traditional policy objectives in

promoting the public interest—competition, diversity, and localism—Order ¶ 8, the

Commission considered whether each of the six rules remained in the public interest and

proposed modifications where it believed necessary. With respect to each of the rules, the

Commission determined as follows.


     7
   Two Commissioners (Jonathan S. Adelstein and Michael J. Copps) held and attended,
between them, thirteen additional public forums, using their own office resources.
Statement of Commissioner Michael J. Copps, Dissenting, 18 F.C.C.R. 13,951, 13,956
(July 2, 2003).
     8
         Commissioners Copps and Adelstein dissented.

                                                 23
       1.     Local Television Ownership

       The existing local television ownership rule allowed television station duopolies,

so long as at least one of the stations was not ranked among the market’s four largest

stations and so long as at least eight independently owned and operated full-power

television stations would remain in the market post-merger. 47 C.F.R. § 73.3555(b). The

Order modified this rule to permit television station triopolies in markets with 18 or more

television stations and television station duopolies in markets with 17 or fewer television

stations. Order ¶ 134. These limits are subject to the restriction (effectively a ban subject

to a waiver provision) that a single firm may not own more than one top-four station in a

market. This restriction forecloses common station ownership in markets with fewer than

five television stations. 
Id. ¶ 186.
The existing rule effectively precludes duopolies in

most markets; only the largest 70 markets of the nation’s 210 DM As could comply with

the “eight voices” test. Adelstein Dissent, 18 F.C.C.R. at 13,998. The new rule would

allow triopolies in the nine largest DMAs, which represent 25.2% of the population.

Duopolies could exist under the new rule in the largest 162 markets, representing 95.4%

of the nation’s population. 
Id. at 13,997–98.
       2.     Local Radio Ownership

       Although the Order retained the existing numerical limits on radio ownership that

Congress established in § 202(b) of the 1996 Act,9 it modified other aspects of the rule.


  9
   In the 1996 Act, Congress directed the Commission to revise the local radio
ownership limits to provide that: (1) in a radio market with 45 or more commercial radio

                                             24
First, it changed the method for determining radio markets by replacing the “contour-

overlap” method (described in detail in Part VI.B infra) with the geography-based market

delineations created by Arbitron, a company that generates market data for radio

advertisers. Order ¶ 239. Additionally, the Commission would now include

noncommercial stations in the station count for each market. 
Id. The Commission
grandfathered any existing radio station combinations rendered noncompliant under the

newly defined markets, 
id. ¶ 484,
but generally restricted transfer of these combinations,

id. ¶ 487.
The Commission also changed the local radio ownership rule by deciding to

attribute “Joint Sales Agreements” (agreements under which a licensee sells advertising

time on its station to a broker station for a fee) toward the brokering entity’s numerical

limit. 
Id. ¶ 239.
       3 & 4. Newspaper/Broadcast and Radio/Television Cross-Ownership

       The Commission has prohibited common ownership of a full-service television

broadcast station and a daily public newspaper in the same community since 1975.

Amendment of Sections 73.35, 73.240, and 73.636 of the Commission’s Rules Relating to




stations, a party may own up to 8 commercial radio stations, not more than 5 of which are
in the same service (AM or FM); (2) in a radio market with between 30 and 44
commercial radio stations, a party may own up to 7 commercial radio stations, not more
than 4 of which are in the same service; (3) in a radio market with between 15 and 29
commercial radio stations, a party may own up to 6 commercial stations, not more than 4
of which are in the same service; and (4) in a market with 14 or fewer commercial radio
stations, a party may own up to 5 commercial radio stations, not more than 3 of which are
in the same service, except that a party may not own more than 50 percent of the stations
in that market. 1996 Act, § 202(b)(1), 110 Stat. at 110.

                                             25
Multiple Ownership of Standard, FM, and Television Broadcast Stations, 50 F.C.C.2d

1046 (1975). Additionally, the Commission regulates the number of television and radio

stations that may be commonly owned with limits that vary with the size of the market.

47 C.F.R. § 73.3555(c).

       The Order announced the Commission’s decision to repeal both cross-ownership

rules (television/newspaper, radio/television) and replace them with a single set of Cross-

Media Limits. The Commission determined that neither cross-ownership prohibition

remained necessary in the public interest to ensure competition, diversity, or localism.

Order ¶¶ 330, 371. The new Cross-Media Limits prohibit newspaper/broadcast

combinations and radio/television combinations in the smallest DM As, i.e., those with

three or fewer full-power commercial or noncommercial television stations. 
Id. ¶ 454.
In

contrast, in the largest markets—those with more than eight television stations—common

ownership among newspapers and broadcast stations is unrestricted. 
Id. ¶ 473.
In

medium-sized markets—those with between four and eight television stations—one entity

may own a newspaper and either (a) one television station and up to 50% of the radio

stations that may be commonly owned in that market under the local radio rule or (b) up

to 100% of the radio stations allowed under the local radio rule. 
Id. ¶ 466.
       In structuring its Cross-Media Limits, the Commission drew upon a

methodological tool named the “Diversity Index,” which the Commission developed as a

measure of viewpoint diversity in local markets to identify those “at-risk” markets where

consolidation would have a deleterious effect. 
Id. ¶¶ 391,
442. The Diversity Index,

                                             26
explained more fully in Part IV.D.1 below, is a highly modified version of the formula for

measuring market concentration—the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index—applied by the

Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission to analyze mergers. 
Id. ¶ 428.
       5.     National Television Ownership

       The national television ownership rule prohibits entities from owning television

stations that in the aggregate reach a certain percentage of our country’s households. 47

C.F.R. § 73.3555(e)(1). Section 202(c) of the 1996 Act directed the Commission to

delete the then-existing twelve-station cap and raise the audience reach limit from 25% to

35%. After the D.C. Circuit Court remanded the Commission’s decision in the 1998

biennial review to retain the limit at 35%, Fox 
I, 280 F.3d at 1049
, the Commission

decided to increase the audience reach limit to 45%. Order ¶ 499. The Commission also

declined to repeal or modify its existing 50% discount for UHF stations’ audiences as

counted toward the audience reach limit. 
Id. ¶ 500.
       6.     Dual Network Rule

       Under the dual network rule, a television station may affiliate with more than one

network except that it may not affiliate with more than one of the four largest networks,

ABC, CBS, Fox, and NBC. 47 C.F.R. § 73.658(g). The rule effectively permits common

ownership of networks to the exclusion of the top four. Order ¶ 592. The Commission

determined that the dual network rule remained necessary in the public interest, and thus




                                            27
did not repeal or modify it. Id.10

G.        Procedural History of the Current Appeals

          Within days of the publication of the Order, several organizations filed petitions

for review of the Commission’s revised rules in various courts of appeals, some

contending that the Commission had gone too far in revising the rules, and others

asserting that the Commission had not gone far enough. Some of these organizations,

including the Prometheus Radio Project, filed their petitions in this Court. Under 28

U.S.C. § 2112(a), petitions to review administrative orders filed in different circuit courts

within the first ten days of the appeal period trigger a lottery conducted by the Judicial

Panel on Multidistrict Litigation. On August 19, 2003, the Panel announced that our

Court had been selected in the lottery and consolidated the appeals here. We entered a

stay of the effective date of the proposed rules after a hearing on September 3, 2003.

Prometheus Radio Project v. FCC, No. 03-3388, 
2003 WL 22052896
(3d Cir. Sept. 3,

2003). We then denied the Deregulatory Petitioners’ motion, joined by the Commission,

to transfer venue to the D.C. Circuit Court on September 16, 2003. Prometheus Radio

Project v. FCC, No. 03-3388 (3d Cir. Sept. 16, 2003) (order denying motion to transfer).

After pushing back briefing and oral argument at the request of the parties, on February

11, 2004, we heard approximately eight hours of oral argument addressing the merits of

Petitioners’ claims.



  10
       No party to this case challenges the retention of this rule.

                                                 28
H.       Subsequent Legislation

         In January 2004, while the petitions to review the Order were pending in this

Court, Congress amended the 1996 Act by increasing from 35% to 39% the national

television ownership rule’s audience reach cap in § 202(c). Consolidated Appropriations

Act, 2004, Pub. L. No. 108-199, § 629, 118 Stat. 3, 99 (2004). The legislation also

amended § 202(h) in two ways: (1) making the Commission’s biennial review obligation

quadrennial; and (2) insulating from § 202(h) review “rules relating to the 39 percent

national audience reach limitation.” 118 Stat. at 100. Prior to oral argument, Petitioners

filed letter briefs addressing the effect of these amendments on their challenges to the

Order.

                         II. Jurisdiction and Standard of Review

         This is an appeal of an agency decision under the Communications Act of 1934, 47

U.S.C. §§ 151 et seq. Our jurisdiction is based on 47 U.S.C. § 402(a) and 28 U.S.C.

§ 2342(1). Our standard of review is governed by the APA and the 1996 Act provision

authorizing the Commission’s periodic regulatory review.11


  11
    The Deregulatory Petitioners raise an additional threshold argument that Fox and
Sinclair provide the “law of the case” because the Order results in part from the D.C.
Circuit Court’s remand in those two decisions. Though we recognize that the Order must
be consistent with these remand directives, the decisions themselves do not fit within the
law of the case doctrine, under which a prior decision binds only future proceedings in the
“same litigation.” See, e.g., Hamilton v. Leavy, 
322 F.3d 776
, 786–87 (3d Cir. 2003).
This case involves petitions for review of the Commission’s comprehensive
reexamination of a larger set of its broadcast ownership rules, in which a different set of
parties participated, a different record was compiled, and different results were reached.
So understood, the law of the case doctrine does not constrain our review here.

                                              29
A.     Standard of Review Under the Administrative Procedure Act

       Our standard of review in the agency rulemaking context is governed first by the

judicial review provision of the APA, 5 U.S.C. § 706. Under it, we “hold unlawful or set

aside agency action, findings, and conclusions” that are found to be “arbitrary,

capricious, an abuse of discretion, or otherwise not in accordance with the law . . . [or]

unsupported by substantial evidence.” 
Id. § 706(2)(a),
(e); N.J. Coalition for Fair Broad.

v. FCC, 
574 F.2d 1119
, 1125 (3d Cir. 1978).

       The scope of review under the “arbitrary and capricious” standard is “narrow, and

a court is not to substitute its judgment for that of the agency.” Motor Vehicle Mfrs.

Ass’n v. State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co., 
463 U.S. 29
, 43 (1983) (“State Farm”).

Nevertheless, we must ensure that, in reaching its decision, the agency examined the

relevant data and articulated a satisfactory explanation for its action, including a “rational

connection between the facts found and the choice made.” 
Id. (quoting Burlington
Truck

Lines, Inc. v. United States, 
371 U.S. 156
, 168 (1962)). Normally, we may find an

agency rule is arbitrary and capricious where

       the agency has relied on factors which Congress has not intended it to
       consider, entirely failed to consider an important aspect of the problem,
       offered an explanation for its decision that runs counter to the evidence
       before the agency, or is so implausible that it could not be ascribed to a
       difference in view or the product of agency expertise. The reviewing court
       should not attempt itself to make up for such deficiencies; we may not
       supply a reasoned basis for the agency’s action that the agency itself has not
       given.

Id. (citing SEC
v. Chenery Corp., 
332 U.S. 194
, 196 (1947)); see also Robert Wood


                                              30
Johnson Univ. Hosp. v. Thompson, 
297 F.3d 273
, 280 (3d Cir. 2002). Put another way,

we reverse an agency’s decision when it “is not supported by substantial evidence, or the

agency has made a clear error in judgment.” AT&T Corp. v. FCC, 
220 F.3d 607
, 616

(D.C. Cir. 2000) (citing Kisser v. Cisneros, 
14 F.3d 615
, 619 (D.C. Cir. 1994)).

         We will, however, “uphold a decision of less than ideal clarity if the agency’s path

may reasonably be discerned.” State 
Farm, 463 U.S. at 43
(quoting Bowman Transp.,

Inc. v. Arkansas-Best Freight Sys., Inc., 
419 U.S. 281
, 286 (1974)). But an agency that

departs from its “former views” is “obligated to supply a reasoned analysis for the change

beyond that which may be required when an agency does not act in the first instance” in

order to survive judicial scrutiny for compliance with the APA. State 
Farm, 463 U.S. at 41
–42.

         Finally, the traditional APA standard of review is even more deferential “where

the issues involve ‘elusive’ and ‘not easily defined’ areas such as programming diversity

in broadcasting.” 
Sinclair, 284 F.3d at 159
. Yet even when an administrative order

involves policy determinations on such elusive goals, a “rationality” standard is

appropriate. See 
NCCB, 436 U.S. at 796
–97 (finding that the Commission acted

rationally in determining that diversification of ownership would enhance the possibility

of increasing diverse viewpoints). Additionally, when an agency has engaged in line-

drawing determinations and our review is necessarily deferential to agency expertise, see

AT&T 
Corp., 220 F.3d at 627
, its decisions may not be “patently unreasonable” or run

counter to the evidence before the agency. 
Sinclair, 284 F.3d at 162
.

                                              31
B.        Standard of Review Considerations Under Section 202(h)

          The Order was promulgated as part of the periodic review requirements of

§ 202(h) of the 1996 Act. Consequently, our review standard is informed by that

provision, which, at the time of the Order’s release, read:

          (h) Further Commission Review. The Commission shall review its rules
          adopted pursuant to this section and all of its ownership rules biennially[12 ]
          as part of its regulatory reform review under section 11 of the
          Communications Act of 1934 and shall determine whether any of such rules
          are necessary in the public interest as the result of competition. The
          Commission shall repeal or modify any regulation it determines to be no
          longer in the public interest.

110 Stat. 111–12. Section 11 of the Communications Act, to which § 202(h) refers, was

also added by the 1996 Act to ensure that the Commission review periodically its

regulations governing telecommunications services to “determine whether any such

regulation is no longer necessary in the public interest as a result of meaningful economic

competition between providers of such service” and “repeal or modify any regulation it

determines to be no longer necessary in the public interest.” 47 U.S.C. § 161.

          The text and legislative history of the 1996 Act indicate that Congress intended

periodic reviews to operate as an “ongoing mechanism to ensure that the Commission’s

regulatory framework would keep pace with the competitive changes in the marketplace”

resulting from that Act’s relaxation of the Commission’s regulations, including the

broadcast media ownership regulations. 2002 Biennial Regulatory Review, 18 F.C.C.R.


     12
   As noted in Part I.H above, Congress has since replaced “biennially” with
“quadrennially” in this provision.

                                                32
4726, ¶¶ 16, 17 (2003) (citing preamble to the 1996 Act; H.R. Conf. Rep. No. 104-458

(1996)). Put another way, the periodic review provisions require the Commission to

“monitor the effect of . . . competition . . . and make appropriate adjustments” to its

regulations. 
Id. ¶ 5.
       As noted, the first sentence of § 202(h) requires the Commission to “determine”

whether media concentration rules are “necessary in the public interest as the result of

competition.” The second sentence contains a separate instruction to the Commission: to

“repeal or modify” those rules “no longer in the public interest.” 110 Stat. 111–12. We

analyze each of these instructions in turn.

       1.     “Determ ine whether any such rules are necessary in the public
              interest.”

       Recognizing that competitive changes in the media marketplace could obviate the

public necessity for some of the Commission’s ownership rules, the first instruction

requires the Commission to take a fresh look at its regulations periodically in order to

ensure that they remain “necessary in the public interest.” This raises the question of

what is “necessary.”

       In the context of § 11 of the Communications Act, 47 U.S.C. § 161—which, like

§ 202(h), requires the Commission periodically to review its telecommunications

regulations and determine whether they “remain necessary in the public interest”—the

Commission has interpreted “necessary” to mean “useful,” “convenient” or “appropriate”

rather than “required” or “indispensable.” Setting out its rationale for this interpretation


                                              33
in the 2002 Biennial Regulatory Review, 18 F.C.C.R. 4726, ¶¶ 14–22 (2003), the

Commission determined that the 1996 Act’s legislative history indicated that Congress

meant “no longer necessary” to mean “no longer in the public interest” and “no longer

meaningful.” 18 F.C.C.R. 4726, ¶ 17 (citing H.R. Conf. Rep. No. 104-458, at 185

(1996)).

       Next, the Commission found that an “indispensable” construction of “necessary”

as to § 11 would be unreasonably inconsistent with the Communications Act’s grant of

general rulemaking authority to the Commission. 
Id. ¶ 18
n.31. Under 47 U.S.C.

§ 201(b) the Commission is authorized to “prescribe such rules and regulations [regarding

services and charges of communications common carriers] as may be necessary in the

public interest to carry out the provisions of this Act.” In AT&T Corp. v. Iowa Utilities

Board, the Supreme Court interpreted this provision as a grant of “general rulemaking

authority.” 
525 U.S. 366
, 374 (1999). Characterizing this interpretation “not as a

limitation on the Commission’s authority, but a confirmation of it,” the Commission

concluded that the standard of review applicable to its rulemaking authority under § 201

is a “plain public interest” standard. 18 F.C.C.R. 4276, ¶¶ 18 n.31, 22 
(citing 525 U.S. at 374
, 378). The Commission reasoned that the same standard must also apply to the

review process required under § 11 in order to avoid absurd results. If the rulemaking

and review standards were different, the Commission could promulgate any rule that is

useful, but then, at the next periodic review, would have to revoke any of those rules that

do not also meet a higher standard of “indispensable.” 
Id. ¶ 18
& n.33. Under such a

                                            34
system, periodic review would either be inefficient or irrelevant, as the Commission could

effectively sidestep the more stringent review standard by subsequently reissuing any

“useful” rule that it had to repeal for failing to be “indispensable.” 
Id. ¶ 18
.

       Lastly, the Commission rejected arguments that there is controlling judicial

precedent for an “indispensable” construction of “necessary.” It acknowledged that the

Supreme Court and the D.C. Circuit Court of Appeals have upheld such constructions, see

id. ¶ 19
(citing Iowa Utils. 
Bd., 525 U.S. at 374
, 378; GTE Serv. Corp. v. FCC, 
205 F.3d 416
(D.C. Cir. 2000)), but countered that these cases “simply demonstrate that terms such

as ‘necessary’ . . . must be read in their statutory context.” 
Id. Furthermore, the
Commission found judicial support for its interpretation of “necessary” in the D.C.

Circuit Court’s decision in 
Sinclair, 284 F.3d at 159
, regarding the Commission’s

periodic review of its local television ownership rule under § 202(h). The Commission

noted that the Sinclair Court did not expressly adopt any particular definition of

“necessary,” but, in affirming the Commission’s § 202(h) finding that the rule furthers

diversity and is thus necessary in the public interest, 
id. at 160,
it “did not articulate a new

or higher public interest yardstick.” 18 F.C.C.R. 4726, ¶ 20.13 Nor did the D.C. Circuit

Court’s decision in Fox foreclose its interpretation of “necessary,” the Commission



  13
    More generally, the Commission cited several Supreme Court decisions interpreting
“necessary” to mean “useful” or “convenient” or “appropriate.” 
Id. ¶ 15
n.24 (citing,
inter alia, McCulloch v. Maryland, 17 U.S. (4 Wheat.) 316, 413 (1819) (under the
Constitution’s Necessary and Proper Clause, U.S. Const. Art. I, § 8, cl. 18, “necessary”
means “convenient” or “useful”)).

                                              35
determined, because on rehearing the Court deleted language in its initial decision that the

Commission had applied too lax a standard in reviewing its broadcast media ownership

rules under § 202(h).14 
Id. ¶ 14
(citing Fox 
II, 293 F.3d at 540
).

       For these reasons, the Commission determined that § 11’s requirement that it

review its telecommunications regulations to determine whether they remain “necessary

in the public interest” does not require it to employ a more stringent standard than “plain

public interest” found in other parts of the Communications Act. 
Id. ¶¶ 18,
22 (citing 47

U.S.C. § 201(b) as an example).

       Recently, the D.C. Circuit Court upheld, in the context of § 11, the Commission’s

interpretation of “necessary” contained in the 2002 Biennial Regulatory Review. Cellco

P’ship v. FCC, 
357 F.3d 88
(D.C. Cir. 2004). Recognizing that “necessary” is a

“chameleon-like” word whose “meaning . . . may be influenced by its context,” the Cellco

Court determined that it would uphold any reasonable interpretation that did not

contravene the express provisions of the Communications Act. 
Id. at 94,
96 (citing

Chevron U.S.A., Inc. v. Natural Res. Def. Council, Inc., 
467 U.S. 837
, 842–43 (1984)). It

went on to determine that the Commission’s interpretation is both reasonable and

consistent with the Communications Act, endorsing the Commission’s view that

“necessary” must mean the same thing in the periodic review context as in the rulemaking


  14
     In addressing available remedies, the Fox I Court interpreted “necessary” to mean that
“a regulation should be retained only insofar as it is necessary in, not merely consonant
with, the public 
interest.” 280 F.2d at 1050
. This language was expressly excised in Fox
II, 293 F.3d at 540
.

                                             36
context in order to avoid absurd results. 
Id. at 98.
       Cellco also acknowledged that the Commission’s interpretation of “necessary” is

consistent with the many courts that have endorsed a “useful” or “appropriate”

interpretation over an “essential” or “indispensable” one. 
Id. at 97
(citing, inter alia,

NCCB, 436 U.S. at 795
–96; McCulloch v. Maryland, 17 U.S. (4 Wheat.) 316, 413 (1819);

Cellular Telecomm. & Internet Ass’n v. FCC, 
330 F.3d 502
, 510 (D.C. Cir. 2003)

(specifically rejecting an “indispensable” connotation of “necessary” as used in the

Communications Act’s enforcement forbearance provision, § 10(a))).

       Finally, the Cellco Court rejected suggestions that the Commission’s interpretation

was inconsistent with its prior decisions in Sinclair and Fox. As noted above, Sinclair did

not expressly adopt any particular definition of “necessary” and Fox I’s suggestion of a

heightened standard was expressly retracted by Fox 
II, 293 F.3d at 540
. Cellco limited

Fox I’s statement that “necessary” implied a presumption in favor of modification or

elimination of existing regulations, 
see 280 F.3d at 1048
, to the context in which it was

made: discussing whether vacating or remanding the national television ownership rule

was the appropriate remedy. 
Cellco, 357 F.3d at 98
. And while Sinclair apparently

endorsed this language from Fox I, 
see 284 F.3d at 159
, the Cellco Court characterized

Sinclair as merely “piggyback[ing]” on Fox I without “adopt[ing] a general presumption

in favor of modification or elimination of regulations when considering a substantive

challenge to the adequacy of the Commission’s determinations.” 
Cellco, 357 F.3d at 98
.

In sum, the D.C. Circuit Court determined that the definition of “necessary” was not

                                              37
constrained by either its Fox or Sinclair decision. It remained an open issue for the

Commission to decide in the first instance, as it did when it released the 2002 Biennial

Regulatory Review. 
Id. For the
same reasons proffered by the Commission and endorsed by the D.C.

Circuit Court to reject the “indispensable” definition of “necessary” under § 11, we do so

under § 202(h). Though § 11 and § 202(h) are separate statutory provisions, they are both

periodic review provisions from the same statute. As evidence of their relatedness,

§ 202(h) imposes periodic review obligations “as part of its regulatory reform review

under section 11 of this Communications Act of 1934,” 110 Stat. at 111.15 We see no

reason to adopt a different definition of “necessary” under § 202(h) than under § 11.

Moreover, interpreting § 202(h)’s first sentence to require the Commission to review its

rules to determine whether they are indispensable in the public interest would lead to

incongruous results when compared to the instruction in § 202(h)’s second sentence,

which requires the Commission to “repeal or modify any regulation it determines to be no

longer in the public interest.” 16 For the “determine” instruction to be meaningful,




  15
    Additionally, the Commission itself impliedly incorporated the 2002 Biennial
Regulatory Review’s interpretation of “necessary” under § 11 when citing it in the “legal
framework” section of the Order. Order ¶ 11 n.15.
  16
     Because § 202(h) omits the word “necessary” in the “repeal or modify” instruction, it
is arguably even more amenable to the “appropriate” or “useful” connotation of
“necessary” than § 11. But like the Commission, “we do not think that difference
[between § 11 and § 202(h)] is significant given what we believe ‘necessary in the public
interest’ means.” 18 F.C.C.R. 4726, ¶ 14 n.20.

                                             38
“necessary” must embody the same “plain public interest” standard that Congress set out

in the “repeal or modify” instruction.17 Lastly, as explained by the Cellco Court, the

“convenient,” “useful,” or “helpful” definition of “necessary” is not foreclosed to the

Commission by any judicial precedent, including Fox and Sinclair. So in interpreting the

Commission’s obligation under § 202(h) to review its broadcast media ownership rules to

determine whether they are “necessary in the public interest,” we adopt what the

Commission termed “the plain public interest” standard under which “necessary” means

“convenient,” “useful,” or “helpful,” not “essential” or “indispensable.”

       2.     “Repeal or modify any regulations it determines to be no longer in the
              public interest.”

       Turning to the second instruction of § 202(h), the Commission is required to

“repeal or modify” rules that are “no longer in the public interest.” Having concluded

that the first instruction requires the Commission to determine whether any existing rule

fails to satisfy the “plain public interest” standard, the relationship between the first and


  17
    Anticipating the argument that consistency between the first and second sentences
could still be achieved using the “indispensable” interpretation of “necessary” for both,
we respond that requiring the Commission to repeal or modify any regulations it
determined were not essential to the public interest would lead to incongruous results
when compared to the plain public interest standard that governs the Commission’s
authority to regulate the broadcast industry. See 
NCCB, 436 U.S. at 796
(“[S]o long as
the regulations are not an unreasonable means for seeking to achieve the [Commission’s
public interest] goals, they fall within [its] general rulemaking authority” under the
Communications Act.). Just as the Commission and Cellco observed in the § 11 context,
the “repeal or modify” instruction would be meaningless because the Commission could
repromulgate (in its rulemaking functions) under the lower “useful” standard any
regulation it was forced to repeal or modify for not being “indispensable” under § 202(h).


                                              39
second instruction is evident. Under the second instruction, the Commission must repeal

or modify the regulations that it has determined under the first instruction do not satisfy

that same standard.

       While we acknowledge that § 202(h) was enacted in the context of deregulatory

amendments (the 1996 Act) to the Communications Act, see Fox 
I, 280 F.3d at 1033
;

Sinclair, 284 F.3d at 159
, we do not accept that the “repeal or modify in the public

interest” instruction must therefore operate only as a one-way ratchet, i.e., the

Commission can use the review process only to eliminate then-extant regulations. For

starters, this ignores both “modify” and the requirement that the Commission act “in the

public interest.” What if the Commission reasonably determines that the public interest

calls for a more stringent regulation? Did Congress strip it of the power to implement

that determination? The obvious answer is no, and it will continue to be so absent clear

congressional direction otherwise.18

       What, then, makes § 202(h) “deregulatory”? It is this: Section 202(h) requires the

Commission periodically to justify its existing regulations, an obligation it would not

otherwise have. A regulation deemed useful when promulgated must remain so. If not, it

must be vacated or modified.


  18
    For example, in enacting a periodic review requirement for the Commission’s
broadcast media ownership regulations, Congress gave no express indication that it
intended to restrict the Commission’s rulemaking authority. See, e.g., Am. Hosp. Ass’n v.
NLRB, 
499 U.S. 606
, 613 (1991) (stating that “if Congress had intended to curtail in a
particular area the broad rulemaking authority [it has] granted[,] . . . we would have
suspected it to do so in language expressly describing an exception [to that authority]”)

                                             40
          Misguided by the Fox and Sinclair Courts’ “deregulatory presumption”

characterization and lacking the benefit of Cellco’s subsequent clarification, the

Commission concluded that § 202(h) “appears to upend traditional administrative law

principles” by not requiring it to justify affirmatively a rule’s repeal or modification.

Order ¶ 11. This overstates the case. Rather than “upending” the reasoned analysis

requirement that under the APA ordinarily applies to an agency’s decision to promulgate

new regulations (or modify or repeal existing regulations), see State 
Farm, 463 U.S. at 43
, § 202(h) extends this requirement to the Commission’s decision to retain its existing

regulations. This interpretation avoids a crabbed reading of the statute under which we

would have to infer, without express language, that Congress intended to curtail the

Commission’s rulemaking authority and to contravene “traditional administrative law

principles.” 19

C.        Conclusion

          Though our standard of review analysis is lengthy, it is in the end amenable to a

straightforward summing-up: In a periodic review under § 202(h), the Commission is


     19
    A purely textual inquiry is also of no avail to the Deregulatory Petitioners. As we
noted above, § 202(h) does not use the word “necessary” in the second sentence to qualify
the public interest standard that governs the Commission’s “repeal or modify” instruction.
Like the Commission (as we point out in 
note 16 supra
), “we do not think that
difference . . . is significant given what we believe ‘necessary in the public interest’
means.” 18 F.C.C.R. 4726, ¶ 14 n.20. But even if “necessary in the public interest”
under the first sentence meant “indispensable,” we still would not have to import that
heightened standard to the second. Textually it is not there. If “necessary” appears twice
in § 11 and in the first sentence of § 202(h), but is absent from its second sentence, logic
favors deliberate omission by Congress over inadvertence.

                                               41
required to determine whether its then-extant rules remain useful in the public interest; if

no longer useful, they must be repealed or modified.20 Yet no matter what the

Commission decides to do to any particular rule— retain, repeal, or modify (whether to

make more or less stringent)—it must do so in the public interest and support its decision

with a reasoned analysis. We shall evaluate each aspect of the Commission’s Order

accordingly.

               III. Mootness and the National Television Ownership Rule

       The national television ownership rule caps the number of television stations that a

single entity may own on a national basis. In the 1996 Act, Congress limited the number

of commonly owned stations to those reaching no more than 35% of the national

audience. 1996 Act § 202(c)(1)(B), 110 Stat. 111. In its first biennial review, the

Commission retained the 35% cap as “necessary in the public interest,” but the D.C.

Circuit Court held that the Commission had not adequately justified this decision. Fox 
I, 280 F.3d at 1048
. On remand and in connection with its 2002 biennial review

proceeding, the Commission increased the cap from 35% to 45%. Order ¶ 583. The

Commission also decided to retain its method of discounting by 50% the audiences of

UHF stations toward the cap. 
Id. ¶ 586.


  20
    Although our dissenting colleague states that he differs “from the majority on the
applicable standard of review,” we can discern no real disagreement between his
formulation of the standard of review and ours. Rather, we see disagreement only over
the question of whether the Commission’s Order survives the standard of review as we
both have described it.

                                             42
       Subsequently, however, Congress enacted a new national television ownership

cap. In its 2004 Consolidated Appropriations Act, it modified § 202(c)(1)(B) of the 1996

Act to provide that “[t]he Commission shall modify its rules for multiple

ownership . . . by increasing the national audience reach limitation for television stations

to 39%.” See Pub. L. No. 108-199, § 629, 118 Stat. 3, 99 (2004). Because the

Commission is under a statutory directive to modify the national television ownership cap

to 39%, challenges to the Commission’s decision to raise the cap to 45% cap are moot. 21

Cf. PLMRS Narrowband Corp. v. FCC, 
182 F.3d 995
, 1002 (D.C. Cir. 1999) (challenges

to Commission’s later-modified order are moot).

       Although the 2004 Consolidated Appropriations Act did not expressly mention the

UHF discount, challenges to the Commission’s decision to retain it are likewise moot.

Congress instructed the Commission to “increase the national audience reach limitation

for television stations to 39%.” 118 Stat. at 99. Since 1985 the Commission has defined

“national audience reach” to mean “the total number of television households” reached by

an entity’s stations, except that “UHF stations shall be attributed with 50 percent of the


  21
    The Deregulatory Petitioners stated that the Commission’s rationale for retaining a
national television ownership limit “raises troubling First Amendment questions.” Br. of
Petitioners Fox, NBC, Telemundo, and Viacom (“Network Petitioners”) at 31. We
recognize that a constitutional challenge would not necessarily be mooted by intervening
legislation. But even if we interpreted this “troubling . . . questions” language as raising a
constitutional challenge to the 45% national audience reach limit, we see no reason to
decide the constitutionality of Congress’s 39% limit, as these same Petitioners
subsequently argued that “any pending challenges to the June order [regarding the
national television ownership rule] will be mooted” by the 2004 Consolidated
Appropriations Act. Network Petitioners’ Letter Br. at 2 (Feb. 2, 2004).

                                             43
television households” reached. 47 C.F.R. § 73.3555(e)(2)(i); Multiple Ownership of AM,

FM and Television Broadcast Stations, 50 Fed. Reg. 4666, 4676 (Feb. 1, 1985). W e

assume that when Congress uses an administratively defined term, it intended its words to

have the defined meaning. See, e.g., Bragdon v. Abbott, 
524 U.S. 624
, 631 (1998).

Furthermore, because reducing or eliminating the discount for UHF station audiences

would effectively raise the audience reach limit, we cannot entertain challenges to the

Commission’s decision to retain the 50% UHF discount. Any relief we granted on these

claims would undermine Congress’s specification of a precise 39% cap.

       As additional evidence of the mootness of challenges to the UHF discount, we note

that the 2004 Consolidated Appropriations Act also added a sentence to § 202(h): “This

subsection does not apply to any rules relating to the 39% national audience limitation.”

118 Stat. at 100. The UHF discount is a rule “relating to” the national audience

limitation. See 47 C.F.R. § 73.3555(e)(2) (providing for the UHF discount in a section

qualified “for the purposes of this paragraph (e),” the national television ownership rule

paragraph). Congress apparently intended to insulate the UHF discount from periodic

review, a position that is consistent with our reading of the legislation as endorsing the

almost 20-year-old regulatory definition of “national audience reach” that provides for the

UHF discount.

       Although we find that the UHF discount is insulated from this and future periodic

review requirements, we do not intend our decision to foreclose the Commission’s

consideration of its regulation defining the UHF discount in a rulemaking outside the

                                             44
context of Section 202(h). The Commission is now considering its authority going

forward to modify or eliminate the UHF discount and recently accepted public comment

on this issue. 69 Fed. Reg. 9216–17 (Feb. 27, 2004). Barring congressional intervention,

see, e.g., S. 1264, 108th Cong. § 12 (2003) (proposing phase-out and 2008 sunset of the

UHF), the Commission may decide, in the first instance, the scope of its authority to

modify or eliminate the UHF discount outside the context of § 202(h).

                               IV.   Cross-Ownership Rules

          The Commission’s decision to repeal its newspaper/broadcast cross-ownership

rules22 in favor of new Cross-Media Limits has been attacked on all fronts. Some

petitioners support the repeal but argue that the Cross-Media Limits are too restrictive.

Others challenge the repeal decision and argue that the new limits are too lenient. W e

conclude that the Commission’s decision to replace its cross-ownership rules with the

Cross-M edia Limits is not of itself constitutionally flawed and does not violate § 202(h).

But we cannot uphold the Cross-Media Limits themselves because the Commission does

not provide a reasoned analysis to support the limits that it chose.

A.        Regulatory Background and the 2002 Biennial Review

          Since the 1970s, the Commission has enforced two separate limits on the common

ownership of different-type media outlets in local markets. One cross-ownership rule

prohibits the common ownership of a full-service television broadcast station and a daily


     22
    The Commission also repealed its radio/television cross-ownership rule in favor of
the Cross-Media Limits, but no petitioner challenges this aspect of the Order.

                                             45
public newspaper in the same community. 47 C.F.R. § 73.3555(d). The other limits the

number of television and radio stations to the following combinations: (1) in markets

where at least 20 independently owned media voices would remain post-merger, two

television stations and six radio stations or one television station and seven radio stations;

(2) in markets where at least 10 independent voices would remain, two television stations

and four radio stations; and (3) in other markets, two television stations (subject to the

local television ownership rule) and one radio station. 
Id. § 73.3555(c).
       The Commission considered both cross-ownership rules during its 2002 biennial

review under § 202(h). In the Order, the Commission announced that because neither

rule remained necessary in the public interest, it was repealing them and replacing them

with a single set of Cross-M edia Limits. The three-tiered Cross-Media Limits regulate

common ownership depending on the size of the market: small (those with three or fewer

full-power commercial or noncommercial television stations), mid-sized (between four

and eight television stations), and large (more than eight television stations). In small

markets, newspaper/broadcast combinations and radio/television combinations are

prohibited. Order ¶ 454. In medium-sized markets, an entity may own a newspaper and

either (a) one television station and up to 50% of the radio stations that may be commonly

owned in that market under the local radio rule or (b) up to 100% of the radio stations

allowed under the local rule. 
Id. ¶ 466.
In large markets, cross-ownership is unrestricted.

Id. ¶ 473.
B.     The Comm ission’s decision not to retain a ban on newspaper/broadcast cross-

                                              46
       ownership is justified under § 202(h) and is supported by record evidence.

       The Commission determined that the rule prohibiting newspaper/broadcast cross-

ownership was no longer necessary in the public interest for three primary reasons: (1) the

ban is not necessary to promote competition in local markets because most advertisers do

not view newspapers and television stations as close substitutes, Order ¶ 332; (2) the ban

undermines localism by preventing efficient combinations that would allow for the

production of high-quality local news, 
id. ¶ 343;
and (3) there is not enough evidence to

conclude that ownership influences viewpoint to warrant a blanket cross-ownership ban,

thus making it unjustifiable on diversity grounds, 
id. at ¶
364, (and moreover, the

presence of other media sources—such as the Internet and cable—compensate for the

viewpoint diversity lost to consolidation, 
id. ¶ 365).
The Citizen Petitioners object to the

localism and diversity components of the Commission’s rationale. We conclude

differently, as reasoned analysis supports the Commission’s determination that the

blanket ban on newspaper/broadcast cross-ownership was no longer in the public interest.

Part 
II.C supra
.

       1.     Newspaper/broadcast combinations can promote localism.

       The Commission measured the promotion of localism by considering “the

selection of programming responsive to local needs and interests, and local news quantity

and quality.” Order ¶ 78. Evidence that existing (grandfathered) newspaper-owned

broadcast stations produced local news in higher quantity with better quality than other

stations convinced the Commission that the ban on newspaper/broadcast combinations

                                             47
undermined its localism interest. The Commission principally relied on the findings of its

MOWG study that newspaper-owned television stations provide almost 50% more local

news and public affairs programming than other stations, an average of 21.9 hours per

week. 
Id. ¶ 344
(citing Thomas C. Spavins et al., The Measurement of Local Television

News and Public Affairs Programs (MOW G Study No. 7) at 3 (Sept. 2002)). The

Commission also found corresponding advantages in quality of local coverage provided

by newspaper-owned stations, as shown by ratings (measuring consumer approval) and

industry awards (measuring critical approval). 
Id. ¶ 344
–45 (citing, among other things,

findings by the Project for Excellence in Journalism that newspaper-owned stations “were

more likely to do stories focusing on important community issues and to provide a wide

mix of opinions, and they were less likely to do celebrity and human interest features”).

       The Citizen Petitioners argue that the MOW G study was flawed because it

examined all newspaper/broadcast station combinations, including “intermarket”

combinations (entities that own a newspaper and broadcast stations in different cities), as

well as “intramarket” combinations (entities that own a newspaper and a broadcast station

in the same city). But the Citizens Petitioners do not suggest that a study entirely focused

on intramarket combinations would have different results. The six intramarket

combinations that were included in the study (grandfathered exceptions to the cross-

ownership ban) averaged more local news and public affairs programming as compared to

the overall average (26 weekly hours compared to 21.9) and higher ratings for their 5:30

p.m. and 6:00 p.m. news programs (9.8 and 11 compared to 7.8 and 8.2). MOWG Study

                                             48
No. 7 app. A; Comments of Newspaper Association of America, MB Docket No. 02-277

at 15 (Jan. 2, 2003).

       The Citizen Petitioners also protest the Commission’s reliance on anecdotal

evidence of pro-localism combinations and its disregard of anecdotal evidence to the

contrary. Significantly, however, the Commission used anecdotal evidence23 merely to

illustrate its statistical findings— it did not rely on anecdote as the sole basis for its

conclusions about localism. Moreover, the Commission properly discounted anecdotal

evidence of a Canadian newspaper conglomerate’s detrimental effect on localism. Can

West, which controls 30% of Canada’s daily newspaper circulation, requires its

newspaper editors to publish editorials from headquarters, which it forbids local editorials

to contradict. But the Commission explained that the Can West example shows the peril

of national ownership and corporate centralization of media services, which is not

relevant to the Commission’s regulations on local combinations. Order ¶ 352. In

summary, the Citizen Petitioners’ arguments do not unsettle the Commission’s conclusion

that the newspaper/broadcast cross-ownership ban undermined localism.

       2.      A blanket prohibition on newspaper/broadcast combinations is not
               necessary to protect diversity.



  23
     For example, Gannett Company reported that the “media integration” resulting from
its newspaper/broadcast combination in Phoenix “improved efficiency, particularly in
situations characterized by fast-breaking news such as the massive wildfires near Phoenix
last year.” Both of Belo Corporation’s Dallas outlets “have been able to cover a wider
range of stories through information sharing between the separate newspaper and
television news staffs.” Order ¶ 348.

                                                49
       The Commission offered two rationales for its conclusion that a blanket

prohibition on newspaper/broadcast combinations is no longer necessary to ensure

diversity in local markets. First, it found that “[c]ommonly-owned newspapers and

broadcast stations do not necessarily speak with a single, monolithic voice.” 
Id. ¶ 361.
Given conflicting evidence in the record 24 on whether ownership influences viewpoint,

the Commission reasonably concluded that it did not have enough confidence in the

proposition that commonly owned outlets have a uniform bias to warrant sustaining the

cross-ownership ban. 
Id. ¶ 364.
       Second, the Commission found that diverse viewpoints from other media sources

in local markets (such as cable and the Internet) compensate for viewpoints lost to

newspaper/broadcast consolidations. 
Id. ¶ 366.
We agree record evidence suggests that

cable and the Internet supplement the viewpoint diversity provided by broadcast and




  24
    On one hand, the record contained examples of a newspaper-owner’s affiliations and
biases influencing the news and editorial pages. But there were also examples of
commonly owned newspapers expressing different viewpoints (such as that the Tribune
Company’s newspapers did not endorse the same candidate in the 2000 presidential
election). The MOWG submitted a statistical study of 10 newspaper-television
combinations; in half of them the newspaper’s overall “slant” was noticeably different
from the broadcast television’s “slant” on the news. See David Pritchard, Viewpoint
Diversity in Cross-Owned Newspapers and Television Stations: A Study of News
Coverage of the 2000 Presidential Campaign (MOW G Study No. 2) (Sept. 2002). But
the Pritchard Study was the subject of much criticism for its flawed methodology (no
control group of independent media outlets for comparison) and narrow scope (it only
looked at one factor in judging “slant”). Order ¶ 362.

                                            50
newspaper outlets in local markets.25 As discussed more fully below, we believe that the

Commission gave too much weight to the Internet in deriving the Cross-Media Limits.

But separate from the question of degree, we conclude that it was acceptable for the

Commission to find that cable and the Internet contribute to viewpoint diversity.

C.        The Commission’s decision to retain some limits on common ownership of
          different-type media outlets was constitutional and did not violate § 202(h).

          The Deregulatory Petitioners support the Commission’s repeal of the

newspaper/broadcast cross-ownership ban but object to its decision to retain any

restriction on the common ownership of newspaper and broadcast media outlets. First

they argue that any limits on newspaper/broadcast cross-ownership violate § 202(h),

because, as the Commission acknowledges, the evidence suggests that the cross-

ownership restrictions are not in the public interest. They also argue that the Cross-Media

Limits violate the First and Fifth Amendments of the United States Constitution. We

disagree on all counts.

          1.    Continuing to regulate cross-media ownership is in the public interest.

          The Commission’s finding that a blanket prohibition on newspaper/broadcast

cross-ownership is no longer in the public interest does not compel the conclusion that no

regulation is necessary. See Order ¶ 364. As described above, the Commission found




     25
    See, e.g., Joel Waldfogel, Consumer Substitutability Among Media (MOW G Study
No. 3) (Sept. 2002) (suggesting that consumers view Internet news sources as a substitute
for daily newspapers and broadcast news).

                                             51
evidence to undermine the premise that ownership always influences viewpoint,26 but it

did not find the opposite to be true. And while the Commission found that other media

sources contributed to viewpoint diversity in local markets, it could not have found that

the Internet and cable were complete substitutes for the viewpoints provided by

newspapers and broadcast stations. See MOW G Study No. 3 (finding that the Internet and

cable rank as sources of local news, but they do not outrank newspapers and broadcast

television). Given the Commission’s goal of balancing the public’s interests in

competition, localism, and diversity, it reasonably concluded that repealing the cross-

ownership ban was necessary to promote competition and localism, while retaining some

limits was necessary to ensure diversity.27

       2.     Continuing to regulate cross-media ownership does not violate the Fifth
              Amendm ent.




  26
    Indeed, ample evidence supported its conclusion that ownership can influence
viewpoint. See Order ¶¶ 24–25; Comments of the UCC et al., MB Docket No. 02-277 at
4 (Jan. 2, 2003) (“UCC Comments”) (citing a Pew Research Center study of television
journalists and executives that found nearly one quarter of journalists purposefully avoid
newsworthy stories and nearly as many soften the tone of stories to benefit the interest of
their news organizations); 
id. at 5
(citing a 2002 study finding that outlets included more
references to their own products and services and treated those items more favorably than
others, thus exhibiting a “synergy bias”); Comments of Consumer Federation of America,
MB Docket 02-277 at 41 (Jan. 2, 2003) (citing a 2002 study finding that election
information on news pages was slanted in favor of candidate endorsed on the editorial
page); 
id. at 44
(citing a 2001 survey of news directors finding that media owners and
sponsors pressure reporters to slant the news).
  27
    We also note that the Commission provided for a waiver of the Cross-M edia Limits
upon a demonstration “that an otherwise prohibited combination would, in fact, enhance
the quality and quantity of broadcast news available in the market.” Order ¶ 481.

                                              52
       The Deregulatory Petitioners argue that the Cross-Media Limits violate the Equal

Protection Clause of the Fifth Amendment because they single out newspaper owners for

special restrictions that do not apply to other media outlets. This argument is foreclosed,

however, by the Supreme Court’s decision in NCCB that endorsed the constitutionality of

the 1975 newspaper/television cross-ownership 
ban. 436 U.S. at 801
–02. Rather than

concluding that newspaper owners were singled out for different treatment, the Court

determined that “the regulations treat newspaper owners in essentially the same fashion as

other owners of the major media of mass communication” by imposing limits on them as

well as owners of television and radio stations. 
Id. at 801.
We decline the Deregulatory

Petitioners’ invitation to disregard Supreme Court precedent because of changing times.

Surely there are more media outlets today (such as cable, the Internet, and satellite

broadcast) than there were in 1978 when NCCB was decided. But it cannot be assumed

that these media outlets contribute significantly to viewpoint diversity as sources of local

news and information. See Part IV.D.2 infra. Even if it could, it is the Supreme Court’s

prerogative to change its own precedent. See State Oil Co. v. Khan, 
522 U.S. 3
, 20 (1997)

(stating that only the Supreme Court can overrule its own precedent); Am. Civil Liberties

Union of N.J. v. Black Horse Pike Reg’l Bd. of Educ., 
84 F.3d 1471
, 1484 (3d Cir. 1996)

(stating that we are obliged to follow Supreme Court precedent “until instructed otherwise

by a majority of the Supreme Court”).

       3.     Continuing to regulate cross-media ownership does not violate the First
              Amendm ent.


                                             53
       The Deregulatory Petitioners argue that the Commission’s decision to retain

restrictions on the common ownership of newspapers and broadcast stations contravenes

the First Amendment because it limits the speech opportunities of newspaper owners and

broadcast station owners, and hence limits the public’s access to information. Yet again

their challenge is foreclosed by NCCB, where the Supreme Court affirmed the

Commission’s authority, despite a First Amendment challenge, to regulate

broadcast/newspaper cross-ownership in the public interest. Due to the “physical

scarcity” of the broadcast spectrum, the Court scrutinized the regulation to discern a

rational 
basis. 436 U.S. at 799
. The Commission’s action, it held, was “a reasonable

means of promoting the public interest in diversified mass communications.” 
Id. at 802.
       The Deregulatory Petitioners suggest, as they did in mounting their Fifth

Amendment challenge, that the expansion of media outlets since NCCB’s day requires a

rethinking of the scarcity rationale and the lower level of constitutional review it entails.

Again we decline their invitation to disregard precedent, and we are not alone. See FCC

v. League of Women Voters of Cal., 
468 U.S. 364
, 376 & n.11 (1984) (upholding the

scarcity rationale until Congress speaks to the issue); Fox 
I, 289 F.3d at 1046
(“First,

contrary to the implication of the networks’ argument, this court is not in a position to

reject the scarcity rationale even if we agree that it no longer makes sense. The Supreme

Court has already heard the empirical case against that rationale and still ‘declined to

question its continuing validity.’” (citing Turner v. FCC, 
512 U.S. 622
, 638 (1994))).

       Even were we not constrained by Supreme Court precedent, we would not accept

                                              54
the Deregulatory Petitioners’ contention that the expansion of media outlets has rendered

the broadcast spectrum less scarce. In NCCB, the Court referred to the “physical

scarcity” of the spectrum—the fact that many more people would like access to it than

can be 
accommodated. 436 U.S. at 799
. The abundance of non-broadcast media does not

render the broadcast spectrum any less scarce. See, e.g., Ruggiero v. FCC, 
278 F.3d 1323
, 1325 (D.C. Cir. 2002), rev’d en banc, 
317 F.3d 239
(D.C. Cir 2003) (citing the

Commission’s statement that “[n]ow . . . radio service is widely available throughout the

country and very little spectrum remains available for new full-powered stations.”).

       In this context, we will apply a rational basis standard to the Commission’s

restrictions on the common ownership between newspaper and broadcast stations, and

uphold them if they are rationally related to a substantial government interest. See 
NCCB, 436 U.S. at 799
–800; see also Am. Family Ass’n v. FCC, 
365 F.3d 1156
, 1168 (D.C. Cir.

2004). In NCCB, the Supreme Court endorsed a substantial government interest in

promoting diversified mass communications. 
Id. at 795,
802. The Supreme Court held

that the Commission had “acted rationally in finding that diversification of ownership

would enhance the possibility of achieving greater diversity of viewpoints.” 
Id. at 796.
Here, as in NCCB, the Commission justified its continued restrictions on common

ownership of newspapers and broadcast stations as promoting the public interest in

viewpoint diversity. Order ¶ 355. The Court has said that limiting common ownership is

a reasonable means of promoting the public interest in viewpoint diversity. 
NCCB, 436 U.S. at 796
. Therefore, applying NCCB, we hold that the Commission’s continued

                                            55
regulation of the common ownership of newspapers and broadcasters does not violate the

First Amendment rights of either.

D.     The Commission did not provide reasoned analysis to support the specific
       Cross-Media Limits that it chose.

       The Commission concluded that cross-ownership limits were necessary in specific

situations to guard against “an elevated risk of harm to the range and breadth of

viewpoints that may be available to the public.” Order ¶ 442. But recognizing that

ownership limits impede the speech opportunities for both broadcasters and newspapers,

the Commission endeavored to craft new limits “as narrowly as possible.” 
Id. ¶ 441.
In

that vein, the Commission sought to identify “at risk” local markets—those with high

levels of viewpoint concentration—where continued regulation was necessary. By

focusing its regulation on those markets, the Commission hoped to avoid needlessly

overregulating markets with already ample viewpoint diversity.

       But for all of its efforts, the Commission’s Cross-Media Limits employ several

irrational assumptions and inconsistencies. We do not object in principle to the

Commission’s reliance on the Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission’s

antitrust formula, the Herfindahl-Hirschmann Index (“HHI”), as its starting point for

measuring diversity in local markets. In converting the HHI to a measure for diversity in

local markets, however, the Commission gave too much weight to the Internet as a media

outlet, irrationally assigned outlets of the same media type equal market shares, and

inconsistently derived the Cross-Media Limits from its Diversity Index results. For these


                                            56
reasons, detailed below, we remand for the Commission to justify or modify further its

Cross-M edia Limits.

       1.     Overview of the Commission’s Diversity Index Methodology

       The Commission designed a methodology called the Diversity Index to identify “at

risk” markets where limits on cross-media ownership should be retained. The Diversity

Index was “inspired by” the HHI, which the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade

Commission use to measure proposed mergers’ effect on competition in local markets.

Id. ¶ 394.
A market’s HHI score is the sum of market shares squared. A highly

competitive market will have a lower HHI score than a concentrated one. For example,

compare the HHI score of a market with 10 equal-sized competitors (10 [competitors] x

10 [each competitor’s market share percentage]2 = 1000) to the HHI score of a market

with only five equal-sized competitors (5 x 202 = 2000).28 The Department of Justice and

the Federal Trade Commission categorize markets with HHI scores above 1800 as

“highly concentrated.” If a proposed merger would exceed that level of concentration,

the agencies believe that it would be harmful to the competition in that market. At its

core, the Diversity Index here uses the same sum of market share-squared formula.

       First, the Commission selected which media outlets to include in its analysis of

viewpoint diversity in local markets based on consumers’ reported preferences for



  28
    Of course, the HHI formula also works where the components of a market are not of
equal size. In a market where one company controls 50% of the market share, two
control 20%, and another controls 10%, the HHI formula is 50 2 + 20 2 + 20 2 + 10 2 = 3400.

                                            57
sources of local news and information. The Commission determined that broadcast

television, daily and weekly newspapers, radio, and Internet (via cable connection and

DSL, dial-up, or other connections) are the relevant contributors to viewpoint diversity in

local markets. See Neilsen Media Research, Consumer Survey on Media Usage (MOWG

Study No. 8) (Sept. 2002). Based on the popularity of each media source, the

Commission assigned each a relative weight: broadcast TV 33.8%, daily newspapers

20.2%, weekly newspapers 8.6%, radio 24.9%, Internet (cable) 2.3% and Internet (DSL,

dial-up, or other connection) 10.2%. Order ¶¶ 412, 415, 427.

       Next, the Commission selected many sample markets 29 for which it would

determine a Diversity Index score. In each of those markets, it counted the number of

outlets within each media type and assigned each outlet an equal market share. (For

example, the New York City market has 23 television stations, so each one was attributed

an equal 4.3% 30 market share.) The Commission calculated the ownership share by

multiplying the number of outlets owned by an entity by the market share. (Univision




  29
    The Commission calculated Diversity Index scores for all markets with five or fewer
television stations, all markets with 15 and 20 television stations, and ten randomly
selected markets with between six and ten stations. For sample market Diversity Index
calculations, see Order app. C.
  30
    Throughout this discussion of the Diversity Index, we adopt the Commission’s
convention and report the decimals of intermediate products and quotients (such as 4.3
here) rounded to the nearest tenth. Final products (such as 13.0 reported in the next
sentence) are derived from the unrounded intermediate product and then rounded to the
nearest tenth.


                                            58
owns three television stations in New York, so its ownership share was 3 x 4.3% =

13.0%.) Each ownership share was then given its relative weight by media type.

(Univision’s 13.0% share was thus subject to the 33.8% multiplier for television stations).

The Commission then squared all of the weighted ownership shares; their sum was the

market’s total Diversity Index score. But in markets with cross-owned shares (outlets of

different media types owned by the same entity) the entity’s weighted ownership shares

were summed together before they were squared. (ABC owned one television station and

four radio stations in New York, so the Commission added its weighted ownership share

for the television station (4.3% x 33.8% = 1.45%) to its weighted ownership share for the

radio stations (6.7% x 24.9% = 1.67% ) for a combined ABC ownership share of 3.12%.

The square of 3.12 was included in the summation). See generally Order app. C.

       After the Commission calculated Diversity Index scores for markets of different

sizes, it determined how those scores would change in several different consolidation

“scenarios.” To illustrate, the Commission determined that markets with five television

stations had an average Diversity Index score of 911. If a newspaper and television

station combined in a market of that size, that score would increase by 223, to 1134. The

other combination scenarios were: (1) one television station and all of the radio stations

allowed to be commonly owned under the local radio rule; (2) one newspaper and all of

the radio stations allowed to be commonly owned under the local radio rule; (3) one

newspaper, one television station, and half of the number of radio stations allowed to be

commonly owned under the local radio rule; (4) two television stations; (5) one

                                             59
newspaper and two television stations; and (6) one newspaper, two television stations,

and all of the radio stations allowed under the local radio rule. Order app. D.

       Finding that all of the consolidation scenarios resulted in relatively high increases

to the average Diversity Index scores for the smallest markets (those with three or fewer

television stations), the Commission prohibited newspaper/television, newspaper/radio,

and radio/television combinations in those markets. Order ¶¶ 456, 459, 460. In the large

markets (nine or more stations), all of the consolidation scenarios resulted in acceptable

increases to the average Diversity Index scores, so the Commission imposed no limits on

cross-media ownership in those markets. In the mid-sized markets (between four and

eight television stations), the Commission found that all of the scenarios, except the two

involving a newspaper and television duopoly, should be allowed, based on their modest

increases to the average Diversity Index scores for those markets. 
Id. ¶ 466.
       2.     The Commission did not justify its choice and weight of specific media
              outlets.

       Petitioners from both sides of the regulatory spectrum attack the Commission’s

selection of media outlets for inclusion in the Diversity Index formula. The Citizen

Petitioners argue that the Commission gave too much weight to the Internet at the

expense of television and daily newspapers, thereby understating the level of

concentration and overstating the level of diversity in a market. The Deregulatory

Petitioners, on the other hand, argue that the Diversity Index understates the actual

amount of diversity in a market by ignoring important media outlets, primarily cable


                                             60
television. As explained below, we affirm the Commission’s reasoned decision to

discount cable. But we think that the same rationale also applies to the Internet.

Therefore, its decision to count the Internet as a source of viewpoint diversity, while

discounting cable, was not rational.

       The Commission properly excluded cable because of serious doubts as to the

extent that cable provided independent local news—the Commission’s recognized

indicator of viewpoint diversity in local markets. Order ¶ 394 (“News and public affairs

programming is the clearest example of programming that can provide viewpoint

diversity. . . . [and] the appropriate geographic market for viewpoint diversity is local.”).

While the responses to one question in the Commission’s survey suggested that cable is a

significant source of local news, see MOWG Study No. 8 tbl. 8, the Commission did not

find this credible because the responses to other survey questions suggested that

respondents were counting broadcast signals that are transmitted as cable channels as

sources of local news on cable. See 
id. tbl. 18
(from a list of popular national cable news

channels and a choice for “local cable news channels,” almost half of the respondents

chose “other” as their source for cable network news, indicating that cable news channels

were probably confused with broadcast networks’ news). The survey’s indication that

cable is an independent source of local news was also undercut by external evidence,

including Neilsen ratings, that local cable channels are the least watched of any broadcast

or cable stations in the market. Order ¶ 414. Furthermore, the Commission noted that

local cable channels are not available everywhere, but only in select markets. 
Id. ¶ 414
                                              61
n.924; see also UCC Comments at 30–31 (reporting that only 10 to 15% of cable systems

include channels that provide local and public affairs programming—i.e., public,

educational, and governmental access channels—and that there are only 22 local news

cable channels in the country, five of which serve the New York City area). Thus, the

Commission justifiably excluded cable from its Diversity Index calculations.

       Similarly, the responses to one of the Commission survey questions suggested that

the Internet is a source of local news. See MOW G Study No. 8 31 tbl.1 (18.8% of

respondents listed the Internet as a source of local news). But the survey did not identify

which websites respondents used as sources of local news. 32 There is a critical distinction

between websites that are independent sources of local news and websites of local




  31
     The dissent suggests that the MOWG Studies, “although not perfect . . . , are a
significant improvement over the study in Sinclair” that the D.C. Circuit Court
determined did not support the Commission’s decision to limit the definition of “voices”
in its local television rule. But this comparison is not relevant because, as we point out,
the Commission inconsistently applied the results of its analysis.
  32
    The follow-up question for the respondents who reported using the Internet as a news
source asked which sites they had used in the past seven days as a source of local or
national current affairs, so their responses to this question are not helpful in determining
whether the Internet is a source of independent local news. To the extent that we can
glean anything from this question— unlikely, as the predominant response was “other”
(34.9%)—the most popular websites identified were those of national cable news
channels, MSN.com (22.4%) and CNN.com (19.1%), indicating that most people had
those types of websites in mind when they reported using the Internet for news. (The
other responses were: Yahoo.com (17.9%), MSNBC.com (5.9%), NewYorkTimes.com
(5.1%), FoxNews.com (2.2%), USAToday.com (1.8%), ABCNews.com (1.8% ),
CBSNews.com (1.7%), Netscape.com (1.7% ), Excite.com (1.3%), Iwon.com (1.2%),
AT&T.net (1.1%), WallStreetJournal.com (1.0%), none (7.3%), don’t know (3.5%), and
refuse (0.5%)).

                                             62
newspapers and broadcast stations that merely republish the information already being

reported by the newspaper or broadcast station counterpart. The latter do not present an

“independent” viewpoint and thus should not be considered as contributing diversity to

local markets. Accordingly, the Commission should have discounted the respondents

who primarily rely on these websites from its total number of respondents who indicated

that they use the Internet to access local news. 33

       Furthermore, just as the Commission discounted responses indicating that cable

was an independent source of local news because this finding conflicted with other record

evidence, it should have discounted the Internet responses as well. The Commission does

not cite, nor does the record contain, persuasive evidence that there is a significant

presence of independent local news sites on the Internet. According to the record, most

sources of local news on the Internet are the websites for newspapers and broadcast

television stations. See, e.g., UCC Comments at 33 (62% of Internet users get local news

from newspaper websites, 39% visit television station websites). And the examples the

Commission does cite—the Drudge Report and Salon.com— have a national, not local,


  33
    The dissent acknowledges the flaws in the MOWG Study No. 8 survey, but suggests
that because the survey “can be fine-tuned on the next round of reviews” it should not be
the basis for remand. But we decline to abdicate our obligation to provide meaningful
judicial review. Just as the Commission may not rely on a “wait-and-see” approach to
rulemaking, 
Sinclair, 284 F.3d at 164
, neither can we. We review an agency’s decision
for whether it is rationally derived from the record evidence—not whether the agency
may (or may not) “fine tune” the record at the next mandated review. Furthermore, just
as we may not supply a reasoned basis for the agency’s action that the agency itself has
not given, State 
Farm, 463 U.S. at 43
, we also do not supply evidence to an agency in the
hopes that the agency will include that evidence in a future study.

                                               63
news focus. 34 Order ¶ 427.

       The Commission suggests that “the virtual universe of information sources” on

the Internet qualifies it as a source of viewpoint diversity. Order ¶ 427. But to accept

this rationale we would have to distort the Commission’s own premise that local news is

an indicator of viewpoint diversity. E.g., 
id. ¶ 391
(Diversity Index measures “the

relative importance of these media as a source of local news”).35 Search-engine

sponsored pages such as Yahoo! Local and about.com,36 which were suggested by

commenters as sources of local news and information, may be useful for finding

restaurant reviews and concert schedules, but this is not the type of “news and public

affairs programming” that the Commission said was “the clearest example of

programming that can provide viewpoint diversity.” 
Id. ¶ 394.
       To accept its “universe of information” characterization of the Internet’s viewpoint

  34
    Moreover, the Drudge Report is an “aggregator” of news stories from other news
outlets’ websites and, as such, is not itself normally a “source” of news, national or local.
  35
    The Order also speaks of “news and public affairs programming” or “local news and
current affairs information” when referring to measures of viewpoint diversity. E.g.,
Order ¶¶ 394, 406, 409.
  36
     The dissent also takes notice of the Independent Media Center websites such as
phillyimc.com. We agree that this is a good example of independent local news on the
Internet. But the IMC provides local links in only eight markets in the United States.
The Commission does not even mention these websites in its analysis of the Internet, let
alone argue that IM C websites in eight local markets will offset the viewpoint diversity
lost when newspapers and broadcast stations are allowed to consolidate. And even if we
believed that to be the case, it is not our role to insert our own analysis to substitute for
that which is missing from the agency’s rationale. State 
Farm, 463 U.S. at 43
(“[W ]e
may not supply a reasoned basis for the agency’s action that the agency itself has not
given.”).

                                              64
diversity, we would also have to disregard the Commission’s professed intent to focus its

consideration of viewpoint diversity on media outlets. 
Id. ¶¶ 20,
391. In terms of

content, “the media” provides (to different degrees, depending on the outlet) accuracy and

depth in local news in a way that an individual posting in a chat room on a particular issue

of local concern does not. But more importantly, media outlets have an entirely different

character from individual or organizations’ websites and thus contribute to viewpoint

diversity in an entirely different way. They provide an aggregator function (bringing

news/information to one place) as well as a distillation function (making a judgment as to

what is interesting, important, entertaining, etc.).37 Individuals (such as political

candidates) and entities (such as local governments or community organizations) may use

the Internet to disseminate information and opinions about matters of local concern (such

as the extension of a bike path on the Schuylkill River in Center City Philadelphia, see

dissent Part IV.A.1), but these individuals and organizations are not, themselves, media

outlets. W e agree that the Internet “helps citizens discharge the obligations of citizenship

in a democracy,” Order ¶ 393, when someone can go cityofglenfalls.com to find the city

council’s next agenda or use sfgov.org to learn how to get a marriage license in San

Francisco. See Comments of the Hearst Corporation, MM Docket No. 01-235 at 11 &

n.36, apps. A & C (Dec. 3, 2001) (“Hearst Comments”) (listing these website addresses,

among others, as examples of local government websites). But local governments are


  37
   See Brief of Petitioner Media General, Inc., at 55 (noting “each media outlet in a
community is actually a platform for the expression of many viewpoints”).

                                              65
not, themselves, “media outlets” for viewpoint-diversity purposes. Like many entities,

they just happen to use a particular media outlet—the Internet— to disseminate

information.

       Similarly, advertiser-driven websites such as hvnet.com and sfadvertiser.com, see

Hearst Comments at apps. A & C, hardly contribute to viewpoint diversity. Like local

governments, the sponsors of these websites are not “media outlets” just because they

have “local information” that they want the public to have— if they were, their

advertisements in telephone directories would also have to count toward viewpoint

diversity. Compare Order ¶ 424 (explaining that the Commission would not count

toward viewpoint diversity a local newspaper’s comics and classified ads because, while

the subscriber is “undoubtedly getting a valuable service, it is not clear that the service

has anything to do with news and current affairs”).

       The Commission attempts to justify different treatment for cable and the Internet

by suggesting that local cable news channels are only available in select markets, while

the Internet is available everywhere. Not only is this distinction demonstrably false (as

even the Commission acknowledged that almost 30% of Americans do not have Internet

access, Order ¶ 365), it is irrelevant. That the Internet is more available than local cable

news channels does not mean that it is providing independent local news. On remand the

Commission must either exclude the Internet from the media selected for inclusion in the

Diversity Index or provide a better explanation for why it is included in light of the

exclusion of cable. See 
Sinclair, 284 F.3d at 163
–65 (unexplained inconsistency was

                                              66
arbitrary and capricious).

       3.     The Comm ission did not justify its assumption of equal market shares.

       Both the Citizen Petitioners and the Deregulatory Petitioners object to the

Commission’s decision to assign all outlets within the same media type (that is, television

stations, daily papers, or radio stations) an equal market share. The assumption of equal

market shares is inconsistent with the Commission’s overall approach to its Diversity

Index and also makes unrealistic assumptions about media outlets’ relative contributions

to viewpoint diversity in local markets.38

       The Commission’s decision to assign equal market shares to outlets within a media

type does not jibe with the Commission’s decision to assign relative weights to the

different media types themselves, about which it said “we have no reason to believe that

all media are of equal importance.” Order ¶ 409; see also 
id. ¶ 445
(“Not all voices,

however, speak with the same volume.”). It also negates the Commission’s proffered

rationale for using the HHI formula in the first place—to allow it to measure the actual



  38
    The dissent views these flaws, effectively, as “harmless error” because the
Commission called the Diversity Index a “useful tool” that “informs, but does not replace,
our judgment in establishing rules of general applicability that determine where we
should draw lines between diverse and concentrated markets.” Order ¶ 391. But
nowhere in the Order, in its briefs, or in its oral argument did the Commission identify
any consideration other than the Diversity Index as having influenced the formulation of
the Cross-M edia Limits. Rather, the Cross-Media Limits prospectively ban certain
combinations in specific markets, and allow others, based on nothing but the relative
increases those combinations would have on the average Diversity Index scores of
markets of that size.


                                             67
loss of diversity from consolidation by taking into account the actual “diversity

importance” of the merging parties, something it could not do with a simple “voices” test.

Id. ¶ 396.
Finally, assigning equal market shares to outlets that provide no local news

almost certainly presents an understated view of concentration in several markets, thus

contravening the Commission’s goal of making “the most conservative assumption

possible” about viewpoint diversity. 
Id. ¶ 400.
         Additionally, there is no dispute that the assignment of equal market shares

generates absurd results. For example, in New York City, the Dutchess Community

College television station and the stations owned by ABC each receive an equal 4.3%

market share. Or compare the Dutchess Community College station’s weighted share of

1.5% (4.3% times the 33.8% multiplier for television) to a mere 1.4% weighted,

combined share assigned to the New York Times Company’s co-owned daily newspaper

and radio station. Order app. C. A Diversity Index that requires us to accept that a

community college television station makes a greater contribution to viewpoint diversity

than a conglomerate that includes the third-largest newspaper in America39 also requires

us to abandon both logic and reality.

         The Commission’s attempt to justify its failure to consider actual market share of

outlets within a media type is not persuasive. It suggests that actual-use data use data is

not relevant because “current behavior is not necessarily an accurate predictor of future



  39
       Source: Audit Bureau of Circulations. See http://www.accessabc.com/.

                                              68
behavior.” Order ¶ 423. But this truism did not prevent the Commission from preferring

actual-use data in assigning relative weight to the different media types. The Commission

also suggests that, compared to consumer preferences for a general media type (which are

generally stable), consumers’ preferences for particular media outlets are fluid because

they depend on the media outlet’s chosen format or quantity or quality of content, which

are easily changed. 
Id. ¶ 422.
But while variance in the local news content of individual

media outlets is conceivable—e.g., the home shopping television station could start

carrying local news—the Commission does not provide any evidence that media outlets

actually undergo any such radical content change, let alone that they regularly do so.

Simply put, the Commission needs to undergird its predictive judgment that stations can

freely change the level of their news content with some evidence for that judgment to

survive arbitrary and capricious review. Fox 
I, 280 F.3d at 1051
.

       Lastly, the Commission attempts to justify its refusal to employ actual-use data by

arguing that collecting “information on viewing/listening/reading of local news and

current affairs material” would make it “necessary first to determine which programming

constituted news and current affairs,” which in turn “would present both

legal/Constitutional and data collection problems.” Order ¶ 424. With respect to

“legal/Constitutional” problems, the Commission is apparently concerned about

categorizing programming as news or “non-news.” But the Commission obtained actual-

use data in M OW G Study No. 8 without any “legal/Constitutional problems.” There it

avoided having to make content-distinguishing judgments simply by asking

                                            69
respondents where they got their local news. And the Commission’s reference here to

data collection problems is vague and unexplained; there is no suggestion that obtaining

actual-use data for outlets within a media type would be prohibitively more onerous than

obtaining the same data for the media types themselves, as it did in MOW G Study No. 8.

       Because the Commission’s reasons for eschewing actual-use data in assigning

market shares to outlets within a media type and assuming equal market shares are

unrealistic and inconsistent with the Commission’s overall approach to the Diversity

Index and its proffered rationale, we remand for the Commission’s additional

consideration of this aspect of the Order.

       4.     The Commission did not rationally derive its Cross-Media Limits from
              the Diversity Index results.

       After the Commission calculated the average Diversity Index scores for markets of

various sizes, it set out to determine whether the increase in those scores resulting from

different consolidation scenarios would have an acceptable or unacceptable effect. The

Commission’s results, contained in appendix D of the Order, are replicated here for ease

of reference. (We have used boldface type to indicate those increases in Diversity Index

scores that the Commission found acceptable in crafting the Cross-Media Limits.)




                                             70
          Base Case                  Average C hange in Diversity Index, Resulting from Mergers

 TV            Average     100%        New s-     New s-    New s-      2 TV        New s-        New s-
 stations      Diversity   Radio +     paper +    paper +   paper + 1   stations    paper +       paper +
 in            Index       1 TV        100%       1 TV      TV                      2 TV          100%
 market        score       station     Radio      station   station +               stations      Radio +
                                                            50%                                   2 TV
                                                            Radio                                 stations

 1             1707        651         271        910       1321        —           —             —

 2             1316        301         335        731       1009        —           —             —

 3             1027        190         242        331       515         —           —             —

 4             928         138         236        242       408         —           —             —

 5             911         111         263        223       393         91          376           846

 6             889         79          239        200       340         63          357           688

 7             753         73          171        121       247         47          242           533

 8             885         79          299        152       314         36          308           734

 9             705         64          198        86        207         28          172           473

 10            635         56          107        51        119         23          101           292

 15            595         43          149        48        145         10          97            302

 20            612         49          222        40        128         6           80            350



As illustrated by the chart’s figures that are not in boldface type, the Commission

prohibited all cross-media consolidation in the smallest markets where, under any of their

sample consolidation scenarios,40 the increase in Diversity Index would be excessive.

The Commission decided to permit all of the scenarios in the largest markets, finding the

Diversity Index increases to be acceptable. In the mid-sized markets, the Commission


     40
     The Commission did not report a Diversity Index increase for those scenarios that
would be precluded by the modified local television ownership rule, see generally Part V
infra, which would prohibit television station duopolies in markets with fewer than five
stations.

                                                       71
allowed most of the consolidation scenarios but prohibited consolidations involving a

newspaper and a television duopoly.

       The Deregulatory Petitioners suggest that the Commission should have prohibited

only cross-ownership mergers that would lead to an increase of more than 400 points,

consistent with the practice of the Department of Justice to block mergers that would

increase the local market’s HHI score by over 400 points. As illustrated by the chart

above, this approach would have generated far more permissive Cross-Media Limits. The

Citizen Petitioners argue, on the other hand, that the Commission should have prohibited

cross-ownership mergers that lead to an increase of more than 100 points, the increase

that triggers the Department of Justice’s “further review.” But the decision of where to

draw the line between acceptable increases and unacceptable increases is almost always

the Commission’s to make. Deference to the Commission’s judgment is highest when

assessing the rationality of the agency’s line-drawing endeavors. See 
NCCB, 436 U.S. at 814
–15; AT&T 
Corp., 220 F.3d at 627
. The Commission rationalized its decision to

make conservative assumptions in order to “protect[ its] core policy objective of

viewpoint diversity.” Order ¶ 399; see also 
Sinclair, 284 F.3d at 153
(Commission

determined that antitrust merger guidelines “might be too low as their purpose lay in

defining the point at which antitrust scrutiny is required, and not in encouraging a wide

array of voices and viewpoints”).

       Although the Commission is entitled to deference in deciding where to draw the

line between acceptable and unacceptable increases in markets’ Diversity Index scores,

                                            72
we do not affirm the seemingly inconsistent manner in which the line was drawn. As the

chart above illustrates, the Cross-Media Limits allow some combinations where the

increases in Diversity Index scores were generally higher than for other combinations that

were not allowed. Consider the mid-sized markets (four to eight stations), where the

Commission found that a combination of a newspaper, a television station, and half the

radio stations allowed under the local radio rule would increase the average Diversity

Index scores in those markets by 408 (four stations), 393 (five), 340 (six), 247 (seven),

and 314 (eight) points respectively. These permitted increases seem to belong on the

other side of the Commission’s line. They are considerably higher than the Diversity

Index score increases resulting from other combinations that the Commission permitted,

such as the newspaper and television combination, 242 (four stations), 223 (five), 200

(six), 121 (seven), and 152 (eight). They are even higher than those resulting from the

combination of a newspaper and television duopoly—376 (five stations), 357 (six), 242

(seven), and 308 (eight)—which the Commission did not permit. The Commission’s

failure to provide any explanation for this glaring inconsistency is without doubt arbitrary

and capricious, and so provides further basis for remand of the Cross-Media Limits.41


  41
     The dissent suggests that the Commission provides sufficient justification in the
Order when it explains why the newspaper + 2 TV stations combination is not allowed in
midsized markets but the newspaper + 1 TV station + 50% of allowed radio stations
combination is allowed. Order ¶ 467 (suggesting that a newspaper will benefit more
from the consolidation with its first-acquired TV station than with subsequently acquired
stations). But this does not address why the newspaper + 1 TV station + 50% allowed
radio stations combination was permitted when its Diversity Index score increases were
overall much greater than the Diversity Index score increases for other allowed

                                             73
       5.     The Commission should provide better notice on remand.

       Our decision to remand the Cross-Media Limits also gives the Commission an

opportunity to cure its questionable notice. Under the APA, an agency must publish

notice of either the terms or substance of the proposed rule or a description of the subjects

and issues involved. 5 U.S.C. § 553(b)(3). We have held that “the adequacy of the notice

must be tested by determining whether it would fairly apprise interested persons of the

‘subjects and issues’ before the agency.” Am. Iron & Steel Inst. v. EPA, 
568 F.2d 284
,

293 (3d Cir. 1977). The Citizen Petitioners argue that, in order to “fairly apprise” the

public, the Commission is also obligated to provide notice of its underlying methodology,

the reasoning from which it derived the proposed rule. The Commission’s notice only

indicated that it was considering “creating a new metric” to “reformulate [its] mechanism

for measuring diversity and competition in a market,” and that it was contemplating

“design[ing] a test that accords different weights to different outlet types.” Notice, 17

F.C.C.R. 18,503, ¶¶ 113–15. The Citizen Petitioners argue that the Commission should

have publically noticed the Diversity Index once it determined that was the methodology

on which it would rely to derive the Cross-Media Limits. See McLouth Steel Prods.

Corp. v. Thomas, 
838 F.2d 1317
(D.C. Cir. 1988) (failure to describe a particular “model”

for computing contamination levels was not adequate notice); United States v. Nova




combinations. In other words, the Commission may have proffered an explanation for
why “F” should be treated differently from seemingly similar “D,” but it does not explain
why “D” should be treated similarly from seemingly different “A,” “B,” and “C.”

                                             74
Scotia Food Prods. Corp., 
568 F.2d 240
, 251 (D.C. Cir. 1977) (agency’s failure to

provide notice of the data from which it derived regulation foreclosed “criticism of the

methodology used or the meaning to be inferred from the data”).

       The Commission argues that the Diversity Index was formulated as a response to

comments, and it need not seek additional public comment on data formulated as a

response to earlier comments.42 We are mindful that the APA’s notice obligations are not

supposed to result in a notice-and-comment “revolving door.” “Rulemaking proceedings

would never end if an agency’s response to comments must always be made the subject of

additional comments.” Cmty. Nutrition Inst. v. Block, 
749 F.2d 50
, 58 (D.C. Cir. 1984).

But courts have also suggested that an agency may withhold notice of its comment-

derived data only in the absence of prejudice. 
Id. (“The response
may, moreover, take the

form of new scientific studies without entailing the procedural consequences appellants

would impose, unless prejudice is shown.”); see also Solite Corp. v. EPA, 
952 F.2d 473
,

484 (D.C. Cir. 1991) (allowing agency to use “‘supplementary’ data, unavailable during

the notice and comment period, that ‘expand[s] on and confirm[s]’ information contained

in the proposed rulemaking and addresses ‘alleged deficiencies’ in the pre-existing data,

so long as no prejudice is shown” (citing Cmty. Nutrition 
Inst., 749 F.2d at 57
–58)

(alteration in original)). As the Diversity Index’s numerous flaws make apparent, the


  42
     The Commission also argues that the Diversity Index was “simply an analytical tool”
for measuring diversity. Resp’t Br. at 90–91. But as we noted before, see supra note 38,
it offers no suggestion that anything other than the Diversity Index was used to formulate
the Cross-Media Limits.

                                            75
Commission’s decision to withhold it from public scrutiny was not without prejudice. As

the Commission reconsiders its Cross-Media Limits on remand, it is advisable that any

new “metric” for measuring diversity and competition in a market be made subject to

public notice and comment before it is incorporated into a final rule.

                         V.    Local Television Ownership Rule

       Both the Citizen Petitioners and the Deregulatory Petitioners challenge the

Commission’s modification to the local television ownership rule, which would allow

triopolies in markets of 18 stations or more and duopolies in other markets, subject to a

restriction on combinations of the four largest stations in any market. We uphold the top-

four restriction but remand the numerical limits for the Commission to harmonize certain

inconsistencies and better support its assumptions and rationale. We also remand for the

Commission to reconsider or justify its decision to expand the rule’s waiver

provision—applicable to sales of failed, failing, or unbuilt television stations—by

eliminating the requirement that waiver applicants notice the station’s availability to out-

of-market buyers.

A.     Regulatory Background and the 2002 Biennial Review

       As part of the 1996 Act, Congress directed the Commission to conduct a

rulemaking to determine whether to “retain, modify, or eliminate” its local television

ownership rule, which at the time prohibited the common ownership of two television




                                             76
stations with overlapping Grade B signal contours.43 § 202(c)(2), 110 Stat. 111;

Amendment of Sections 73.35, 73.240, and 73.636 of the Commission’s Rules Relating to

Multiple Ownership of Standard, FM and Television Broadcast Stations, 45 F.C.C. 1476,

¶ 3 (1964) (establishing the restriction on the common ownership of televisions stations).

       In response to Congress’s directive, the Commission promulgated a rule allowing

an entity to own two television stations in the same DMA, provided that: (1) the Grade B

field-strength contours of the stations do not overlap; and (2) (a) at least one of the

stations is not ranked among the four highest-ranked stations in the DMA, and (b) at least

eight “voices”—that is, independently owned, operational, commercial or noncommercial

full-power broadcast television stations—would remain in the DMA after the proposed

combination. 1999 Television Rule Review, 14 F.C.C.R. 12,903, ¶ 8; 47 C.F.R.

§ 73.3555(b). The D.C. Circuit Court reviewed this so-called “duopoly rule,” and in 2002

remanded it for the Commission to justify its decision to count only broadcast television

stations as voices to the exclusion of other non-broadcast media. 
Sinclair, 284 F.3d at 162
.

       The Commission consolidated Sinclair’s remand order with its 2002 biennial

review under § 202(h). The Order announced the Commission’s decision to abandon the

duopoly rule in favor of a rule that would permit common ownership of two commercial


  43
    The Commission considers two field-strength contours, Grade A and Grade B, as
indicators of a station’s approximate extent of coverage over average terrain in the
absence of interference. Grade B contours measure a weaker signal than Grade A, and
thus have a wider coverage area. 47 C.F.R. § 73.683.

                                              77
stations in markets that have 17 or fewer full-power commercial and noncommercial

stations, and common ownership of three commercial stations in markets that have 18 or

more stations. Both limits are subject to a restriction44 on the common ownership of

stations ranked among the market’s largest four based on audience share. Order ¶ 186.

The Commission also decided to expand its criteria for waiving the rule’s ownership

restrictions for proposed combinations that involve failed, failing, or unbuilt stations by

eliminating the requirement that waiver applicants provide notice of the sale to out-of-

market buyers. 
Id. ¶ 225.
B.        We uphold several threshold challenges to the Commission’s overall
          regulatory approach.

          Before we consider the specific modifications to the local television rule, we

address some threshold challenges to the Commission’s regulatory approach.

          1.     Limiting local television station ownership is not duplicative of
                 antitrust regulation.

          We reject the Deregulatory Petitioners’ contention that the Commission’s local

television rule is duplicative of antitrust enforcement (by the Department of Justice and

the Federal Trade Commission) and, thus, not in the public interest. The Commission

ensures that license transfers serve public goals of diversity, competition, and localism,


     44
     Under the new rule, the top-four restriction may be waived on a case-by-case basis.
In deciding whether to grant a waiver, the Commission may consider such factors as
ratings information demonstrating the competitive effect of the merger, the proposed
merger’s effect on the stations’ ability to transition to a digital signal, and the proposed
merger’s effect on localism and viewpoint diversity. Order ¶¶ 227–30. The top-four
restriction waiver, however, is only available in markets of 11 or fewer stations.

                                               78
while the antitrust authorities have a different purpose: ensuring that merging companies

do not raise prices above competitive levels. See, e.g., Clayton Act, § 7, 15 U.S.C. § 18

(restraining mergers that would lessen competition in a market); Dep’t of Justice and

Federal Trade Comm’n, Horizontal Merger Guidelines § 0.1 (1997 rev. ed.) (“Merger

Guidelines”) (seeking to protect consumers by ensuring mergers do not result in

anticompetitive prices).

       The Deregulatory Petitioners contend that the Commission’s new regulations are

not derived from its professed reliance on audience preference, which the Commission

suggests distinguishes its regulatory approach from that of the antitrust authorities. Order

¶ 65 (pointing out that it considers audience preferences plus advertising data as

indicators of competition, while the antitrust authorities focus on prices). But the

Commission’s local television ownership rule does reflect audience preferences in at least

three ways. First, the Commission decided to focus its competition analysis on the

delivered program market (as opposed to the video programming market or the video

advertising market) because that is the market that “directly affects viewers.” 
Id. ¶ 14
1.

Second, as discussed in Part V.C below, the Commission used audience preference data

to support its conclusion that common ownership of local television stations can improve

program quality. 
Id. ¶ 15
0. Third, as also discussed in Part V.C, the Commission

justified the top-four restriction on evidence of an audience share “cushion” between the

top-four stations and the fifth-ranked station in most markets. 
Id. ¶ 195.
Thus, we reject

the Deregulatory Petitioners’ suggestion that the local television ownership rule does not

                                             79
reflect the Commission’s concern for audience preferences.

       Finally, we note that the Commission reviews all license transfers, 47 U.S.C.

§ 310(d), while the antitrust agencies typically review only large mergers. See 15 U.S.C.

§ 18a(a) (a merger must only be reported to the FTC and DOJ if the size of the transaction

exceeds $200 million or if the assets of one party exceed $10 million and the assets of the

other party exceed $100 million). Eighty-five percent of station mergers that have taken

place since 2000 would not have been subject to antitrust review because the parties’

assets fell below these thresholds. Br. of Intervenor UCC at 37 (citing BIA Financial

Network, Television Market Report (2d ed. 2003)). In this context, it hardly seems that

the Commission’s local television station ownership rule is duplicative of other agencies’

antitrust enforcement.

       2.      Media other than broadcast television may contribute to viewpoint
               diversity in local markets.

       Recognizing that allowing more television concentration in local markets could

detract from viewpoint diversity, the Commission rationalized its decision to deregulate

with its finding that media other than broadcast television contribute to viewpoint

diversity. Order ¶ 171. This is a departure from the Commission’s rationale for the

existing rule—the issue remanded by the Sinclair Court—that only television stations are

relevant to its diversity analysis.

       We agree with the Commission’s conclusion that broadcast media are not the only

media outlets contributing to viewpoint diversity in local markets. Yet because we


                                            80
remand the Commission’s numerical limits, as explained in Part V.D below, we need not

decide the degree to which non-broadcast media compensate for lost viewpoint diversity

to justify the modified rule. Rather, we leave it for the Commission to demonstrate that

there is ample substitutability from non-broadcast media to warrant the particular

numerical limits that it chooses on remand.

       We note that the record contains only weak evidence that cable can substitute for

broadcast television as a source of viewpoint diversity. For example, the Commission

found that among cable subscribers (a class that already omits one-third of American

households) only 30% have access to local cable news channels. See Order ¶ 414 n.924;

see 
also supra
Part IV.D.2 (describing why the Commission concluded that a majority of

survey respondents’ purported reliance on cable as a source of local news was probably

based on confusion with broadcast news); Reply Comments of the UCC, MM Docket No.

01-235 at 5 (Feb. 15, 2002), UCC Comments at 30–31. W ith respect to the Internet,

while record evidence indicates a negative correlation between respondents’ reliance on

broadcast television and the Internet as news sources (suggesting that people who use the

Internet for local news do so at the expense of television), the Internet is also limited in its

availability and as a source of local news. Compare MOWG Study No. 3 at 3, 34; with

UCC Reply Comments at 10 and MOWG Study No. 8 tbl. 097. Therefore, it seems that

the degree to which the Commission can rely on cable or the Internet to mitigate the

threat that local station consolidations pose to viewpoint diversity is limited.

       3.     Consolidation can improve local programming.

                                              81
       The Commission supported its decision to relax the existing “eight voices” rule

with findings that common ownership of television stations in local markets can result in

“consumer welfare enhancing efficiencies” by eliminating redundant expenses and

increasing opportunities for cross-promotion and related programming. Order ¶ 147. To

promote localism, the Commission found that these efficiencies translated into improved

local news and public interest programming.45 
Id. ¶ 164.
Evidence supporting this

conclusion included findings that commonly owned television stations are more likely to

carry local news than other stations and air a similar quality and quantity of local news as

other stations. See Bruce M. Owen et al., Effect of Common Ownership or Operation on

Television News Carriage, Quantity and Quality, in Comments of Fox Entertainment

Group, Inc. et al., MB Docket 02-277 (Jan. 2, 2003). And a study of seven commonly

owned broadcast television stations indicates that consolidation generally improved

audience ratings—the studied stations increased their audience shares by an average of

3.2% over the share they enjoyed prior to entering into co-ownership with another station.

Order ¶ 150 & n.295 (citing Mark R. Fratrik, Television Local Marketing Agreement and

Local Duopolies: Do They Generate New Competition and Diversity? (Jan. 2003),

appendix to Comments of Coalition Broadcasters et al., MM Docket 02-277 (Jan. 2,


  45
    This finding is consistent with the Commission’s 1999 decision to relax the local
television ownership rule because local ownership combinations were likely to yield
efficiencies that “can in turn lead to cost savings, which can lead to programming and
other service benefits that enhance the public interest.” Order ¶ 155 (citing 1999
Television Rule Review, 14 F.C.C.R. 12,903, ¶ 34).


                                             82
2003)). In light of this evidence, we reject the Citizen Petitioners’ contention that the

Commission’s finding of localism benefits from consolidation was unsupported.

       4.     The Comm ission adequately noticed its decision to allow triopolies.

       We also reject the Citizen Petitioners’ contention that the Commission failed to

provide adequate notice that it was considering a rule that would allow triopolies. The

APA requires agencies to publish a notice of proposed rulemaking that contains “either

the terms or substance of the proposed rule or a description of the subjects and issues

involved.” 5 U.S.C. § 553(b). The Notice advised parties that any reevaluation of the

television ownership rule would take account of the remand ordered by Sinclair, which

left it to the Commission to reexamine its “voices” test as well as “the numerical limit,

given that there is a relationship between the definition of voices and the choice of a

numerical limit.” Notice, 17 F.C.C.R. 18,503, ¶ 76 (citing 
Sinclair, 284 F.3d at 162
).

Specifically, the Commission asked for comment on “different economic incentives”

relating to diverse viewpoints in newscasting that might exist “among stand-alone

stations, duopolies, or triopolies.” 
Id. ¶ 80.
This leaves little doubt that the Notice

provided a sufficient “description of the subjects and issues involved” in the

Commission’s decision to allow triopolies.

C.     We uphold the Commission’s decision to retain the top-four restriction.

       Though the Commission recognized that the combination of television stations

within the same market could yield efficiencies that benefit consumers, the Commission

also recognized that station combinations only have an overall public “welfare-

                                              83
enhancing” effect when the consolidation does not create a “new largest” entity. Order ¶

194 (citing, inter alia, R. Preston McAfee & Michael Williams, Horizontal Mergers and

Antitrust Policy, 40 J. Indus. Econ. 181–87 (June 1992)). Thus, the Commission

determined that it had to limit allowable station combinations to those that would not

create excessive market power in a “new largest” entity. Finding that a significant

“cushion” of audience share percentage points generally separates top-four stations from

the fifth-ranked stations, the Commission decided that a top-four restriction would ensure

that station consolidations did not lead to excessive market power. 
Id. ¶ 195–96.
The

Commission also recognized that efficiencies are less prevalent when financially strong

stations merge with each other. 
Id. ¶ 197.
For example, top-four stations are already

more likely to be originating local news46 and to have made the transition to digital

television. 
Id. ¶¶ 198–99.
       The Deregulatory Petitioners assert that the top-four restriction prevents small-

market stations from yielding any of the benefits of consolidation. They argue that by

effectively precluding any consolidation in markets with fewer than five stations, the

Commission deprives the benefit of consolidation from stations—those in small

markets—who need it most. But the Commission’s local television rule is protective of



  46
     The Commission found that 85% of top-four stations offer local news programs, as
compared to 19% of stations outside the top four. Order ¶ 198 (citing Bruce M. Owen et
al., News and Public Affairs Programming Offered by the Four Top-Ranked Versus
Lower-Ranked Television Stations, included in Comments of Fox Entertainment Group,
Inc., et al., MB Docket 02-277 (Jan. 2, 2003)).

                                             84
small-market stations. The numerical limits already allowed, in effect, extra47

concentration to ensure that small-market stations would realize the efficiency benefits of

consolidation. As for the smallest markets with fewer than five stations—where the top-

four restriction operates to preclude any consolidation—it was not unreasonable for the

Commission to conclude, as it did, that the detriment of concentrated market power—e.g.,

reduced incentive to improve programming of mass appeal—outweighed the efficiency

benefits. 
Id. ¶¶ 197,
200. And, while we recognize that the Commission “cannot save an

irrational rule by tacking on a waiver procedure,” ALLTEL Corp. v. FCC, 
838 F.2d 551
,

561 (D.C. Cir. 1988), we note that the modified rule allows the Commission to waive the

top-four restriction in small markets where those consolidations would be beneficial

overall.48


  47
     As explained more fully in the next subpart, the Commission justified its numerical
limits on the belief that they would ensure six equal-sized competitors in most markets.
But the Commission departed from this rationale when it allowed duopolies in markets
with five to eleven stations. Order ¶ 201. The Commission explained that stations in
those small and mid-sized markets are experiencing greater competitive difficulty than
stations in large markets. 
Id. (citing data
on the comparative profitability of stations in
markets of various sizes). Thus, the Commission determined, it was necessary to allow
some additional concentration in those markets (relative to that allowed in the larger
markets) so that small and mid-sized market stations would realize the efficiency benefits
of consolidation.
  48
    The Deregulatory Petitioners challenge the waiver provision as well, suggesting that
the Commission’s decision to limit its availability to markets with fewer than 12 stations
is an arbitrary and capricious number “plucked out of thin air.” See 
Sinclair, 284 F.3d at 162
. But the Commission explained that its decision to draw the line at markets with
fewer than 12 stations was based on its determination that it was in those markets that
“the economics of broadcast television justify relatively greater levels of station
consolidation.” Order ¶ 227. Moreover, it is consistent with the Commission’s overall

                                            85
       The Deregulatory Petitioners also object to the top-four restriction because, they

argue, it unjustifiably treats all top-four ranked stations the same. The essence of their

objection is the Commission’s finding of a “general separation” between the top-four

stations and other stations. They point out that in many markets, especially small- and

medium-sized ones, 49 the third- and fourth-ranked stations could combine without

exceeding the audience share of the first- or second-ranked stations. Thus, they contend,

there is a more substantial “separation” between the third- and fourth-ranked stations than

between the fourth- and fifth-ranked stations.50

       But we must uphold an agency’s line-drawing decision when it is supported by the

evidence in the record. 
Sinclair, 284 F.3d at 162
; AT&T 
Corp., 220 F.3d at 627
. Here

there is ample evidence in the record to support the Commission’s restriction on

combinations among the top-four stations as opposed to the top-three or some other


approach of maintaining a balance between ensuring that small-market stations can reap
the benefits of consolidation while protecting the public’s interest in viewpoint diversity.
Thus we defer to the Commission’s expertise and affirm this particular line-drawing.
       We also note that the modified rule does not preclude a top-four restriction waiver
in a market with more than 12 stations, as the Commission expressly acknowledged its
duty to give a “hard look . . . to waiver requests.” 
Id. ¶ 85;
see also 47 C.F.R. § 1.3
(authorizing waiver of Commission rules “for good cause shown”).
  49
    In all but 18 of the markets ranked 76 to 201, the combined market share of the third-
and fourth- ranked station is less than that of the top-ranked station. Ex Parte
Communication of National Association of Broadcasters, MB Docket No. 02-277 at 4
(May 22, 2003).
  50
    In the largest 150 markets, the fourth-ranked station trailed the third-ranked station by
34% in audience share and 26% in revenue share. Bear, Stearns & Co., Inc., Duopoly
Relief Needed—4th Ranked Stations Significantly Trail 3rd Ranked Stations (May 29,
2003).

                                             86
number. The Commission found a “cushion” of audience share percentage points

between the fourth- and fifth-ranked stations in most markets. Order ¶ 195. Networks’

national audience statistics, which are generally reflected in local market rankings of

affiliated stations, also show a substantial 60% drop in audience share between the fourth-

and fifth-ranked networks. In the ten largest markets, the top-four stations combined

control at least 69% (and an average of 83%) of the local commercial share in their

respective markets, and in all of the ten largest markets a combination between the third-

and fourth-ranked stations would produce a new largest station. Local Television

Ownership and Market Concentration Study, in UCC Reply Comments at attachment 5.51

Furthermore, the Commission found that permitting mergers among top-four ranked

stations generally leads to large HHI increases.

          Thus we conclude that the Commission’s decision to retain the top-four restriction

is supported by record evidence. Accordingly, we extend deference. See 
Sinclair, 284 F.3d at 162
.

D.        We remand the specific numerical limits for the Commission’s further
          consideration.

          The Commission decided to construct its numerical limits to ensure that most



     51
    While the likelihood that a third- and fourth-ranked station combination would
produce a new largest station was lower in the mid- and small-sized markets, the market
share of those markets’ top-four stations combined was much higher than in the large
markets. 
Id. So while
the top-four restriction does not operate to protect the small and
mid-sized markets from as many “new largest station” mergers, it furthers diversity by
ensuring there are at least four independent voices in those markets.

                                              87
markets would have six equal-sized competitors because the HHI score of a six-member

market—1667 (6 x (100 ÷ 6)2 )—is below the Department of Justice and Federal Trade

Commission’s 1800 threshold for highly concentrated markets for antitrust purposes.

Order ¶¶ 192–93 (citing Merger Guidelines § 1.51(c)). Thus the Commission decided to

allow triopolies in markets of 18 stations or more (18 ÷ 3 = 6 equal-sized competitors)

and duopolies in markets of 17 or fewer (both limits subject to the restriction on a

combination of top-four stations). 
Id. ¶ 193.
       The Commission’s assumption of equal market shares received flak from both

ends of the objecting spectrum. The Citizen Petitioners point out that television stations’

market shares vary widely and argue that it is arbitrary for the Commission to base its

numerical limits on a rudimentary station “head count” of outlets. The Commission’s

rationale for its triopoly rule requires that we accept a combination of the first-, fifth-, and

sixth-ranked stations as the competitive equal of a combination of the 16th-, 17th-, and

18th-ranked stations, just because each combination consists of the same number of

stations. While the Citizen Petitioners demonstrate the Commission’s flawed rationale

with examples of what the modified rule allows, the Deregulatory Petitioners demonstrate

the same flaw by pointing out what the modified rule forbids. There is no logical reason,

they argue, why it should be impermissible to have five duopolies and one triopoly (a

total of six competitors)52 in a market with 13 stations when it is possible that the triopoly


  52
   The Deregulatory Petitioners also challenge the Commission’s six equal-sized
competitor benchmark as inconsistent with its five equal-sized competitor benchmark in

                                               88
could have a lower combined market share than any or all of the duopolies.

       The Commission defends its equal market shares approach with the suggestion that

market share, which varies with each season’s new programs, is too “fluid” to be the basis

for its regulations. 
Id. ¶ 193.
But elsewhere in the local television ownership rule the

Commission found that the market share was stable enough to rely on for support of its

top-four restriction.53 
Id. ¶ 195.
And not only is the Commission’s “market share is too

fluid” rationale inconsistent with other aspects of the rule, it is unsupported. The Order

cites no evidence to support its assumption that market share fluctuates more in television

broadcasting than in other industries. Nor does it refute the Citizen Petitioners’

suggestion that this is unlikely to be the case because, unlike most other industries,

television station owners face a barrier to market entry (requirement of a license) and the

number of market participants (television station owners) is in decline.

       The Citizen Petitioners also object to the numerical limits because they allow

markets that are already highly concentrated to become even more concentrated. For

example, Philadelphia is a market with more than 18 stations, so the modified rule would

allow the duopolist Viacom to acquire a third station and potentially increase its audience



the local radio rule. Order ¶ 289. No reason exists, however, for the Commission’s local
television ownership limits to mirror precisely its local radio ownership limits,
particularly given that there are generally more radio stations than television stations in a
given market.
  53
    The Commission also defends its rule against charges that it is duplicative of antitrust
authority by pointing out that it takes audience preferences into account, unlike antitrust
regulators who focus on prices.

                                             89
share from 25% to 34%. Philadelphia’s HHI score is already 2037, well above the

Commission’s 1800 target, and a Viacom triopoly would raise the score to 2487. We

acknowledge that the Commission never intended the numerical limits to represent a

“mechanical application of the DOJ/FTC Merger Guidelines.” 
Id. ¶ 197.
But it expressly

chose its six equal-sized competitor benchmark to ensure that markets would not exceed

the Merger Guidelines’ 1800 threshold for highly competitive markets.54 
Id. ¶ 192.
After justifying 1800 as the target, the Commission relaxed the local television ownership

rule to allow more concentration in markets that already exceed the target—which is not

just some markets, but most. UCC Reply Comments attachment 5 (28 out of 33 markets

studied had HHIs that exceeded 1800, based on 2001 data). 55


  54
     The Commission deliberately did not select the M erger Guidelines’ 1000 threshold
for moderately concentrated markets out of recognition that television stations receive
competitive pressure not only from each other but from cable networks as well.
        We reject the Deregulatory Petitioners’ contention that the Commission’s
consideration of the competitive effect of cable for this purpose is inconsistent with its
refusal to define the relevant competitive market to include cable networks. The
Commission explained that cable networks offer “almost exclusively . . . national or
broadly defined regional programming,” and thus profit-maximizing decisions reflect
national, rather than local, markets. Order ¶ 191. On this ground, the Commission
justified its decision not to accept that television and cable compete in the same market.
As a matter of degree, however, the Commission recognized that cable networks exerted
some competitive pressure on local networks, and thus selected a higher benchmark
(1800) than it otherwise might have.
  55
     The dissent says that the Commission selected the HHI score of 1800 as a mere
“starting point” for its analysis. Dissent Part IV.B. Indeed, the Commission cautioned
against “strict, overly simplistic application of the DOJ/FTC Merger Guidelines.” Order
¶ 192. But the triopoly rule was justified by the six equal-sized competitor rationale,
which was in turn derived from the Merger Guidelines’ 1800 benchmark. No other
rationale was provided. Surely, then, it is proper judicial review to call the Commission

                                            90
          The deference with which we review the Commission’s line-drawing decisions

extends only so far as the line-drawing is consistent with the evidence or is not “patently

unreasonable.” 
Sinclair, 284 F.3d at 162
. The Commission’s numerical limits are

neither. No evidence supports the Commission’s equal market share assumption, and no

reasonable explanation underlies its decision to disregard actual market share. The

modified rule is similarly unreasonable in allowing levels of concentration to exceed

further its own benchmark for competition (1800)—a glaring inconsistency between

rationale and result. We remand the numerical limits for the Commission to support and

harmonize its rationale.

E.        We remand the Comm ission’s repeal of the Failed Station Solicitation Rule.

          The Citizen Petitioners also challenge the Commission’s repeal of the Failed

Station Solicitation Rule (“FSSR”), 47 C.F.R. 73.3555 n.7, which required a waiver

applicant to provide notice of the sale to potential out-of-market buyers before it could

sell the failed, failing, or unbuilt television station to an in-market buyer.56 Order ¶ 225.



on its failure to adhere to the 1800 benchmark it selected.
     56
     The proponent of this argument is the Minority Media and Telecommunications
Council (“MMTC”), which had participated in the briefing as an intervenor party. On
April 7, 2004, MMTC withdrew its petition to the Commission for reconsideration on the
same grounds, thus eliminating the jurisdictional bar that otherwise would have precluded
our review. See West Penn Power Co. v. EPA, 
860 F.2d 581
, 587 (3d Cir. 1989). We
then accepted MMTC’s petition for review because its pending reconsideration petition
tolled the time for filing a petition for judicial review. See L.A. SMSA Ltd. P’ship v. FCC,
70 F.3d 1358
, 1359 (D.C. Cir. 1995). MMTC’s new status as a petitioner rather than an
intervenor negates the Commission’s initial concern that M MTC had impermissibly
expanded the scope of issues on review by raising an argument that was not addressed in

                                              91
       The Commission promulgated the FSSR in its review of the local television rule

that Congress had required under § 202(c) of the 1996 Act. To alleviate concerns that its

decision to allow duopolies would undermine television station ownership by minorities,

the Commission created the FSSR to ensure that qualified minority broadcasters had a fair

chance to learn that certain financially troubled—and consequently more

affordable— stations were for sale. 1999 Television Rule Review, 14 F.C.C.R. 12,903, ¶¶

13–14, 74. In the current Order, however, the Commission does not explain that

preserving minority ownership was the purpose of the FSSR, nor does it argue that the

FSSR was harmful or ineffective toward this purpose. The only support for its decision to

eliminate the FSSR is its prediction that “the efficiencies associated with operation of two

same-market stations, absent unusual circumstances, will always result in the buyer being

the owner of another station in that market.” 57 Order ¶ 225.

       By failing to mention anything about the effect this change would have on

potential minority station owners, the Commission has not provided “a reasoned analysis

indicating that prior policies and standards are being deliberately changed, not casually

ignored.” Greater Boston TV Corp. v. FCC, 
444 F.2d 841
, 852 (D.C. Cir. 1970).




any of the petitioners’ briefs.
  57
    We fail to see the logic in this proffered rationale. Even if it were true that same-
market efficiencies will always lead to a duopoly absent unusual circumstances, it does
not follow, without additional proof or explanation, that (1) marketing the station outside
the market is a meaningless burden or that (2) the Commission should not retain the FSSR
to make that “circumstance” less “unusual.”

                                             92
Furthermore, while the Commission had promised in 1999 to “expand opportunities for

minorities and women to enter the broadcast industry,” 1999 Television Rule Review, 14

F.C.C.R. 12,903, ¶ 14, the FSSR remained its only policy specifically aimed at fostering

minority television station ownership. In repealing the FSSR without any discussion of

the effect of its decision on minority television station ownership (and without ever

acknowledging the decline in minority station ownership notwithstanding the FSSR), the

Commission “entirely failed to consider an important aspect of the problem,” and this

amounts to arbitrary and capricious rulemaking.58 State 
Farm, 463 U.S. at 43
; see also

Copps Dissent, 18 F.C.C.R. at 13,970–71 (chastising the Commission for “fail[ing] to

conduct rigorous analysis of today’s rules on minorities and women); Adelstein Dissent,

18 F.C.C.R. at 13,997 (same). For correction of this omission, we remand.59

                          VI.    Local Radio Ownership Rule

       Petitioners challenge the Commission’s decision to modify its local radio




  58
     Repealing its only regulatory provision that promoted minority television station
ownership without considering the repeal’s effect on minority ownership is also
inconsistent with the Commission’s obligation to make the broadcast spectrum available
to all people “without discrimination on the basis of race.” 47 U.S.C. § 151.
  59
    We also note that the Commission deferred consideration of the MMTC’s other
proposals for advancing minority and disadvantaged businesses and for promoting
diversity in broadcasting. See Order ¶¶ 49–50 (promising to issue a Notice of Proposed
Rulemaking to address the MMTC’s thirteen specific proposals); 
id. ¶ 52
(deferring
consideration of the MMTC’s “Transaction Nondiscrimination” proposal pending
recommendations from its Advisory Committee for Diversity). The Commission’s
rulemaking process in response to our remand order should address these proposals at the
same time.

                                            93
ownership rule, which limits the number of commercial radio stations that a party may

own in local markets of different sizes, 47 C.F.R. § 73.3555(a), by, among other changes,

adopting a new method for determining the size of local markets. They also argue that

the Commission failed to justify its decision to retain the rule’s specific numerical limits.

We affirm the Commission’s decision to modify the rule (including modifying its method

for determining local market size), but we agree that its decision to retain the numerical

limits was arbitrary and capricious, and hence remand for the Commission’s further

consideration.

A.           Regulatory Background and the 2002 Biennial Review

             In 1992 the Commission abandoned its one-to-a-market limit on radio station

ownership and implemented tiered numerical limits that allowed for common ownership

of as many as six (three AM and three FM) stations—but no more than a combined 25%

of the market’s total audience share—in the largest markets of 40 or more commercial

stations.60 In 1996 Congress directed the Commission to relax the tiered limits even


     60
          Specifically, the numerical limits provided that:
            (1)     In markets with fewer than 15 radio stations, a single licensee will be
            permitted to own up to three stations, no more than two of which are in the
            same service, provided that the owned stations represent less than 50
            percent of the stations in the market. Common ownership of one AM/FM
            combination will continue to be allowed in any event.
            (2)     In markets with 15 to 29 radio stations, a single licensee will be
            permitted to own up to two AM stations and two FM stations, provided that
            the combined audience share of the stations does not exceed 25 percent.
            (3)     In markets with 30 to 39 radio stations, a single licensee will be
            permitted to own up to three AM stations and two FM stations, provided
            that the combined audience share of the stations does not exceed 25 percent.

                                                  94
more, to allow for as many as eight radio stations (but no more than five in the same AM

or FM service) to be commonly owned in the largest markets of 45 or more commercial

stations.61 Additionally, Congress required that the Commission review these limits

biennially and repeal or modify them as necessary in the public interest. 
Id. § 202(h),
110

Stat. at 111–12.

          In its 1998 and 2000 biennial reviews, the Commission decided to retain the same

numerical limits enacted by Congress after finding that they continued to be necessary in

the public interest. 1998 Biennial Regulatory Review, 15 F.C.C.R. 11,058, ¶ 59 (2000);

2000 Biennial Regulatory Review, 16 F.C.C.R. 1207, ¶ 32 (2001). But separately the

Commission initiated a proceeding to consider modifying the way in which it

“determine[s] the dimensions of radio markets and counts the number of stations in

them.” Definition of Radio Markets, 15 F.C.C.R. 25,077, ¶ 1 (2001). That rulemaking

was later consolidated with the 2002 biennial review. Notice, 17 F.C.C.R. 18,503, ¶ 7.

          In its 2002 biennial review, the Commission again decided that the numerical

limits set by Congress in 1996 remained necessary in the public interest. Order ¶ 239.

But the Commission changed its method for determining the size of a radio station

market. Since the Commission first promulgated tiered numerical limits in 1992, it had



      (4)    In markets with 40 or more radio stations, a single licensee may own
      up to three AM stations and three FM stations, provided that the combined
      audience share of the stations does not exceed 25 percent.
57 Fed. Reg. at 18090.
  61
       Congress’s 1996 Act-directed limits are set out in full at Part 
I.F.2 supra
.

                                                95
defined the markets as the overlapping area of radio stations’ coverage. 47 C.F.R.

§ 73.3555(a)(3)(ii); 57 Fed. Reg. 18,089 (Apr. 29, 1992). For each proposed combination

of stations, the local market was defined by “the number of . . . stations whose principal

community contours overlap, in whole or in part, with the principal community contours

of the stations” that were proposed to be commonly owned. 47 C.F.R.

§ 73.3555(a)(3)(ii).62

         Following the 2002 biennial review, the Commission decided to replace this so-

called “contour-overlap methodology” with the geography-based market definition used

by Arbitron, a private entity that measures local radio station audiences for its customer

stations. Order ¶¶ 275–76. Within these so-called “Arbitron Metro markets,” the number

of total radio stations would include both commercial and noncommercial stations that are

licensed to a community within the market, as well as stations located outside the market

that attract a minimum level of listenership within, see 
id. ¶¶ 279-81,
295. Under the

1996 Act, only commercial stations had counted in determining the size of the market.

         Though the Commission decided to grandfather any existing radio station

combinations rendered noncompliant by the switch to Arbitron Metro markets, it

restricted transfer of those combinations, subject to a limited exception for sales to

eligible small businesses. 
Id. ¶ 489.
         In an additional modification to the local radio ownership rule, stations under Joint



  62
       The 1996 Act did not define radio markets by any particular methodology.

                                               96
Sales Agreements— as noted earlier, when a licensee authorizes a broker station to sell

advertising time on the licensee’s station in return for a fee—would be “attributed” to the

brokering entity for the purpose of determining the brokering entity’s compliance with the

applicable limit. 
Id. ¶ 317.
B.     We uphold the Comm ission’s new definition of local markets.

       Both the Deregulatory Petitioners and the Citizen Petitioners object to the

Commission’s changes to the way in which it defines a local radio market. Predictably,

the Deregulatory Petitioners object to the modification that decreases the size of local

markets (using Arbitron Metro markets instead of the contour-overlap

methodology)—which potentially lowers the applicable numerical limit in a given

market—while the Citizen Petitioners object to the modification that increases the size of

local markets (inclusion of noncommercial stations)—which potentially raises the

applicable numerical limit in a given market. But we conclude that the Commission has

justified these changes under § 202(h) and they are not arbitrary and capricious under the

APA.

       1.     The Comm ission justified using Arbitron Metro markets.

       We reject out of hand the Deregulatory Petitioners’ argument that, by changing the

market definition methodology, the Commission effectively increased the numerical

limits in violation of § 202(h)’s presumption in favor of deregulation. As discussed in

Part II above, § 202(h) is not a one-way ratchet. The Commission is free to regulate or

deregulate as long as its regulations are in the public interest and are supported by a

                                             97
reasoned analysis. The change to Arbitron Metro markets is both.

       Under the existing rule, to determine whether an entity may acquire a radio station

under the local radio rule, the Commission first must know how many radio stations are

in that station’s local market (called the “denominator” figure). The size of the market

determines which numerical limit applies. Second, the Commission must determine how

many radio stations in that market would be owned by the same entity if the entity

acquired the stations it proposes (called the “numerator” figure). If this figure is within

the numerical limit, the transaction may proceed.

       Under the contour-overlap methodology, the Commission calculates the numerator

by counting the acquiring entity’s radio stations that all have overlapping signal contours.

A station whose signal contour overlaps with some but not all of the other stations’

contours will not be counted in the numerator. The Commission calculates the

denominator by counting all of the stations whose contours intersect with at least one (not

all) of the contours of another station in the numerator.

       The Commission found that the contour-overlap methodology results in

inconsistency between the numerator and denominator figures for a given transaction.

Some radio stations owned by the acquiring entity may be counted in the denominator

(because their contours intersect with at least one of the numerator-station’s contours) but

not the numerator (because their contours do not intersect with all of the other numerator-

station’s contours). An acquiring entity might actually own stations that do not count

toward determining how many more it may own within the numerical limit, but do count

                                             98
toward determining the size of the market, where a bigger number correlates to a higher

applicable limit. Order ¶ 253. The numerator/denominator inconsistency gives rise not

only to an artificially low numerator/denominator ratio, which favors combinations but

also the potential that combination owners could strategically acquire stations—those

whose signals overlap with some, but not all of their already-owned stations’ signals—to

end-run the numerical limits altogether. 
Id. ¶ 254.
Furthermore, a “perverse incentive”

problem arises, as the contour-overlap methodology actually encourages consolidation of

powerful radio stations because the stations with larger signals are more likely to create

larger markets, which makes it more likely that their owner would be able to acquire even

more radio stations in the market. 
Id. ¶ 257.
       The Commission determined that it could not fix these problems with the contour-

overlap methodology “merely by excluding commonly owned stations from the

denominator or including those stations in the numerator.” 
Id. ¶ 255.
Excluding those

stations from the denominator would mean the Commission was determining the size of

the market based on who owns the stations, “a distinction that would be both unprincipled

and unprecedented in the history of competition analysis.” 
Id. On the
other hand,

including all commonly owned stations that are represented in the denominator could

overly inflate ownership levels by including “outlying stations far from the area of

concentration.” 
Id. The Commission
also found that its transaction-specific market definitions

frustrated its ability to benchmark and compute the level of competition in a given area.

                                             99
Thus it determined that “a local radio market that is objectively determined, i.e., that is

independent of the radio stations involved in a particular acquisition, presents the most

rational basis for the defining radio markets.” 
Id. ¶ 273.
For these reasons, the

Commission decided to jettison the contour-based methodology and instead employ

Arbitron’s existing geographical definitions of local markets, finding they are the

“established industry standard” that “represent a reasonable geographic market

delineation within which radio stations compete.” 
Id. ¶ 276.63
       As the Deregulatory Petitioners point out, the Commission’s reliance on Arbitron

Metro markets is not without flaw. One obvious problem is that this method of measure

does not cover the entire country. In fact, about 70% of counties in the United States are

not within one of the 287 Arbitron Metro markets. But people tend to be clustered in

specific population centers, as 78% of the United States’ population over the age of 12

lives in Arbitron Metro markets. Nor has the Commission ignored the minority of the

public who does not live in Arbitron Metro markets. It initiated a new rulemaking

proceeding to develop market definitions for these areas, and in the interim decided to use

a modified contour-overlap methodology that “minimize[s] the more problematic aspects

of that system.” 
Id. ¶ 285.
       The Deregulatory Petitioners argue that the Commission failed to demonstrate that

the contour-overlap methodology was actually harming competition. One petitioner


  63
   In addition, the Commission noted that the Department of Justice treats Arbitron
Metros as the relevant market for antitrust purposes. Order ¶ 276.

                                             100
called the Commission’s explanation of the numerator/denominator inconsistency an

“exercise in graduate school theoretical economics.” Tr. at 394. But the Commission did

find evidence of potential competitive harm in a working group study suggesting that

station consolidation under the contour-overlap regime has resulted in an increase in

advertising prices. Order ¶ 261 n.548. And, as described above, the Commission

observed that the contour-overlap methodology created a “perverse incentive” problem,

as the most powerful stations whose contours intersect more stations (and thus have a

larger denominator) are more able than smaller stations to acquire more stations. 
Id. ¶ 257.
The Commission also found that the contour-overlap methodology impairs its

ability accurately to measure and compare competition in consistently defined markets.

Id. ¶ 259.
The Commission’s findings provide ample justification for the conclusion that

the contour-overlap methodology’s resulting inconsistencies are more than just abstract

theory.

          Next we reject the Deregulatory Petitioners’ argument that the Commission

improperly departed from its past precedent, namely, its 1992 and 1994 decisions to retain

the contour-overlap methodology. See Revision of Radio Rules and Policies, 7 F.C.C.R.

6387, ¶¶ 37–40 (1992); Revision of Radio Rules and Policies, 9 F.C.C.R. 7183, ¶ 35

(1994). In State Farm, the Supreme Court said that when an agency reverses its “former

views” it is “obligated to supply a reasoned analysis for the change beyond that which

may be required when an agency does not act in the first 
instance.” 463 U.S. at 41
–42;

see also Rust v. Sullivan, 
500 U.S. 173
, 186 (1991). Here the Commission supplied a

                                             101
reasoned analysis for the change— that “[i]t was only after the ownership limits were

substantially raised in the 1996 Act that the scope of the market distorting effects of that

system became manifest.” Order ¶ 262.

       The Deregulatory Petitioners argue that because radio is a signal-based enterprise,

any market definition that ignores the actual reach of station signals and the scope of their

listenership does not accurately measure competition. But we believe that it was

reasonable for the Commission to conclude that fixed, geography-based market

definitions more readily enable accurate measurement and comparison of competition

than a transaction-specific, contour-based definition. 
Id. ¶ 259.
       Finally, the Deregulatory Petitioners point out that Arbitron makes money from its

station customers, and it has financial and other obligations to those stations and its

shareholders. Therefore, they argue, Arbitron’s economic incentives render its market

definitions subject to manipulation. But the Commission recognized these potential

problems and adequately established specific safeguards to deter potential manipulation,

including a two-year buffer period before any party can receive the benefit of either a

change in Arbitron Metro market boundaries or the addition of more radio stations to the

market. 
Id. ¶ 278.
The Deregulatory Petitioners’ suggested conjectural flaws do not

persuade us that the Commission’s adoption of Arbitron Metro markets was arbitrary and

capricious. We also reject their contention that the Commission’s use of Arbitron

markets delegates governmental power to a private entity. Arbitron will only provide a

mechanism for measuring concentration. Because the Commission remains the sole

                                             102
arbiter of whether a proposed radio station combination serves the public interest, no

improper delegation will occur.

       For these reasons, we conclude that the Commission’s decision to replace contour-

overlap methodology with Arbitron Metro markets was “in the public interest” within the

meaning of § 202(h) and that it was a rational exercise of rulemaking authority.

       2.     The Comm ission justified including noncommercial stations.

       The Citizen Petitioners object to the Commission’s decision to count both

noncommercial and commercial stations in determining the size of an Arbitron Metro

market.64 They argue that the inclusion of noncommercial stations increases the number

of stations in a given market and thereby allows more consolidation under the numerical

limits. It is impermissibly inconsistent, they argue, to increase effectively the numerical

limits in this way while at the same time defending the existing numerical limits from

arguments that they should be relaxed. But we reject this argument’s factual premise that

counting noncommercial stations will increase significantly the number of stations in a

given market. Even counting noncommercial stations in the definition of markets, the

change to Arbitron Metro markets operates as a net decrease in most markets’ size.65 This


  64
    The Commission included noncommercial stations upon finding that they “exert[]
competitive pressure on all other radio stations in the market seeking to attract the
attention of the same body of potential listeners.” Order ¶ 295.
  65
    In 33 markets of various sizes, investment banking firm Bear Stearns found that there
would be an average 47.5% fewer stations under the Commission’s adopted approach
(that includes noncommercial stations and uses Arbitron Metro markets) than under the
existing approach (that excludes noncommercial stations and employs the contour-overlap

                                            103
undercuts the Citizen Petitioners’ argument that it was inconsistent for the Commission to

increase the sizes of local markets while justifying the existing numerical limits. It was

not arbitrary and capricious, therefore, for the Commission to take account of

noncommercial stations in determining the ownership limits.66

C.        We uphold the Commission’s transfer restriction.

          In applying its local ownership rules, the Commission decided to grandfather

existing radio, television, and radio/television combinations, and did “not require entities

to divest their current interests in stations in order to come into compliance with the new

ownership rules.” Order ¶ 484.67 Under past Commission rules, radio stations created in

compliance with the rules were freely transferable under the Commission’s policy that



methodology). In only 6 of the 33 markets studied by Bear Stearns was there an increase
in market size under the adopted approach. See Bear, Stearns and Co., A Defining
Moment in Radio?, MB Docket No. 02-277 (May 12, 2003).
     66
     We also reject the Citizen Petitioners’ contention that Commission failed to provide
adequate notice of its decision to include noncommercial stations in its new market
definition. The Notice stated that the Commission would engage in a “comprehensive
review” of its media ownership rules, including, specifically, whether its competition
analysis should focus on “competition for viewers/listeners,” “competition for
programming,” and “competition for advertising.” 17 F.C.C.R. 18,503, ¶¶ 50, 52, 57.
This language adequately apprised the public that the Commission might find, as it did,
that noncommercial stations compete with commercial stations for listeners.
     67
     Though the Commission restricted the transfer of existing combinations rendered
noncompliant by all three local rules (Cross-Media Limits, local radio ownership rule,
and local television ownership rule), we consider the Deregulatory Petitioners’ challenges
to the transfer restrictions issue within the context of the local radio rule because the
modifications to the local radio rule (i.e., the change to Arbitron Metro markets) are more
likely than the deregulatory modifications to the other two local rules to render existing
combinations noncompliant.

                                             104
maintaining the status quo did not create new harm to public interest goals. See Revision

of Radio Rules and Policies, 7 F.C.C.R. 6387, ¶ 48. Switching course, in this Order the

Commission refused to permit the transfer or sale of grandfathered combinations that

violate its local ownership limits except to certain “eligible entities” that qualify as small

businesses.68 Order ¶ 488. We reject the Deregulatory Petitioners’ arguments that this

modification to the local radio ownership rule contravenes § 202(h), constitutes arbitrary

and capricious rulemaking, and violates the United States Constitution.

         1.     Transfer restriction is “in the public interest.”

         The Commission successfully demonstrates that the transfer restriction is “in the

public interest” as required under § 202(h).69 The Commission notes that forcing

divestitures at the time of transfer “could afford new entrants the opportunity to enter the

media marketplace” and “could give smaller station owners already in the market the

opportunity to acquire more stations,” which would promote the public interest in having

competitive and diverse radio markets. 
Id. ¶ 487.
Additionally, the Commission found a

strong public interest in curtailing the perpetuation of “combinations [that] were created

pursuant to a market definition that we conclude fails to adequately reflect competitive


  68
       An eligible entity is a business with $6 million or less in annual revenue. Order ¶
489.
  69
     The Deregulatory Petitioners argue that the transfer restriction, as an anti-
deregulatory modification, is per se invalid under § 202(h). As we explained in Part II,
we do not read § 202(h) to impose such a stringent standard for rulemaking. For our
review purposes, any modification, whether deregulatory or regulatory, that is “in the
public interest” survives threshold scrutiny under § 202(h).

                                              105
conditions.” 
Id. Unlike its
decision not to require noncompliant combinations to divest,

the Commission decided to restrict transfers because it found no “countervailing

considerations” (such as the expectancy interests of existing station owners) to outweigh

the public interest. 
Id. This rationale
satisfies the public interest requirement under

§ 202(h).

       2.     Transfer restriction is reasoned decisionmaking.

       According to the Deregulatory Petitioners, the transfer restriction is arbitrary and

capricious because the Commission “failed to consider an important aspect of the

problem”—as required under State Farm, 
see 463 U.S. at 43
—by ignoring the fact that

combination-owners’ investments are diminished by the rule. Requiring station

combinations to spin off noncompliant stations depresses the price of the station

combinations as a whole, which deprives combination-owners (as sellers) of their

expected investments. But an agency is not restricted in its rulemaking by the

expectations of the regulated. Borough of Columbia v. Surface Transp. Bd., 
342 F.3d 222
, 236 (3d Cir. 2003) (recognizing that parties who enter the market knowing that the

industry is heavily regulated “cannot be said to have been surprised that the [agency’s]

decisions might thwart its goals”); see also 
Sinclair, 284 F.3d at 166
(upholding a

modification to the local television ownership rule “notwithstanding that it may upset

some expectations”).

       The Deregulatory Petitioners also suggest that the Order arbitrarily and

capriciously exempted sales to “eligible entities” from the transfer restriction because the

                                             106
Commission did not purport to analyze whether small businesses ($6 million or less in

annual revenue) would actually be able to obtain financing necessary to acquire a

noncompliant radio station combination. But the rationality of the transfer restriction

does not depend on the “eligible entities” exception. It is enough for the Commission to

decide, as it did, that when it comes to small business the relative diversity advantages to

a market in which an eligible-entity transfer occurred would outweigh the disadvantages

to the market’s competition interests from the perpetuation of a noncompliant

combination. The number of times the exception is invoked is irrelevant to the

reasonableness of the transfer restriction as a whole.70

       3.     Transfer restriction is constitutional.

       We reject also the Deregulatory Petitioners’ suggestion that the Commission’s

restriction on the transferability of pre-existing noncompliant consolidations “raises

serious constitutional questions” 71 under the Due Process and Takings Clauses of the


  70
     We also reject the Citizen Petitioners’ contention that the Commission should have
chosen “socially and economically disadvantaged businesses” (SDBs) as the waiver-
eligible class instead of Small Business Administration-defined small businesses. It noted
that small businesses often include women- and minority-owned stations. Order ¶ 488.
The Commission noted that, because of pending legislation, the definition of SDBs is
currently too uncertain to be the basis of its regulation. 
Id. ¶ 488
n.1042. We anticipate,
however, that by the next quadrennial review the Commission will have the benefit of a
stable definition of SDBs, as well as several years of implementation experience, to help
it reevaluate whether an SDB-based waiver will better promote the Commission’s
diversity objectives.
  71
    It is perhaps telling that the Deregulatory Petitioners do not argue that “questions”
raised by this aspect of the Order rise to the level of an actual constitutional violation. Br.
of Pet’r Clear Channel at 49.

                                             107
Constitution’s Fifth Amendment. 72

       In order to succeed in a due process or takings case under the Fifth Amendment,

the plaintiff must first show that a legally cognizable property interest is affected by the

Government’s action in question. See Cleveland Bd. of Educ. v. Loudermill, 
470 U.S. 532
, 538 (1985) (requiring protected property interest for due process violation); Webb’s

Fabulous Pharmacies, Inc. v. Beckwith, 
449 U.S. 155
, 160–61 (1980) (requiring protected

property interest for taking). But broadcast licenses, which are the subject of the

Commission’s restriction on transferability, are not protected property interests under the

Fifth Amendment. See FCC v. Sanders Bros. Radio Station, 
309 U.S. 470
, 475 (1940)

(“The policy of the [1936 Communications] Act is clear that no person is to have

anything in the nature of a property right as a result of the granting of a license.”); see

also CBS, Inc. v. FCC, 
453 U.S. 367
, 395 (1981) (noting that the broadcast spectrum is

part of the public domain and that a broadcaster merely has “use of a limited and valuable

part of the public domain; when he accepts that franchise it is burdened by enforceable

public obligations” (quoting Office of Communication of the United Church of Christ v.

FCC, 
359 F.2d 994
, 1003 (D.C. Cir. 1966))); 47 U.S.C. § 301 (broadcast licenses provide

for the “use . . . but not the ownership” of channels of communication)). Broadcast

licensees accept their licenses subject to the Commission’s power to regulate their



  72
    The Fifth Amendment provides, “No person shall . . . be deprived of life, liberty, or
property, without due process of law; nor shall private property be taken for public use,
without just compensation.” U.S. Const. Amend. V.

                                              108
transfer pursuant to “the public interest, convenience, and necessity.” 47 U.S.C. § 310(d).

Because a legally cognizable property interest is not implicated by the Commission’s

decision to restrict the transfer of pre-existing, noncompliant station combinations, a Fifth

Amendment violation will not occurr.

D.        We affirm the attribution of Joint Sales Agreements.

          Under a Joint Sales Agreement (“JSA”), a radio station authorizes a broker to sell

advertising time on the station in exchange for a fee. In the Order, the Commission

decided to count stations brokered under a JSA toward the brokering station’s permissible

ownership totals (that is, to “attribute” JSAs), as long as (1) the brokering entity owns or

has an attributable interest in one or more stations in the local market, and (2) the joint

advertising sales amount to more than 15% of the brokered station’s advertising time per

week. Order ¶ 317. The Commission justified this departure from its prior policy of

nonattribution with its finding that in-market JSAs above the 15% threshold convey to the

brokering entity a degree of “influence or control” sufficient to warrant limitation under

the ownership rules—i.e., a “realistic potential to affect [the brokered station’s]

programming and other core operating decisions.” 73 
Id. ¶ 318.
Furthermore, the

brokering entity has the ability and the incentive to exercise market power because it

controls the advertising revenue of the brokered stations and assumes the financial risks



     73
     In this way, the Commission found that JSAs were no different from their Local
Marketing Agreement counterparts under the local television rule, which are attributable.
Id. ¶ 318.
                                              109
and rewards of advertising. 
Id. ¶ 320.
The Commission gave parties to JSAs two years to

end their agreements or otherwise come into compliance with the local ownership rules.

Id. ¶ 325.
We reject the Deregulatory Petitioners’ arguments that this modification to the

local radio ownership rule contravenes § 202(h), constitutes arbitrary and capricious

rulemaking, and violates the Constitution.

       1.     Attribution of JSAs is “necessary in the public interest.”

       In the Order the Commission explained that, due to their potential to convey

influence to brokering entities, JSAs “may undermine [the Commission’s] continuing

interest in broadcast competition sufficiently to warrant limitation under the multiple

ownership rule.” 
Id. ¶ 318.
The Commission’s decision to modify its attribution policy

to “reflect accurately the competitive conditions of today’s local radio markets,” 
id. ¶ 321,
and thus prevent its local radio rule from being undermined, is a modification “in the

public interest” under § 202(h). 74

       2.     Attribution of JSAs is reasoned decisionmaking.

       An agency that departs from its “former views” is “obligated to supply a reasoned

analysis for the change beyond that which may be required in the first instance” in order

to survive judicial scrutiny for compliance with the APA. State 
Farm, 463 U.S. at 41
–42.

Here the Commission acknowledged that its decision to attribute JSAs was a departure



  74
    Again we reject the Deregulatory Petitioners’ arguments that, as an anti-deregulatory
modification, this aspect of the Order is a per se violation of § 202(h). 
See supra
Part
II.B.

                                             110
from its prior policy of nonattribution, promulgated in 1999. Order ¶ 320 n.698. The

Commission explained that, “upon reexamination of the issue,” it found that JSAs convey

the potential for brokering entities to influence the brokered stations; thus a policy of

attributing JSAs is necessary to “reflect accurately competitive conditions of today’s local

radio markets.” 
Id. ¶¶ 320,
321.

       The Deregulatory Petitioners argue that this proffered rationale is insufficient

because the Commission does not explain what, if anything, transpired since 1999 that

accounts for its change of position. But because we interpret the Commission’s

modification as a correction of its prior policy’s “inaccuracy,” the Commission’s failure

to cite a particular intervening change is not fatal to its reasoned analysis. In this context

we accept that the Commission’s determination—upon “reexamination of the issue” that

the JSAs convey (and always have conveyed) a potential for influence— sufficiently

rationalizes its decision to jettison its prior nonattribution policy and replace it with one

that more accurately reflects the conditions of local markets.

       3.     Attribution of JSAs is constitutional.

       We also disagree with the Deregulatory Petitioners’ suggestion that the attribution

of JSAs “raises serious constitutional concerns”75 under the Fifth Amendment’s Takings

Clause. Contracts such as JSAs are protected property interests under the Fifth



  75
    Again it is telling that the Deregulatory Petitioners do not argue that “concerns”
raised by this aspect of the Order rise to the level of an actual constitutional violation. Br.
of Pet’r Clear Channel at 58.

                                              111
Amendment, see United States Trust Co. of N.Y. v. New Jersey, 
431 U.S. 1
, 19 n.16

(1977), but here the Commission has not invalidated or interfered with any contracts. In

deciding to attribute JSAs, it is has simply decided that stations subject to JSAs should, in

certain circumstances, count toward the regulatory limit in determining how many

stations the brokering entity may own in a market. Moreover, station owners have no

vested right in the continuation of any particular regulatory scheme. Folden v. United

States, 
56 Fed. Cl. 43
, 61 (2003) (parties “in a highly regulated field such as FCC

licensing can have no distinct investment-backed expectations that include a reliance

upon a legislative and regulatory status quo”); cf. Connolly v. Pension Benefit Guar.

Corp., 
475 U.S. 211
, 222–27 (1986) (no regulatory taking occurred because government

had not appropriated property for its own use, did not impose a severe economic impact,

and did not interfere with reasonable expectations). Thus we reject the Deregulatory

Petitioners’ suggestion that the attribution of JSAs will result in a regulatory taking.

E.     We remand the numerical limits to the Commission for further justification.

       In the Order, the Commission announced its decision to retain the existing

numerical limits on radio ownership that Congress established in § 202(b) of the 1996

Act. The existing limits preclude the common ownership of radio stations with

overlapping principal community contours, except that: (1) in a radio market with 45 or

more commercial radio stations, a party may own up to eight commercial radio stations,

not more than five of which are in the same service (that is, AM or FM ); (2) in a radio

market with between 30 and 44 commercial radio stations, a party may own up to seven

                                             112
commercial radio stations, not more than four of which are in the same service; (3) in a

radio market with between 15 and 29 commercial radio stations, a party may own up to

six commercial stations, not more than four of which are in the same service; and (4) in a

market with 14 or fewer commercial radio stations, a party may own up to five

commercial radio stations, not more than three of which are in the same service, except

that a party may not own more than 50 percent of the stations in that market. 1996 Act,

§ 202(b)(1), 110 Stat. at 110; 47 C.F.R. § 73.3555(a)(1).

       First, the Commission defended its use of numerical limits from those commenters

who argued that there should be no limits at all on local radio station ownership. The

Commission explained that radio is a closed-entry market, i.e., all available

radiofrequency spectrum has been licensed. So the only way to develop market power is

to buy existing stations. Thus, the Commission says, numerical limits are a reasonable

way of preventing available capacity from being “locked up” in the hands of a few

owners. Order ¶ 288.

       The Commission then explained that the specific numerical limits that it currently

employs are effective to this end. Citing economic literature, the Commission suggested

that a market with five equal-sized competitors is a sufficiently competitive market. The

existing limits allow for roughly five equal-sized firms in each market. (For example, the

eight-station limit for markets of 45 or more stations allows for five eight-station

combinations). 
Id. ¶ 289.
The Commission concluded that the existing limits ensure




                                             113
sufficiently competitive local markets.76 The Commission also concluded that the

existing limits are not overly restrictive based on data showing that the top-four stations

in each metro market are thriving in terms of revenue and audience share. 
Id. ¶ 290.
       As explained in Part II.B above, § 202(h) operates to extend the “reasoned

analysis” requirement (which ordinarily applies only to an agency’s decision to

promulgate new regulations or modify existing ones) to apply also to the Commission’s

decision to retain existing regulations. Although we accept the Commission’s rationale

for employing numerical limits (as opposed to other regulatory approaches such as a case-

by-case analysis), we conclude that the Commission’s decision to retain the specific

numerical limits is not supported by a reasoned analysis.

       1.     The Commission’s numerical limits approach is rational and in the
              public interest.


  76
    The Commission also explained why the numerical limits depart from the five equal-
sized competitor rationale. Of its decision not to adopt a 10-station limit for markets with
50 or more stations, the Commission said that it found no evidence that additional
consolidation would increase efficiencies in those markets. Furthermore, the Commission
said that the largest markets usually have many small, low-power stations, which make
those markets appear more competitive than they actually are. A numerical limit that
ensures even more than five equal-sized competitors in these largest markets provides a
competition-protecting cushion that compensates for this. Order ¶ 291. The Commission
also realized that its numerical limits for the smaller market tiers also depart from the five
equal-sized competitor rationale. It maintained that, in small markets, “greater levels of
concentration may be needed to ensure the potential for viability of radio stations.” 
Id. ¶ 292.
       As explained below, we believe that the numerical limits lack a rational
underpinning in the “five equal-sized competitor” theory the Commission advanced. But
because we remand for further justification by the Commission, we do not address
Petitioners’ arguments regarding the Commission’s departure from the five equal-sized
competitor rationale.

                                             114
       The Commission’s decision to retain a numerical limits approach to radio station

ownership regulation is “in the public interest.” W ithout numerical limits, radio markets

risk becoming “locked up” in the hands of a few owners (or even one owner) because all

of the available radiofrequency spectrum has been licensed—a high barrier to new market

entrants. Order ¶ 288. Based on record evidence, the Commission justifiably concluded

that numerical limits are necessary “to guard against consolidation . . . and to ensure a

market structure that fosters opportunities for new entry into radio broadcasting.” 
Id. ¶ 291.
For example, a MOW G study found that, since the existing limits were imposed in

1996, the number of radio station owners declined by 34% even though the number of

stations increased by 5.4%. George Williams & Scott Roberts, Radio Industry Review

2002: Trends in Ownership, Format, and Finance (MOW G Study No. 11) at 3 (Sept.

2002). Additionally, the record shows that today 10 parent companies—the largest of

which, Clear Channel Communications, owns 1200 stations nationwide, or

10%— dominate the radio industry and control about two-thirds of both listeners and

radio revenues nationwide. 
Id. at 4.
In contrast, prior to the 1996 Act’s deregulation, the

largest nationwide radio station combinations had fewer than 65 stations each. 
Id. Furthermore, the
record shows how increased consolidation has increased station

prices, which limits opportunities for new market entrants and as a result limits diversity

in station ownership and output. UCC Comments at 18. Consolidation has also reduced

the amount of locally produced radio content, as large group-owners often broadcast


                                            115
remotely from national offices instead of having local employees produce programming.

Comments of Future of Music Coalition, MB Docket 02-277 at 13–14 (Nov. 20, 2002).

The record contains examples of consolidated stations that eliminated local news

production. UCC Comments at 37–38. The evidence thus supports the Commission’s

conclusion that, by continuing to limit the consolidation of radio stations, numerical limits

are “in the public interest” as required under § 202(h).

        2.    The Commission did not support its decision to retain the existing
              numerical limits with reasoned analysis.

       Both the Citizen Petitioners and the Deregulatory Petitioners argue that the

Commission’s decision to retain the existing numerical limits was arbitrary and

capricious. Predictably, the Citizen Petitioners argue that the Commission should have

tightened the existing limits, and the Deregulatory Petitioners argue that the Commission

should have relaxed them. But both sides’ predominant argument is essentially the same:

the numerical limits are not supported by the Commission’s theory that they ensure five

equal-sized competitors in most markets. While, as discussed above, substantial evidence

supports the Commission’s decision to retain the numerical limits structure of its local

radio ownership rule, we also agree with the Petitioners that the Order lacks a reasoned

analysis for retaining these specific numerical limits. We thus remand for the

Commission’s additional justification.




                                            116
              a.     The Commission did not sufficiently justified “five equal-sized
                     competitors” as the right benchmark.

       The Commission relied on game theory to support its premise that five equal-sized

competitors ensure that local markets are fragmented and structurally competitive.

Order ¶ 289 n.609 (citing Louis Phillips, Competition Policy: A Game Theory

Perspective Ch. 2 (1995); Timothy F. Bresnahan & Peter C. Reiss, Entry and Competition

in Concentrated M arkets, 99 J. Pol. Econ. 997 (1991); Reinhard Selten, A Simple Model

of Imperfect Competition Where Four Are Few and Six Are Many, 2 Int’l J. Game Theory

141 (1973)). The Citizen Petitioners and the Deregulatory Petitioners both dispute that

these articles support the Commission’s selection of five equal-sized competitors as the

appropriate benchmark. The Deregulatory Petitioners argue that the articles fall short

because they do not rule out market structures other than equal-sized competitors (such as

one large firm and many small ones) as equally competitive markets. This argument,

unanswered by the Commission, warrants a response because (as discussed below) the

record evidence supports neither actual nor potential existence of equal-sized competitors.

       The Citizen Petitioners argue that the three articles the Commission cites are

superseded and contradicted by the Department of Justice and Federal Trade

Commission’s most recent re-write of the Merger Guidelines, under which a market with

five equal-sized competitors is considered “highly concentrated.” See Merger Guidelines

§ 1.51(c) (a highly concentrated market has an HHI score higher than 1800). The

Commission’s decision to rely on theory that conflicts with the M erger Guidelines is


                                            117
suspect because, in the same Order, the Commission relied on the Merger Guidelines to

derive its new limits for local television station ownership. See Order ¶¶ 192–93. The

Commission did not address this discrepancy in its Respondent’s Brief, 77 and should do

so on remand.

               b.    The Commission did not sufficiently justified that the existing
                     numerical limits actually ensure that markets will have five
                     equal-sized competitors.

       Regardless whether five equal-sized competitors is the right benchmark for

competition, the Commission did not sufficiently justified that five equal-sized

competitors would emerge or actually have emerged under the numerical limits. It defies

logic to assume that a combination of top-ranked stations is the competitive equal to a

combination of low-ranked stations just because the two combinations have the same

number of stations. The Commission itself acknowledges that “radio station groups with

similar numbers of radio stations [can] have vastly different levels of market power.”

Order ¶ 290.

       Furthermore, evidence shows that the existing numerical limits do not ensure five

equal-sized competitors. According to the record, most markets are dominated by one or




  77
     The Commission argued instead that we should defer to its line-drawing discretion.
But in order to warrant judicial deference, an agency’s line-drawing decision must be
justified by a reasonable explanation and cannot run counter to the evidence before it.
Sinclair, 284 F.3d at 162
; see also 
NCCB, 436 U.S. at 814
–15. On this aspect of the
Order, the Commission’s decision is neither.

                                            118
two large station owners.78 And the top-four station owners together control the lion’s

share of the market. 79 Even if these four station-owners were “equal-sized” (they are not),

the HHI score of such a market would be 2500 (4 x (100 ÷ 4)2 ), well above the Merger

Guidelines’ 1800 threshold for highly concentrated markets.

       The Commission does not explain why it could not take actual market share into

account when deriving the numerical limits.80 Had it proffered the “market share is too

  78
     The Local Radio Market Concentration Study, submitted with comments of the UCC
to MM Docket No. 01-317 (Mar. 26, 2002), supports this conclusion. The UCC studied
33 local radio markets (using 2001 data from the BIA Financial Network) of various sizes
and reported each market’s four largest station owners’ local commercial share. In most,
the largest and second-largest station owners had market shares considerably higher than
the next largest owners. For example, in San Francisco the top two station owners
controlled, respectively, 26.8% and 20% of the local commercial share; the third- and
fourth-largest owners controlled 13.4% and 12.1%, respectively. In Atlanta, the largest
station owner had a 30.8% market share while the owners of the three next-largest
stations had between 9% and 17% each. Medium and small markets were also dominated
by one or two owners. The four largest station owners in Jacksonville, Florida owned
45.5% , 36.3% , 9.1%, and 2.5%. The four (only) station owners in Fargo, North Dakota
owned 50.8%, 40.2%, 7.0% , and 2.0% .
  79
     See 
id. In all
but one of the 11 of the 50 largest markets analyzed by the UCC, the
four largest firms controlled between 64 and 82% of the market share. In its 15 mid-sized
markets, four largest firms controlled between 86 and 100% of the market share. And in
the seven small markets it studied, the four largest firms controlled between 92 and 100%
of the market share.
  80
     The dissent suggests that this conclusion is undermined by two paragraphs in the
Order, ¶¶ 300–01, in which the Commission justified its decision not to reinstate an
audience share cap on mergers. But the flaw we find in the Commission’s analysis has
nothing to do with its conclusion that an audience share cap would discourage radio
stations from earning market share by investing in quality programming. Order ¶ 300.
Our concern is, rather, that the Commission sought to justify its numerical limits by
suggesting that they would allow a sufficient number of equal-sized competitors (five) to
allow for a competitive market, when in fact there is no evidence that the resulting
competitors would be anything approaching “equal-sized.”

                                            119
fluid” rationale, we have already rejected that explanation in the context of the local

television ownership rule and the Cross-Media Limits. We also note that the Commission

has in the past extolled the value of audience share data for measuring diversity and

competition in local radio markets.81 So the Commission’s reliance on the fiction of

equal-sized competitors, as opposed to measuring their actual competitive power, is even

more suspect in the context of the local radio rule.

       For these reasons, the Commission’s numerical limits cannot rationally be derived

from a “five equal-sized competitor” premise. We thus remand for the Commission to

develop numerical limits that are supported by a rational analysis.




  81
    In the context of its decision in its 1992 rulemaking to retain a 25% audience share
benchmark at which an acquisition will raise a prima facie concern that the transaction
will lead to undue local concentration, the Commission said:
        We recognize that there are some limitations to relying exclusively on
        market share data to weigh concentration in the local radio marketplace, as
        pointed out by petitioners. However, to the extent petitioners argue that
        ratings data are inherently unsuitable for purposes of analyzing local
        concentration, we disagree. We believe that audience share information will
        be useful in helping to measure diversity and competition. Specifically,
        audience share data can identify the most dominant stations in a market.
        And, compared to limits based solely on the number of stations involved,
        use of audience share is a means of accounting for the variety of types of
        stations—clear channel, regional, daytime, low and high power— that exist
        in various markets. Moreover, by continuing to consider this factor as part
        of our ownership limits, our rules may provide an incentive for stronger,
        successful stations to invest in other local stations with generally low
        audience shares—an outcome that is consistent with the purposes of this
        proceeding.
Revision of Radio Rules and Policies, 7 F.C.C.R. 6387, ¶ 47.

                                             120
              c.     The Commission did not support its decision to retain the
                     AM/FM subcaps.

       The Deregulatory Petitioners challenge the Commission’s decision to retain the

AM/FM subcaps, which the Commission justified on the grounds that FM stations have

technological and economic advantages over AM stations. Order ¶ 294. But the

Deregulatory Petitioners point out, and we agree, that this does not explain why it is

necessary to impose an AM subcap at all. The Commission does not respond in its brief

to this particular criticism. Thus it should do so, or modify its approach, on remand.

                                    VII.    Conclusion

       Though we affirm much of the Commission’s Order, we have identified several

provisions in which the Commission falls short of its obligation to justify its decisions to

retain, repeal, or modify its media ownership regulations with reasoned analysis. The

Commission’s derivation of new Cross-Media Limits, and its modification of the

numerical limits on both television and radio station ownership in local markets, all have

the same essential flaw: an unjustified assumption that media outlets of the same type

make an equal contribution to diversity and competition in local markets. We thus

remand for the Commission to justify or modify its approach to setting numerical limits.

We also remand for the Commission to reconsider or better explain its decision to repeal

the FSSR.82 The stay currently in effect will continue pending our review of the


  82
     On remand the Commission should also consider MMTC’s proposals for enhancing
ownership opportunities for women and minorities, which the Commission had deferred
for future consideration.

                                             121
Commission’s action on remand, over which this panel retains jurisdiction.




SCIRICA, Chief Judge, dissenting in part, concurring in part.

       Although I concur in some parts of the Court’s comprehensive analysis of this

complex agency order, including its rejection of the constitutional challenges, I

respectfully dissent from its decision to vacate and remand. In my view, the Court’s

decision has upended the usual way the judiciary reviews agency rulemaking. Whether

the standard is “arbitrary or capricious,” “reasonableness,” or some variant of a

“deregulatory presumption,” the Court has applied a threshold that supplants the well-

known principles of deference accorded to agency decision-making. In so doing, the

Court has substituted its own policy judgment for that of the Federal Communications

Commission and upset the ongoing review of broadcast media regulation mandated by

Congress in the Telecommunications Act of 1996.

       I would lift the stay and allow the Commission’s media ownership rules to go into

effect. It is not the role of the judiciary to second-guess the reasoned policy judgments of

an administrative agency acting within the scope of its delegated authority. Allowing the

biennial (now quadrennial) review process to run its course will give the Commission and

Congress the opportunity to monitor and evaluate the effect of the proposed rules on the

media marketplace. More importantly, it will ensure that accountability for these crucial


                                            122
policy decisions rests with the political branches of our government.

                                      I. Introduction

       In 1934, Congress delegated broad authority to the Federal Communication

Commission to regulate “interstate and foreign commerce in communication by wire and

radio,” and to grant station broadcast licenses that served “public convenience, interest,

and necessity.” Communications Act of 1934, 47 U.S.C. §§ 151, 309(a). This statutory

authority to regulate broadcast media is girded by an obligation “to preserve an

uninhibited marketplace of ideas in which truth will ultimately prevail.” Red Lion Broad.

Co. v. FCC, 
395 U.S. 367
, 390 (1969). The FCC’s delegated responsibility to foster a

robust forum for national debate is unique in administrative law and essential to the

vibrancy of our deliberative democracy. See Buckley v. Valeo, 
424 U.S. 1
, 49 (1976)

(“Democracy depends on a well-informed electorate.”).

       Preserving the “marketplace of ideas” does not easily lend itself to mathematical

certitude. While other independent federal agencies may act with greater measurable

precision in reducing pollution emissions, defining safety standards or even establishing

interest rates, the FCC operates in the less scientific arena of speech and debate.83 In this

realm, the Commission’s mandate to maintain viewpoint diversity in the national




  83
    See Abrams v. United States, 
250 U.S. 616
, 630 (1919) (Holmes, J., dissenting)
(describing the theory of free speech as “an experiment, as all of life is an experiment”).

                                             123
broadcast media is complicated both by the “elusive” concept of diversity,84 and by the

inherent uncertainty regarding the prospective effects of structural rules.85 Even the direct

regulation of specific broadcast content—e.g., content guidelines for news and public

affairs programming—does not necessarily assure viewpoint diversity will be achieved.

       The Commission’s duty to regulate broadcast media in the public interest is further

complicated by the unpredictable impact of emerging technologies on the media

marketplace. When the Commission was first formed, AM or “standard” radio was the

only broadcast medium of practical concern. See 2002 Biennial Regulatory Review –

Review of the Commission’s Broadcast Ownership Rules and Other Rules Adopted

Pursuant to Section 202 of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 18 F.C.C.R. 13,620,

13,649-651 ¶¶ 90-94 (2003) (“Order”) (detailing history of the modern media

marketplace). Today, the modern media marketplace includes literally thousands of radio

and broadcast television stations, hundreds of national, regional and local non-broadcast

television networks delivering a vast range of content over cable and direct broadcast

satellite systems, and perhaps most significantly, the Internet and a host of digital

technology-enabled interactive services. 
Id. ¶¶ 95-128.
In designing media ownership




  84
    FCC v. Nat’l Citizens Comm. for Broad., 
436 U.S. 775
, 796-97 (1978) (“NCCB”)
(“[Diversity] and its effects are . . . elusive concepts, not easily defined let alone
measured without making qualitative judgments objectionable on both policy and First
Amendment grounds.”) (citation omitted).
  85
   FCC v. RCA Communications, Inc., 
346 U.S. 86
, 96 (1953) (“the possible benefits of
competition do not lend themselves to detailed forecast”).

                                             124
rules for this dynamic technological landscape, the Commission must balance the

potentially negative effects of license ownership concentration on programming diversity

against the economic viability of new or struggling media outlets.

       Over the past seventy years, the Commission has actively adjusted its license

ownership rules on an ongoing basis to foster the growth of new media outlets while

maintaining a focus on programming diversity. For much of its early history, the

Commission operated with the assumption that diversification of ownership best served

the public interest in promoting programming diversity.86 For example, in 1938 the

Commission denied Genesee Radio Corporation’s application for a second AM station

license after concluding it was “not in the public interest to grant the facilities for an

additional broadcast station to interests already in control of the operation of a station of

the same class and in the same community.” Genesee Radio Corp., 5 F.C.C. 183, 186

(1938). For the next forty years, media regulation continued primarily “on the theory that

diversification of mass media ownership serves the public interest by promoting diversity

of program and service viewpoints, as well as by preventing undue concentration of

economic power.” 87 
NCCB, 436 U.S. at 780
.


  86
   See generally Bruce M . Owen, Regulatory Reform: The Telecommunications Act of
1996 and the FCC Media Ownership Rules, 2003 M ich. St. DCL L. Rev. 671 (Fall 2003).
  87
   See, e.g., Rules Governing Standard and High Frequency Broadcast Stations, 5 Fed.
Reg. 2382, 2384 (June 26, 1940) (FM radio); Rules Governing Standard and High
Frequency Broadcast Stations, 6 Fed. Reg. 2282, 2284-85 (M ay 6,1941) (television);
Amendment of Sections 73.35, 73.240, and 73.636 of the Commission’s Rules Relating to
Multiple Ownership of Standard, FM and Television Broadcast Stations, 22 F.C.C.2d

                                              125
      The Commission has departed from this baseline presumption when strict

adherence to a policy of ownership diversity threatened to drive some media outlets from

the market. For example, in the early 1970s, the Commission relaxed its “one-to-a-

market” rule to permit co-ownership of AM and FM licenses in the same market after

observing that most AM-FM combinations were “economically and/or technically

interdependent,” and that most free-standing FM stations were not economically viable

without a co-owned AM license revenue. See Amendment of Sections 73.35, 73.240 and

73.636 of the Commission’s Rules Relating to Multiple Ownership Rules of Standard, FM

and Television Broadcast Stations, 28 F.C.C.2d 662, 671 ¶ 33 (1971). The Commission

similarly permitted UHF-radio combinations on a case-by-case basis to encourage the

development of the UHF broadcasting medium. 
Id. at 674.
Likewise, in repealing

national ownership caps for television and radio, the FCC concluded the potential

economic efficiency gains from “group ownership actually further[], rather than

frustrate[], the foremost First Amendment goal of augmenting popular discussion of

important public issues.” Amendment of Section 73.3555 of the Commission’s Rules

Relating to Multiple Ownership of AM, FM, and Television Broadcast Stations, 100

F.C.C.2d 17, 20 (1984).



306, 307-08 ¶¶ 5-8 (1970) (proscribing common ownership of more than one full-time
broadcast station (radio or TV); Amendment of Sections 73.34, 73.240, and 73.636 of the
Commission’s Rules Relating to Multiple Ownership of Standard FM, and Television
Broadcast Stations, 50 F.C.C.2d 1046 (1975), amended on reconsideration, 53 F.C.C.2d
589 (1975) (prohibiting broadcast licensees from owning or controlling newspapers in the
same geographic markets).

                                           126
       The dynamic evolution of the media ownership rules—with the Commission

intermittently encouraging and discouraging economic concentration—demonstrates the

virtual impossibility of drafting a single, static regulatory structure that consistently

serves the public interest for an extended time period. The Commission’s statutory

mandate to regulate broadcast media “in the public convenience, interest, and necessity”

has been interpreted to require this sort of iterative, if imprecise, rulemaking. Nat’l

Broad. Co. v. United States, 
319 U.S. 190
, 225 (1943) (“If time and changing

circumstances reveal that the ‘public interest’ is not served by application of the

Regulations, it must be assumed that the Commission will act in accordance with its

statutory obligations.”).

       The Telecommunications Act of 1996, Pub. L. No. 104-104, 110 Stat. 56, codified

this ongoing review process by requiring the Commission to conduct a biennial review of

its media ownership rules and “repeal or modify” any rule that no longer serves the public

interest. 
Id. at §
202(h), 110 Stat. at 111-112.88 On the cusp of an unprecedented

revolution in communication technologies, Congress set in motion this statutorily-

prescribed process of media deregulation based on the conviction that increased

competition in the media marketplace would best serve the public interest.89 The


  88
    In the Consolidated Appropriations Act of 2004, Pub. L. 108-199, § 629, 118 Stat. 3,
100 (2004), Congress replaced the biennial review with a quadrennial review.
  89
    See H.R. Conf. Rep. No. 104-458, at 113 (1996) (defining purpose of the Act “to
provide for a pro-competitive, de-regulatory national policy framework designed to
accelerate rapidly private sector deployment of advanced telecommunications and

                                              127
significance of the mandatory review mechanism should not be ignored. This particular

set of ownership rules—like any of those passed by the Commission—is not cast in iron.

No single set of proposed rules can perfectly capture the dynamic nature of the media

marketplace. These rules serve as an important point of reference in an ongoing review

process. Nevertheless, the latest rules represent a reasoned step towards the pro-

competitive, de-regulatory media ownership framework contemplated by Congress.90

       Short-circuiting the statutory review process deprives both the Commission and

Congress the valuable opportunity to evaluate the new rules and the effects of

deregulation on the media marketplace. Under the original implementation schedule, the

Commission already would have initiated its assessment of the proposed rules in

preparation for the 2004 Biennial Review. See Telecommunications Act of 1996 §

202(h). Vacating and remanding the proposed rules to the Commission will preserve the

existing rules in place for months or even years,91 and the resulting delay will likely leave


information technologies to all Americans by opening all telecommunications markets to
competition”).
  90
    See Michael I. Meyerson, Ideas of the Marketplace: A Guide to the 1996
Telecommunications Act, 49 Fed. Comm. L.J. 251, 253 (1997) (“The 1996 Act is an
experiment, as, one would have to admit, all telecommunication regulation is an
experiment.”).
  91
    The Notice of Proposed Rulemaking process (“NPRM ”) typically consumes several
months. See, e.g., Rules and Policies Concerning Multiple Ownership of Radio
Broadcast Stations in Local Markets, Definition of Radio Markets, 16 F.C.C.R. 19,861
(2001) (allowing 90-days from publication of notice for comment and reply); Cross-
Ownership of Broadcast Stations and Newspapers, Newspaper/Radio Cross-Ownership
Waiver Policy, Order and Notice of Proposed Rule Making, 16 F.C.C.R. 17,283 (2001)
(issuing notice of proposed rulemaking on September 20, 2001, and requiring comment

                                             128
the public worse off than if these rules were allowed to take effect.92

       Given the dynamic nature of the industry, the task of crafting a regulatory structure

that reflects the realities of the media marketplace requires the Commission to make

predictive judgments about the future. Courts have consistently recognized the

Commission’s authority and unique expertise in making such estimations. See Cellco

P’ship v. FCC, 
357 F.3d 88
, 98 (D.C. Cir. 2004) (“Nothing . . . suggest[s] that under §

11's biennial review mandate the Commission could no longer rely on its predictive

judgment or properly-supported inferences in determining to retain a regulation.”).

Courts also have correctly acknowledged it is virtually impossible for an agency to

compile an unchallengeable factual record in support of forward-looking rules designed




and reply by January 7, 2002). Thereafter, the Commission requires additional time to
thoroughly review and evaluate the public commentary gathered through the NPRM.
Here, the Commission initiated a comprehensive NPRM on the proposed media
ownership rules—which incorporated commentary from previous rulemaking proceedings
on the local radio and newspaper/broadcast cross-ownership rules—on September 23,
2002. See 2002 Biennial Regulatory Review--Review of the Commission’s Broadcast
Ownership Rules and Other Rules Adopted Pursuant to Section 202 of the
Telecommunications Act of 1996; Cross-Ownership of Broadcast Stations and
Newspapers; Rules and Policies Concerning Multiple Ownership of Radio Broadcast
Stations in Local Markets; Definition of Radio Markets (“Notice”), 17 F.C.C.R. 18,503
(2002). The Commission did not issue its final order on the proposed media ownership
rules until July 2, 2003, some ten months after initiation of the notice and comment
process.
  92
    The Commission has already been chastised for holding up the process of
deregulation so clearly mandated by Congress. See Fox Television Stations, Inc. v. FCC,
280 F.3d 1027
, 1042 (D.C. Cir. 2002) (“Fox I”) (“The Commission’s wait-and-see
approach cannot be squared with its statutory mandate promptly . . . to ‘repeal or modify’
any rule that is not ‘necessary in the public interest.’”).

                                             129
to anticipate the future development of the marketplace. As the Supreme Court noted,

“[i]n such circumstances complete factual support in the record for the Commission’s

judgment or prediction is not possible or required; ‘a forecast of the direction in which

future public interest lies necessarily involves deductions based on the expert knowledge

of the agency.’” 
NCCB, 436 U.S. at 814
(quoting FPC v. Transcontinental Gas Pipe Line

Corp., 
365 U.S. 1
, 29 (1961)).

       Foremost among the future developments facing the Commission is the explosive

growth of the Internet as a media source. The unique qualities of the Internet provide an

unimaginable breadth of accessible information as well as a forum for individual

expression. The Supreme Court recognized the unique nature of this media source when

it wrote:

       The Internet . . . offer[s] a forum for a true diversity of political discourse,
       unique opportunities for cultural development, and myriad avenues for
       intellectual activity.” 47 U.S.C. § 230 (a)(3) (1994 ed., Supp. V). While
       “surfing” the World Wide Web, the primary method of remote information
       retrieval on the Internet today, individuals can access material about topics
       ranging from aardvarks to Zoroastrianism. One can use the Web to read
       thousands of newspapers published around the globe, purchase tickets for a
       matinee at the neighborhood movie theater, or follow the progress of any
       Major League Baseball team on a pitch-by-pitch basis.

Ashcroft v. ACLU, 
535 U.S. 564
, 566 (2002) (citations omitted).

       By requiring the Commission to craft a set of media ownership rules that perfectly

account for the effects of concentration, economic efficiency, diversity and future

technological progress, the majority constructs a high bar and impedes the review process

established by Congress. Instead of asking the Commission to start from zero, the

                                             130
prudent step would be to allow these reasoned rules to go into effect, monitor the

resulting impact on the media marketplace, and allow the Commission to refine or modify

its approach in its next quadrennial review. In the interim, if the Commission goes too

far or ignores the scope of its statutory mandate, Congress itself may act, as it already has

with respect to the national television ownership rules, see Consolidated Appropriations

Act of 2004, 118 Stat. 3, to modify or repeal any rule it deems to be no longer in the

public interest.

       There are, of course, alternative approaches the Commission might have taken in

crafting the proposed media ownership rules. But the Commission acted within its

delegated authority by adopting a set of rules which it properly determined would serve

the public interest. Our review of those rules is necessarily cabined within our traditional

constitutional role. The courts “must guard against the danger of sliding unconsciously

from the narrow confines of law into the more spacious domain of policy.” Phelps Dodge

Corp. v. NLRB, 
313 U.S. 177
, 194 (1941). Whether or not we agree with this particular

set of rules, it is not our role to overturn the Commission’s reasoned policy judgments.

See Chevron, U.S.A., Inc. v. Natural Res. Def. Council, 
467 U.S. 837
, 866 (1984) (“The

responsibilities for assessing the wisdom of such policy choices and resolving the struggle

between competing views of the public interest are not judicial ones: ‘Our Constitution

vests such responsibilities in the political branches.’”) (quoting TVA v. Hill, 
437 U.S. 153
,

195 (1978)). Questions of media diversity and ownership command strongly divergent

views. But those questions should be answered by officials within our legislative and

                                             131
executive branches of government.

                                 II. Standard of Review

       This is an appeal of an agency decision under the Communications Act of 1934, 47

U.S.C. § 151 et seq. This Court’s jurisdiction is based on 47 U.S.C. § 402(a), and 28

U.S.C. § 2342(1). Although there are some similarities, I differ from the majority on the

applicable standard of review. Moreover, I believe the majority’s subsequent analysis

oversteps the appropriate standard. In doing so, the majority substitutes its own judgment

for policy decisions meant to be resolved by the Agency.

                                             A.

       As noted, Petitioners bring a litany of challenges to the Commission’s Order.

Different standards of review apply to the various challenges. In reviewing a contention

that an agency rule is arbitrary and capricious, our standard of review is governed first by

the Administrative Procedure Act, 5 U.S.C. § 706. Under the APA, this Court is

instructed to “hold unlawful and set aside agency action, findings, and conclusions” that

are found to be “arbitrary, capricious, an abuse of discretion, or otherwise not in

accordance with law.” § 706(2)(A); New Jersey Coal. for Fair Broad. v. FCC, 
574 F.2d 1119
, 1125 (3d Cir. 1978).

       The scope of review under the “arbitrary and capricious” standard is “narrow, and

a court is not to substitute its judgment for that of the agency.” Motor Vehicle Mfrs.

Ass’n v. State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co., 
463 U.S. 29
, 43 (1983). Nevertheless, in

reaching its decision, the agency must examine the relevant data and articulate a

                                             132
satisfactory explanation for its action including a “rational connection between the facts

found and the choice made.” 
Id. (quoting Burlington
Truck Lines, Inc. v. United States,

371 U.S. 156
, 168 (1962)). Normally, an agency rule is arbitrary and capricious where:

       the agency has relied on factors which Congress has not intended it to
       consider, entirely failed to consider an important aspect of the problem,
       offered an explanation for its decision that runs counter to the evidence
       before the agency, or is so implausible that it could not be ascribed to a
       difference in view or the product of agency expertise. The reviewing court
       should not attempt itself to make up for such deficiencies; we may not
       supply a reasoned basis for the agency’s action that the agency itself has not
       given.

Id.; see also Robert Wood Johnson Univ. Hosp. v. Thompson, 
297 F.3d 273
, 280 (3d Cir.

2002). W e will, however, “uphold a decision of less than ideal clarity if the agency’s

path may reasonably be discerned.” Motor Vehicle M frs. 
Ass’n, 463 U.S. at 43
(quoting

Bowman Transp., Inc. v. Arkansas-Best Freight Sys., Inc., 
419 U.S. 281
, 286 (1974)).

       The scope of our review is necessarily influenced by the authority allocated to the

FCC in its enabling act. The 1934 Act grants “broad discretion” to the Commission to

allocate broadcast licenses in the “public interest, convenience and necessity.” FCC v.

WNCN Listeners’ Guild, 
450 U.S. 582
, 594 (1981). The Act’s public interest standard is

a “supple instrument for the exercise of discretion by the expert body which Congress has

charged to carry out its legislative policy.” 
Id. at 593
(quoting FCC v. Pottsville Broad.

Co., 
309 U.S. 134
, 138 (1940)). The Commission’s broad authority suggests that “the

Commission’s judgment regarding how the public interest is best served is entitled to

substantial judicial deference,” and “is not to be set aside” as long as its implementation


                                            133
of the public interest standard is “based on a rational weighing of competing policies.”

Id. at 596.
       Finally, the standard of review is even more deferential “where the issues involve

‘elusive’ and ‘not easily defined’ areas such as programming diversity in broadcasting.”

Sinclair Broad. Group v. FCC, 
284 F.3d 148
, 159 (D.C. Cir. 2002). Because many

aspects of this administrative order involve policy determinations on such elusive goals, a

“rationality” standard is often appropriate. See 
NCCB, 436 U.S. at 796
-97 (finding the

Commission acted rationally in determining diversification of ownership would enhance

the likelihood of achieving diversity of viewpoints). Additionally, where issues involve

line-drawing determinations, our review is necessarily deferential to agency expertise, see

AT&T Corp. v. FCC, 
220 F.3d 607
, 627 (D.C. Cir. 2000), so long as these decisions do

not run counter to the evidence before the agency. 
Sinclair, 284 F.3d at 162
.

                                             B.

       Several Deregulatory Petitioners challenge the Order as violating § 202(h) of the

1996 Act. This section reads:

       The Commission shall review its rules adopted pursuant to this section and
       all of its ownership rules biennially as part of its regulatory reform review
       under section 11 of the Communications Act of 1934 and shall determine
       whether any of such rules are necessary in the public interest as the result of
       competition. The Commission shall repeal or modify any regulation it
       determines to be no longer in the public interest.

Because the Order was promulgated as part of the biennial review required by this

section, our review is necessarily informed by Congress’ direction in the statute that in


                                            134
addition to reviewing its ownership rules biennially to “determine whether any of such

rules are necessary in the public interest as the result of competition[,] [t]he Commission

shall repeal or modify any regulation it determines to be no longer in the public interest.”

§ 202(h).

       This statutory language has been interpreted to correspond with the deregulatory

process codified in the 1996 Act. See Fox 
I, 280 F.3d at 1033
(noting that in § 202(h)

Congress instructed the Commission to “continue the process of deregulation”); 
Sinclair, 284 F.3d at 159
(“This sentence appears as the last sentence of Congress’s instruction that

the review of each of its ownership rules every two years ‘which the court characterized

as designed to continue the process of deregulation.’”) (quoting Fox 
I, 280 F.3d at 1033
).

       The FCC recognized its heightened burden for maintaining regulations in its

Order, noting that “Section 202(h) appears to upend the traditional administrative law

principle requiring an affirmative justification for the modification or elimination of a

rule.” 93 Order ¶ 11. The FCC further recognized the direction from Fox and Sinclair that


  93
     The D.C. Circuit’s amendment of Fox I in Fox Television Stations v. FCC, 
293 F.3d 537
(D.C. Cir. 2002) (“Fox II”), does not negate the deregulatory flavor of § 202(h).
        In Fox I, the D.C. Circuit declared that section 202(h) “is clear that a regulation
should be retained only insofar as it is necessary in, not merely consonant with, the public
interest.” 280 F.3d at 1050
. This language was subsequently modified upon petition by
the FCC. Fox II, 
293 F.3d 537
. The FCC’s petition was denied with regard to
interpretation of the word “necessary,” however. 
Id. at 540.
Instead, the court held that
its earlier decision “did not turn at all upon interpreting ‘necessary in the public interest’
to mean more than ‘in the public interest.’” 
Id. Nonetheless, the
court noted that,
because the issue was not fully briefed, the meaning of “necessary in the public interest”
should be left open. 
Id. The paragraph
interpreting “necessary in the public interest” in
Fox 
I, 280 F.3d at 1050
, was rewritten to read:

                                             135
“Section 202 carries with it a presumption in favor of repealing or modifying the

ownership rules.” Order ¶ 11; 
Fox, 280 F.3d at 1048
; 
Sinclair, 284 F.3d at 159
.94 The

FCC must demonstrate that retention of the rules remains in the public interest. See 
Fox, 280 F.3d at 1044
(faulting the Commission for providing no analysis of the state of the

television broadcast market in maintaining the National Television Ownership Rule). As

noted at the outset, this requirement does not preclude the FCC from relying on predictive

judgments and expertise in crafting its rules. See 
id. at 1051
(noting that the “court

should ordinarily defer to the Commission’s predictive judgments”). The Commission’s

authority to rely on predictive judgments and empirical assumptions was recently

affirmed by the Court of Appeals for the D.C. Circuit. See Am. Family Ass’n, Inc. v.

FCC, Nos. 00-1310, 
2004 U.S. App. LEXIS 9150
, *23 (D.C. Cir. May 11, 2004) (noting

“necessarily wide latitude to make policy based on predictive judgments deriving from



      Next, Time Warner argues that the Commission applied too lenient a standard
      when it concluded only that the CBCO Rule “continues to serve the public
      interest,” . . . and not that it was “necessary” in the public interest. Again the
      Commission is silent, but nonetheless we do not reach the merits of Time W arner’s
      argument. This important question was barely raised by the petitioners and was
      not addressed at all by the Commission or the intervenors. Even if “necessary in
      the public interest” means simply, “continues to serve the public interest,” for all
      the reasons given above and below, the Commission’s decision not to repeal or to
      modify the NTSO and the CBCO Rules cannot 
stand. 293 F.3d at 541
. This language, leaving open the meaning of “necessary in the public
interest,” does not alter the effect of § 202(h) on our standard of review.
  94
    The majority found the Commission’s interpretation of § 202(h) misguided. I believe
the Commission adequately articulated the standard in its Order. I do not find the
Commission’s statements about its burden under §202(h) to significantly alter the
standard of review expressed in this section.

                                            136
[the Commission’s] general expertise”).

       At issue on the § 202(h) standard of review is whether and to what extent the

presumption to repeal or modify ownership rules turns on the definition of the term

“necessary.” The FCC interpreted “necessary” in § 202(h) to mean “useful,”

“convenient” or “appropriate” rather than “required” or “indispensable.” 18 F.C.C.R.

4726, 4730-36 (March 14, 2003); Order ¶ 11 n.15 (citing same). The FCC’s

interpretation of “necessary” is correct. 95 The term “necessary” in statutes has been found

repeatedly to mean “useful” or “appropriate” rather than “indispensable.” 18 F.C.C.R. at

4731 n.24 (citing, inter alia, Morgan v. Commonwealth of Va., 
328 U.S. 373
, 377-78

(1946)); see also 
Cellco, 357 F.3d at 99
.

       The FCC’s interpretation of “necessary” does not neutralize the deregulatory

flavor of the 1996 Act. Under the FCC’s interpretation, a regulation must be useful

(albeit not indispensable) in promoting the public interest in order to survive the

biennial—now quadrennial—review process. The “presumption,” therefore, is that a

regulation will be vacated or modified if it does not continue to be in the public interest.

This is different from the traditional approach to rule retention, which would counsel for



  95
    Courts have recognized that Chevron standards apply to judicial review of the
Commission’s interpretation of the Communications Act. See 
Cellco, 357 F.3d at 94
.
Under the familiar instruction of Chevron, an agency’s construction of the statute it
administers will be upheld unless it contradicts an explicit congressional directive or
otherwise is an impermissible interpretation of the statute. 
Chevron, 467 U.S. at 844
.
The Commission’s interpretation is clearly permissible. Nonetheless, even without
Chevron deference, the FCC properly interpreted the statute.

                                             137
retention of a rule unless there were reasons to change it. In this sense, Congress’

mandate and the FCC’s approach is “deregulatory” because it would repeal or modify

rules no longer found to be in the public interest.

       The FCC looked to the structure of the 1996 Act in reaching its interpretation. The

FCC recognized that “necessary” appears in other sections of the Communications Act

that discuss the FCC’s rulemaking powers, and in those contexts “necessary” has taken on

the “useful” meaning. See, e.g., 47 U.S.C. § 201(b). Holding the review process to a

more stringent standard would lead to the absurd result of the FCC issuing a rule as

merely useful, but then having to revoke it at the next review because it is not

indispensable. Furthermore, if the rulemaking and review definitions of “necessary” were

different, the FCC could simply sidestep the more stringent review standard by repealing

and then reissuing any useful rules that were not indispensable.

       The rulemaking provisions are permissive, while the biennial review is mandatory.

Compare, e.g., 
id. (Commission “may
prescribe such rules and regulations as may be

necessary in the public interest”) with § 202(h) (“The Commission shall review its rules .

. . biennially . . . and shall determine whether any of such rules are necessary in the public

interest as the result of competition. The Commission shall repeal or modify any

regulation it determines to be no longer in the public interest.”) (emphasis added). That

the FCC is permitted to make rules but required to review them, however, does not shed

light on the meaning of the term “necessary.” The mandatory nature of the review is not

undermined by the “useful” interpretation. The FCC must repeal or modify a rule that is

                                             138
no longer useful in promoting the public interest.

       Recently in Cellco, 
357 F.3d 88
, the D.C. Circuit upheld the Agency’s

interpretation of “necessary” in a similar review provision of the 1996 Act.96 The FCC’s

“useful” interpretation of the statutory language is a reasonable one, and should be

upheld.97

       The 1996 Act’s legislative history bolsters the FCC’s interpretation. Section

202(h) falls within the ambit of a larger review provision, Section 11 in the 1996 Act.

The conference report regarding Section 11, H.R. Conf. Rep. No. 104-458, at 185 (1996),

interprets “no longer in the public interest” as “no longer meaningful.” This phrase, of

course, is essentially synonymous with the phrase “no longer useful” or “no longer




  96
    Cellco restricted any discussion in Fox and Sinclair of a presumption to repeal or
modify rules under § 202(h) to those cases’ discussions of remedies. See 
Cellco, 357 F.3d at 98
. I do not believe the deregulatory thrust of § 202(h) can be so easily
eviscerated.
  97
     “Necessary” has been found to mean more than merely “useful” or “appropriate” by
other courts reviewing the 1996 Act, but these cases all dealt with other discrete portions
of the statute. See Cellular Telecomm. & Internet Ass’n v. FCC, 
330 F.3d 502
(D.C. Cir.
2003) (dealing with § 10(a) of the 1934 Act); GTE Serv. Corp. v. FCC, 
205 F.3d 416
(D.C. Cir. 2000) (dealing with 47 U.S.C. § 251); AT&T Corp. v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 
525 U.S. 366
(1999) (same). Moreover, the Cellular Telecommunications court explicitly rejected
the “indispensable” interpretation of “necessary” as required by the statute, instead giving
Chevron deference to the FCC’s interpretation that “necessary” in § 10(a) means
“referring to the existence of a strong connection between what the agency has done by
way of regulation and what the agency permissibly sought to achieve.” Cellular
Telecomm., 330 F.3d at 509-12
(discussing GTE, 
205 F.3d 416
; Iowa Util. Bd., 
525 U.S. 366
). Most recently in Cellco, 
357 F.3d 88
, the D.C. Circuit upheld the Agency’s
“useful” interpretation of “necessary” in a similar review provision of the 1996 Act. 
Id. at 99.
                                            139
appropriate,” and much less exacting than “no longer indispensable.” Thus, the

Conference Report’s definition of “no longer in the public interest” supports the FCC’s

interpretation of “necessary.”

       Despite § 202(h)’s admittedly deregulatory tenor, the statute does not foreclose the

possibility of increased regulation under the biennial review if the Commission finds such

action in the public interest. Nothing in the 1996 Act overcomes the broad rulemaking

authority of the FCC. See 47 U.S.C. § 303(r). Any limitation must be clearly stated by

Congress. See, e.g., Am. Hosp. Ass’n v. NLRB, 
499 U.S. 606
, 613 (1991) (stating that “if

Congress had intended to curtail in a particular area the broad rulemaking authority [it

has] granted . . . we would have suspected it to do so in language expressly describing an

exception [to the authority]”). 98

        Finally, though the Order must be consistent with the remand directives from Fox

and Sinclair, and those reasoned decisions are instructive, they are not the law of the case

in the current appeal. This case involves petitions for review of the FCC’s

comprehensive reexamination of a larger set of its broadcast ownership rules, in which a

different set of parties participated, a different record was compiled, and a different result

reached. See, e.g., Hamilton v. Leavy, 
322 F.3d 776
, 786 (3d Cir. 2003) (Law of the case




  98
   On this point, I do not find the 1996 Act provided a highwater mark for regulation,
beyond which the FCC could not regulate.

                                             140
doctrine applies only to the “same litigation.”).99

        But Sinclair is instructive for another reason relating to the proper application of

our standard of review. In Sinclair, the D.C. Circuit found the Commission failed to

demonstrate its exclusion of non-broadcast media from its definition of “voices” in its

local television ownership rule was not arbitrary and 
capricious. 284 F.3d at 165
. The

Commission’s failure in the order at issue in Sinclair is notably different in both kind and

degree from the purported “flaws” the majority believes require vacating the FCC’s Order

here.

        In sum, the standard of review is governed foremost by the APA’s requirement

that the FCC’s rules not be arbitrary and capricious. Beyond this, we bear in mind the

requisite flexibility afforded the Commission’s rulemaking under the 1934 Act, and the

particular deference granted to the Commission’s decisions on diversity and other

difficult to define goals. Finally, § 202(h) overlays a deregulatory tenor on our review.

While I would not term this standard a “deregulatory presumption,” the FCC is required

to demonstrate that its rules remain useful in the public interest.

           III. Rules at Issue in this Appeal and Agency Rationale for Rules

        The majority partially vacates and remands the Order for the Commission to re-

evaluate certain purported flaws. With regard to the Diversity Index, the majority finds

the weight assigned to the Internet, as well as the assumption of equal shares for outlets


  99
    As noted in the denial of the motion to transfer, “we find this case separable and
independent from Fox and Sinclair . . . .” Denial of Motion to Transfer, at 5.

                                              141
within the same media type lacks record support. The majority also finds the

Commission inconsistently derived its Cross Media Limits from the Diversity Index

results. In regard to the local ownership rules, the majority finds the television and radio

rules’ reference to a particular market structure—one with equal-sized firms—as the

Commission’s underpinning for adopting specific ownership limits, is not supported by

the record. In my view, none of these purported flaws reach the level of arbitrary and

capricious decision-making or violate § 202(h). 100

            The majority’s conclusions cannot be evaluated without examining the

underlying rules and the FCC’s rationale for the changes. The evolution of the

challenged rules puts the Agency’s mammoth task in perspective. This includes

discussion of the FCC’s goals and objectives in its biennial review. In my view, the

Agency rationale supports the rule changes and demonstrates that the Commission’s

decisions were neither arbitrary nor capricious.

A.         Policy Goals and Media Landscape

           In accordance with its 2002 biennial review obligations, the Commission initiated

a comprehensive review of six media ownership rules. Order ¶ 1. As part of its 2002

Biennial Review, the Agency sought comment on four broadcast ownership rules: the



     100
     The majority also vacates and remands the Commission’s decision to repeal the
Failed Station Solicitation Rule, as well as its decision to retain an AM sub-cap in the
Local Radio Ownership Rule. Finally, the majority instructs the Commission to provide
specific notice of the Diversity Index in its rulemaking after remand. I find none of these
purported flaws to be arbitrary or capricious or violate § 202(h).

                                               142
Local Television Multiple Ownership Rule on remand from Sinclair; the Radio-

Television Cross-Ownership Rule; the National Television Multiple Ownership Rule on

remand from Fox;101 and the Dual Network Rule. 2002 Biennial Regulatory Review, 17

F.C.C.R. 18,503 (2002). The FCC also incorporated pending proceedings on local radio

ownership, Rules and Policies Concerning Multiple Ownership of Radio Broadcast

Stations in Local Markets; Definition of Radio Markets, 16 F.C.C.R. 19,861 (2001),

Definition of Radio Markets, 15 F.C.C.R. 25,077 (2000), and proceedings on

newspaper/broadcast cross-ownership. Cross-Ownership of Broadcast Stations and

Newspapers, 16 F.C.C.R. 17,283 (2001).

        The Order at issue here commenced with a notice of proposed rulemaking released

in September 2002. 17 F.C.C.R. 18,503 (2002) (“NPRM”). To help guide its analysis,

the Commission established a Media Ownership Working Group (“MOWG”), which

commissioned twelve studies ranging from consumer surveys to economic analyses of

media markets. Interested parties filed thousands of pages of comments, consisting of

legal, social, and economic analyses, empirical and anecdotal evidence, and industry and

consumer data to support their positions.

        The result was a 256-page order in which the Commission analyzed the record and


  101
     As the majority noted, our review of this rule is precluded by the Consolidated
Appropriations Act, 2004, Pub. L. No. 108-199, § 629, 118 Stat. 3, 99 (2004). For
reasons discussed in the majority opinion, I agree this statutory directive renders
challenges to the Commission’s decision to maintain the UHF discount moot. I also agree
the Commission is not estopped from revisiting the UHF discount in rulemaking outside
the § 202(h) context.

                                            143
determined, by a three-to-two vote, to modify its ownership rules to provide a “new,

comprehensive framework for broadcast ownership regulation.” Order ¶ 3. The FCC

adopted the Order on June 2, 2003, and released it a month later, on July 2, 2003. A

summary of the Order was published in the Federal Register on August 5, 2003. 68 Fed.

Reg. 46,286 (Aug. 5, 2003).

       1.     Policy Goals of the Present Order

       In its Order, the Commission identified three longstanding policy goals that would

continue to guide its ownership rules: diversity, competition, and localism. The

Commission found five types of diversity relevant to ownership policy: viewpoint

diversity, program diversity, outlet diversity, source diversity, and minority and female

ownership diversity. Order ¶ 18.

       Viewpoint diversity applies to the availability of media content reflecting a variety

of perspectives. 
Id. ¶ 19.
This goal endeavors to ensure a robust marketplace of ideas.

The Commission adhered to its “longstanding determination that the policy of limiting

common ownership of multiple media outlets is the most reliable means of promoting

viewpoint diversity.” 
Id. ¶ 26.
       Programming diversity refers to a variety of programming formats and content. 
Id. ¶ 36.
The Commission found that programming diversity was generally best acheived by

reliance on competition between delivery systems. 
Id. ¶ 37.
According to the

Commission, outlet diversity means that in a given market there are multiple

independently owned firms. 
Id. ¶ 38.
The Commission found that regulating the

                                            144
ownership of outlets to achieve outlet diversity was preferable to attempting to engineer

outcomes directly, because ownership regulation reduces the need for the Commission to

make subjective judgments about program content. 
Id. ¶ 39.
       Source diversity refers to the availability of media content from a variety of

content producers. 
Id. ¶ 42.
In light of dramatic changes in television markets, including

the increase in the number of channels available to most households, the Commission

determined that source diversity need not be an objective of its broadcast ownership

policies. 
Id. ¶ 43.
Minority and female diversity refers to policies which encourage

minority and female ownership of media sources, and the Commission reaffirmed this

policy goal in the Order. 
Id. ¶ 46.
       As set forth in the preamble to the 1996 Act, Congress believed greater

competition and reduced regulation would inure to the public benefit. 1996 Act,

preamble, 110 Stat. 56. The Order reaffirmed the Commission’s “longstanding

commitment to promoting competition by ensuring pro-competitive market structures,”

Order ¶ 57, recognizing “[c]onsumers receive more choice, lower prices, and more

innovative services in competitive markets than they do in markets where one or more

firms exercises market power.” 
Id. In satisfying
its competition goal, the Commission

also noted competitive markets help contribute to the related goal of viewpoint diversity.

Id. ¶ 58.
The Commission pointed out that competition also furthers the goal of product

innovation. 
Id. ¶ 69.
       Federal regulation of broadcasting historically has placed significant emphasis on

                                            145
localism. The policy goal of localism addresses whether broadcast stations are responsive

to the needs and interests of their local communities. 
Id. ¶ 74.
Localism is contained in

congressional directives to the Commission and has been judicially reaffirmed as a valid

regulatory objective. 
Id. ¶ 73;
see NBC v. United States, 
319 U.S. 190
, 203 (1943)

(“Local program service is a vital part of community life. A station should be ready, able,

and willing to serve the needs of the local community . . . .”). The Commission sought to

promote localism through market structures that take advantage of media companies’

incentives to serve local communities. To measure localism, the Commission focused on

the selection of programming responsive to local needs and interests, and local news

quantity and quality. Order ¶ 78-79.

        The Commission considered the regulatory framework that would best achieve its

goals. It recognized that bright line rules and case-by-case analysis offer different

advantages. The Commission concluded that bright line rules provide greater “certainty

to outcomes, conserve resources, reduce administrative delays, lower transaction costs,

increase transparency of [the] process, and ensure consistency in decisions.” 
Id. ¶ 82.
The Commission determined that a case-by-case process accounts for the particular

circumstances of each transaction but is fraught with regulatory problems, 
id. ¶ 84,
such

as high administrative costs and a lack of planning and investment predictability for

media owners.102 Based on the efficiencies and predictability of bright line rules, this


  102
     Still, the Commission reiterated its commitment to review particular cases and to
closely examine both waiver requests and petitions to deny. Order ¶ 85.

                                            146
regulatory model supports most of the Agency’s rules. 
Id. ¶ 85.
The Agency reiterated

the bright line rules were adopted based on a comprehensive review of the media

marketplace and its assessment of what rules were necessary to promote its goals.

       2.     New M edia Landscape and the Growth of the Internet

       In its Order, the Commission took substantial notice of the expanding media

market and significant technological advances that influence its rules. The Commission

commented: “This Order confronts that challenge by determining the appropriate

regulatory framework . . . in a world characterized not by information scarcity, but by

media abundance.” 
Id. ¶ 89.
       Significant technological advances in the media marketplace over the last twenty-

five years required new regulatory responses from the Commission. Among these

advances in the distribution of information were the Internet, satellite distribution

systems, cable television and video-cassette recorders. Today there are over 308 satellite

delivered non-broadcast networks available for carriage over cable, direct broadcast

satellite systems (“DBS”), and other multi-channel viewed programming distribution

(“MVPD”) systems. Within more traditional sources, the number of broadcast television

and radio outlets have also grown significantly in the last 40 years. 
Id. ¶ 121.
       This explosion of new media sources is best illustrated by the Internet. The

Commission commented:

       The Internet, as an entirely new medium, composed of an amalgam of all
       the technologies that preceded it, completely transformed the way in which
       we communicate in unimaginable ways. These advances not only enabled

                                             147
       the provision of vast amounts of content they also put more control in the
       hands of the public, allowing them to control what, when and how they
       receive information.

Order ¶ 111. The Internet provides a forum for unlimited numbers of independently

administered voices. Additionally, content on the Internet is multimedia; it can be read,

heard, and viewed simultaneously. 
Id. ¶ 118.
The Commission also pointed out that

experiencing web content is a highly individualized activity where people can access the

Internet 24 hours a day anywhere they have access to a web browser. 
Id. The Internet
has spawned a new way of looking at media. The first graphical

interface for the Internet was introduced in 1989. In 1992 there were only 50 websites in

the world. By 1994, there were as many as 3,000 web sites in use. By year-end 2000,

there were more than 30 million web sites. 
Id. ¶ 117.
Approximately 42.5 million

American households subscribed to an Internet access provider in 2000. 
Id. ¶ 120.
According to submitted comments, 62.6 million households in 2001 were online, and that

total is expected to rise to 86.3 million, or 76% of total U.S. households by 2006.

Comments of Tribune Co., at 10.

       According to the Commission, virtually every major media company has a

corresponding web site, and any person with access to a web-hosting file server can

create a web site, which the public may access. Internet users can view sites of their own

choosing or can use a search engine, such as Google News, which presents information




                                            148
gathered from approximately 4,500 news sources worldwide.103 
Id. ¶ 119.
In conclusion,

the Commission determined that:

           there are far more types of media available today, far more outlets per-type
           of media today, and far more news and public interest programming options
           available to the public today than ever before. Although many of these new
           outlets are subscription-based . . . the competitive pressure placed upon
           free, over-the-air media has led to better quality and in some cases, an
           increase in the quantity of some types of content. In the next five to ten
           years, we expect more free, over-the-air content to become available as new
           technologies (i.e., digital transmission) are applied to these traditional
           media (i.e., broadcast television).

Id. ¶ 128.
This dynamic, rapidly changing media landscape provided the backdrop for the

Commission’s ownership rules.

B.         Ownership Rules
           1.   Cross-Ownership Rules
                a.    History of Cross-Ownership Regulation

           For many years the Commission maintained rules governing cross-ownership of

media in local markets. From 1975 through the present Order, the Newspaper/Broadcast

Cross-Ownership Rule prohibited a single company from owning a full-service radio or

television broadcast station and a daily newspaper serving the same community. See 47

C.F.R. § 73.3555(d) (2002). The rule was intended to promote media competition and

diversity. 50 F.C.C.2d at 1074. The Commission examined the newspaper/broadcast



     103
     As the Commission noted, the headlines that appear on Google News are selected
entirely by computer algorithms, based on how and where the stories appear elsewhere on
the web. There are no human editors at Google selecting the headlines and deciding
which headlines get top placement. Order ¶ 119 n.230 (citing A Novel Approach to
News, Google News (BETA), at www.google.com/help/about_news_search.html).

                                               149
cross-ownership prohibition in 1998 and concluded that the rule continued to serve the

public interest because it furthered diversity. 15 F.C.C.R. at 11,105-08 ¶¶ 89-93. In that

review, the Commission noted the rule should be continually reviewed to ensure it

remained in the public interest. Specifically, the Commission noted “[t]here may be

instances, for example, in which, given the size of the market and the size and type of the

newspaper and broadcast outlet involved, sufficient diversity and competition would

remain if a newspaper/broadcast combination were allowed.” 
Id. at 11,109
¶ 95.

       In 1970 the Commission issued a “one-to-a-market” Radio/Television Cross-

Ownership Rule, which proscribed common ownership of more than one full-time

broadcast station (radio or television) in the same market. Amendment of Sections 73.35,

73.240, and 73.636 of the Commission Rules Relating to Multiple Ownership of Standard,

FM and Television Broadcast Stations, 22 F.C.C. 2d 306, 307-08 ¶¶ 5-8 (1970). Like the

newspaper/broadcast rule, the purpose of the rule was twofold: (1) to promote

competition in broadcasting; and (2) to promote diversification of programming sources

and viewpoints. 
Id. at 307
¶ 3. In 1989, the Commission relaxed its “one-to-a-market”

rule by implementing a lenient waiver policy for applications involving radio and

televison combinations in the top 25 markets. Second Ownership Order, 4 F.C.C.R. 1741

¶ 1 (1989). The 1996 Act required the Commission to extend the radio-television cross-

ownership presumptive waiver policy to the top 50 television markets “consistent with the

public interest, convenience, and necessity.” § 202(d). Although the Commission

retained the rule after the 1996 Act, it stated that it would continue to monitor the impact

                                             150
of the rule on the radio and television industries and would consider further modification

of the rule in future biennial reviews. 14 F.C.C.R. at 12,949 ¶ 106.

       In 1999, the Radio/Television Cross-Ownership Rule was modified to its current

form. The Commission found the growth of media outlets, the efficiencies of joint

ownership, and the public service benefits obtained from joint operations all supported its

decision to allow common ownership of radio and television stations. 
Id. at 12,948
¶ 102.

Currently, the Radio/Television Cross-Ownership Rule allows a party to own up to two

television stations and up to six radio stations in a market where at least 20 independently

owned media voices would remain post-merger. Where parties may own a combination

of two television stations and six radio stations, the rule allows a party alternatively to

own one television station and seven radio stations. A party may own up to two

television stations (as permitted under the local television rule) and up to four radio

stations (as permitted under the local radio rule) in markets where, post-merger, at least

ten independently owned media voices would remain. A combination of one television

station and one radio station is allowed regardless of the number of voices in the market.

47 C.F.R. § 73.3555(c) (2002).

        In light of the 1999 relaxation of the rule, the Commission decided to proceed

cautiously and monitor the impact of the new rules on diversity and competition. See

2000 Biennial Review, 16 F.C.C.R. 1207, 1218 ¶ 32 (2001).

       In the Order at issue, the Commission repealed both cross-ownership rules and

replaced them with more flexible Cross Media Limits, which established more finely-

                                             151
tuned cross-ownership limits in small and medium-sized markets, and placed no

restrictions on cross-ownership in large markets beyond the intra-service local caps.

       To provide historical perspective, and to place the repeal of the

Newspaper/Broadcast Cross-Ownership Rule in proper context, it is important to note that

the ban was adopted nearly three decades ago, in a media environment that has been

dramatically and irreversibly transformed in the intervening years. In the nearly thirty

years since the newspaper/broadcast cross-ownership prohibition was enacted, the media

landscape has changed dramatically, as the Commission extensively documents in its

Order. Among these changes are the growth of cable, VCRs, satellite video and audio

services, and the Internet. Order ¶¶ 106-19. As noted, media outlets per market within

broadcast television and radio have grown during this period as well, 
id. ¶ 121,
providing

viewers with a multitude of choices not available twenty or even ten years ago. With

other technological advancements likely in the near future, the Commission recognized

that its rigid rule had become outdated. The FCC concluded that “the question

confronting media companies today is not whether they will be able to dominate the

distribution of news and information in any market, but whether they will be able to be

heard at all among the cacophony of voices vying for the attention of Americans.” 
Id. ¶ 367.
              b.     Repeal of Newspaper Broadcast Cross-Ownership Prohibition

       The FCC looked to its policy objectives of promoting competition, localism and

diversity, and concluded the Newspaper/Broadcast Cross-Ownership Rule (NBCO): 1)

                                            152
was neutral with respect to competition; 2) actually undermined localism by preventing

newspaper-broadcast mergers that would provide more and higher-quality local news to

their markets; and 3) was not necessary to preserve viewpoint diversity in most markets.

Id. ¶ 330.
       In terms of competition, the Commission concluded “the local newspaper market

is distinct from the local broadcasting market,” and therefore “a newspaper/broadcast

combination . . . cannot adversely affect competition in any product market.” 
Id. ¶ 332.
Synergies and cost-reductions of cross-ownership could also translate into increased

competition. 
Id. ¶ 337.
As discussed, the FCC measured the promotion of localism

through two metrics: “the selection of programming responsive to local needs and

interests, and local news quantity and quality.” 
Id. ¶ 78.
The FCC determined cross-

ownership promotes localism because it allows newspaper stations and broadcast stations

to pool their resources, allowing the whole of their coverage to exceed the sum of their

parts. “Specifically, MOWG Study No. 7 found that while non-network owned but

network-affiliated stations provide, on average, 14.9 hours per week of local news and

public affairs programming, newspaper-owned affiliated stations provide almost 50%

more such programming, averaging 21.9 hours per week.” 
Id. ¶ 344
. In addition, the

study found the average number of hours of local news and public affairs programming

provided by same-market, commercially owned television-newspaper combinations was

25.6 hours/week, compared to 16.3 hours/week for the sample of television stations

owned by out-of-market newspapers. 
Id. The FCC
also found corresponding advantages

                                            153
in quality of local coverage provided by newspaper-owned stations, as shown by ratings

(measuring consumer approval) and industry awards (measuring critical approval). 
Id. ¶ 345.
Substantial evidence supports the Commission’s decision that cross-ownership

translates into pro-competitive public interest benefits.

       The FCC concluded the negative effects of the NBCO Rule on localism hurt

diversity as well: if local stations do not have the resources to provide a high quantity and

quality of news, the number of strong voices in their market will be diminished. The FCC

cited record evidence both supporting and refuting the notion that common ownership

leads to common viewpoint among media properties. From this conflicting evidence, the

FCC inferred that “although there is evidence to suggest that ownership influences

viewpoint, the degree to which it does so cannot be established with any certitude.” 
Id. ¶ 364.
       The Commission also examined the growth in media outlets, including the addition

of cable and the Internet as viable news sources. It concluded the large number of new

voices rendered the NBCO unnecessary for purposes of protecting diversity, because any

loss in independent voices resulting from cross-ownership would, in all but the most

concentrated markets, be counterbalanced by the plethora of alternative voices. The

Order concluded “competing media outlets abound in markets of all sizes . . . .” 
Id. ¶ 365.
Specifically, the Commission pointed to the expanding role of cable in providing varied

content, including local news and public affairs programming. 
Id. The Order
continued,

noting:

                                             154
       The Internet, too, is becoming a commonly-used source for news,
       commentary, community affairs, and national/international information.
       Seventy-two percent of Americans are now online and spend an average of
       nine hours weekly on the Internet. MOW G Study No. 3 suggests that
       consumers generally view Internet news sources as a substitute for daily
       newspapers and broadcast news . . . the Internet does play an important role
       in the available media mix.

Id. ¶ 365.
It is also worth noting that none of the 30 million web sites existing in the year

2000 existed when the NBCO Rule was first adopted.

       The record supports: (1) the growth in television and radio outlets; and (2) that

cable and the Internet were properly cited in the growth of media outlets. Additionally,

the benefits to localism from cross-ownership provide a rational basis for repealing the

blanket prohibition. Moreover, the Agency’s decision on the mixed record is particularly

reasonable in light of the deregulatory tenor of § 202(h).

              c.     Cross-Media Limits

       The record and the Commission’s experience led it to conclude that more narrowly

focused limits were necessary in certain specific situations to guard against “an elevated

risk of harm to the range and breadth of viewpoints that may be available to the public,”

resulting from cross-ownership of media properties. Order ¶ 442. Having examined the

record evidence, the Commission reasonably concluded that new limits were necessary

“to check the acquisition by any single entity of a dominant position in local media

markets—not in economic terms, but in the sense of being able to dominate public

debate—through combinations of cross-media properties.” 
Id. ¶ 432.
       In that vein, the FCC adopted a methodology termed the Diversity Index to

                                             155
provide its new media cross-ownership framework with an empirical footing. The

Diversity Index takes account of certain media outlets available to consumers, the relative

importance of those media as sources of local news, and ownership concentration across

these media. 
Id. ¶ 391.
       Based on detailed analysis of the record, informed by the Diversity Index, the FCC

adopted the following Cross Media Limits:


 Number of Television Stations in Market      Cross-Ownership Limits
 1-3 television stations                      No cross-ownership of newspapers, radio
                                              stations, or television stations.
 4-8 television stations                      Single entity may own a daily newspaper
                                              and either: (1) a television station and up
                                              to half the maximum number of radio
                                              stations allowed by the local radio rules;
                                              or (2) no television station and as many
                                              radio stations as allowed by the cross-
                                              ownership rule. Additionally, a television
                                              owner who owns a duopoly (two
                                              television stations) may not own a
                                              newspaper; likewise, a newspaper owner
                                              may only own one television station.
 Over 9 television stations                   No cross-ownership limits.

       As noted, in crafting its Cross Media Limits, the FCC drew upon the Diversity

Index, which it modeled after the Herfindahl-Hirschmann Index (“HHI”). The HHI was

originally constructed to measure market concentration in the context of economic

competition; if a given market’s HHI was too high, it signaled the market was at risk of

being monopolized. By analogy, the FCC used its Diversity Index to determine which



                                            156
media markets presented the highest risk of ownership concentration. Underlying this

objective is the premise that media ownership influences viewpoint, so that highly

concentrated media ownership could negatively impact the diversity of viewpoints

disseminated within a market.

         The FCC chose the HHI as its market concentration metric over a simple firm

count because of the former’s greater sensitivity for concentration. 
Id. ¶ 396.
The HHI

sums the squares of firms’ market shares in a given market. The higher a market’s HHI,

the more concentrated it is. For example, an economic market with only one firm (a

monopoly) would have an HHI of 10000 (100 squared), while a market shared equally

among ten firms (“M arket A”) would have an HHI of 1000 (10 times 10 squared). A firm

count system would treat Market A as evenly concentrated with a ten-market firm having

a market share breakdown of 30-30-5-5-5-5-5-5-5-5 (“Market B”) because each market

contains ten firms. In contrast, the HHI supports the intuition that Market B is actually

vastly more concentrated, with an HHI of 2000. Furthermore, unlike the firm count

system, the HHI recognizes that a merger between two large firms creates a more

concentrated market than a merger between two smaller firms. If the two 30% firms

merged in M arket B, its HHI would rise to 3800, while a merger of two 5% firms would

increase the HHI to 2050. The firm count system would undiscerningly treat both

mergers the same, however, by noting that both markets would now have 9 firms instead

of 10.

         The FCC adapted the HHI to viewpoint diversity by ascertaining different media’s

                                            157
shares of consumers’ local news preferences. MOWG Study No. 8, a nationwide survey,

asked respondents to identify sources used in the past seven days for local news and

current affairs, offering the following answer choices: “television, newspaper, radio,

Internet, magazines, friends/family, other, none, don’t know, and refuse.” 
Id. ¶ 402.
The

Study then asked respondents to identify the sources they had used in the past 7 days for

national news. According to Study No. 8, the five leading sources of local news were

television, newspapers, radio, the Internet and magazines. In apportioning media shares,

however, the FCC decided to discount magazines entirely because they only accounted

for 6.8% of respondents’ answers, and only .6% of respondents identified magazines as

their “primary” source of local or national news. Furthermore, the Pew Research Center

conducted a study that showed only 4.2% of their responses cited news magazines as a

source of local or national news. The FCC concluded such small figures for local or

national news presaged even lower figures for local news only, because, with isolated

exceptions, most magazines are national in focus. Accordingly, the FCC reasoned that

magazines would have a negligible weight in the Diversity Index and should properly be

excluded, at least until the next biennial review. After excluding magazines, and

adjusting the remaining market shares accordingly, the user shares of the remaining four

media were 33.8% for television, 28.8% for newspapers, 24.9% for radio and 12.5% for

the Internet.

       The FCC then explored whether any of the media could be broken down into sub-

media (i.e., television into broadcast and cable, newspapers into daily and weekly). The

                                            158
FCC decided to remove cable/satellite stations/providers from the voice pool because it

was unclear whether the Study No. 8 respondents who said they received local news from

cable television were in reality watching broadcast channels on their cable platforms. 
Id. ¶ 414
. Additionally, local cable stations are only available to approximately one third of

all cable subscribers. 
Id. Thus, the
FCC counted only broadcast stations in its television

percentage. The Order also notes the exclusion of cable from the Diversity Index will be

reviewed in subsequent reviews. Such reviews will include follow-up MOWG questions

concerning non-broadcast media. 
Id. The FCC
broke down newspapers into daily and weekly subcategories, with the

survey data indicating that 70.3% of newspaper respondents read dailies and 29.7% read

weeklies. The FCC used these weights to divide the total newspaper share (28.8%)

among daily (20.2%) and weekly (8.6%) newspapers. Finally, the FCC separated the

Internet into cable modem users and “other users.” The Commission’s studies

demonstrated the appropriate break-down was 18.3% cable users and 81.7% dial-up or

DSL users. Therefore, of the 12.5% of the media market allocated to the Internet, that

percentage was broken down into 2.3% for cable users, and 10.2% for dial-up and DSL

users.

         Having apportioned shares among the various media based on actual use figures,

the FCC turned to weighing different outlets within the same media. Here, the

Commission moved away from actual use and attributed each outlet an equal share of its




                                            159
media type.104 In other words, in a market with ten television stations, the FCC did not

determine what percentage of viewers actually received their local news from each of the

ten stations; it simply apportioned each 10% of the television share, meaning a 3.4%

share of the overall local news “market.” The FCC added commonly owned shares

together to divide shares of the market by owner. For example, a market with ten

television stations, two of which are commonly owned, would have share figures of 6.8

and eight 3.4’s rather than ten shares of 3.4. Similarly, the FCC added cross-owned

shares from different media. For example, a market with ten television stations and ten

radio stations with one cross-ownership combination would have share figures of 5.9,

nine 3.4’s and nine 2.5’s, rather than ten 3.4’s and ten 2.5’s. Once the FCC determined

the breakdown of shares amongst various independent owners, it squared those shares and

added them together to get the Diversity Index for the market in question. See Order

App. C (calculating Diversity Indices for various sample markets).

        The FCC then sought to determine the Diversity Indices for various sample

markets as a function of their number of Television stations. Specifically, the FCC

calculated the Diversity Index for every market in the U.S. with 1-5, 15 or 20 television

stations. The FCC then calculated the Diversity Indices for ten randomly selected

markets with 6 television stations, 7 television stations, 8 television stations, 9 television

stations and 10 television stations; the FCC chose ten-market samples for each television


  104
    As noted, the Commission adopted a different policy with regard to the Internet
where many more “stations,” or websites, exist.

                                              160
station grouping in the 6-10 station range because so many media markets have 6-10

television stations. Using this data, the FCC determined the average Diversity Index for a

market as a function of the number of television stations within that market. Order App.

D. The FCC also calculated the average increase in HHI in each tested market that would

result from various cross-ownership merger scenarios. 
Id. The FCC
noted that in antitrust analysis, a market is not considered moderately

concentrated until its HHI exceeds 1000. The FCC’s calculations revealed that markets

with three or fewer television stations had average Diversity Indices of over 1000, and

that any cross-ownership mergers in such small markets would lead to significant

Diversity Index increases; consequently, the FCC decided to prohibit any cross-

ownership in markets with three or fewer television stations. In markets with four to

eight television stations, which had base Diversity Indices below but near 1000,105 the

FCC determined that dangerously large Diversity Index increases would result from daily

newspaper-television duopoly mergers, as well as mergers between a daily newspaper, a

television station and more than half the radio stations allowed by the local radio rule.

Finally, the FCC concluded that large markets, with low indices and modest Diversity

Index effects from potential mergers, did not need any cross-ownership regulation at all.

             The Diversity Index was not promulgated as an ownership rule. Instead, it played

a supporting role in the development of the Cross Media Limits. In adopting the


     105
           Average Diversity Indices for these markets ranged from 753-928. See Order App.
D.

                                                 161
Diversity Index, the FCC noted: “While the Diversity Index is not perfect, nor absolutely

precise, it is certainly a useful tool to inform our judgment and decision-making. It

provides us with guidance, informing us about the marketplace and giving us a sense of

relative weights of different media.” Order ¶ 391. As the Commission stated, the “cross-

media limits are based on a set of assumptions drawn directly from the record evidence in

this proceeding . . . the CML [Cross Media Limits] . . . ultimately rest[] on our

independent judgments about the kinds of markets that are most at-risk for viewpoint

concentration, and the kinds of transactions that pose the greatest threat to diversity.” 
Id. ¶ 435.
In the end, the Diversity Index provided the Commission with a rough picture of

the amount of media diversity concentration in markets, and how changes as a result of

cross-media combinations could affect the level of diversity in markets.

       The Commission’s use of the Diversity Index constitutes a rational effort to lend a

factual foundation to a thorny regulatory question. The development of the Diversity

Index represents a bona fide approach that employs empirical evidence to measure and

inform policy choices, which do not easily lend themselves to calculation. I would affirm

the Commission’s effort to lend a modicum of empirical support to a regulatory issue that

had not been fully revisited in nearly thirty years. Perhaps other measures might have

been employed, but the development and use of the Diversity Index was rational and

reasonable, and clearly neither arbitrary nor capricious. The FCC sufficiently

demonstrated the new rule was “necessary in the public interest.”

       2.     Local Television Ownership Rule

                                             162
       Adopted in 1964, the Commission’s “duopoly” rule prohibited ownership or

control of television stations with overlapping Grade B signal contours. 47 C.F.R. §

73.3555(b) (1998). Section 202(c)(2) of the 1996 Act instructed the Commission to

conduct a rulemaking “to retain, modify, or eliminate” its local television ownership

limitations. 110 Stat. 111. Under the 1996 Act, the Commission adopted rules permitting

common ownership of two television stations with overlapping contours, so long as (1)

one of the two stations is not ranked among the top four, and (2) at least eight

independently owned full-power commercial and noncommercial stations remain in the

market after the merger. 47 C.F.R. § 73.3555(b) (2002).

       This rule was remanded to the Commission by the Court of Appeals for the D.C.

Circuit in Sinclair. 
284 F.3d 148
. In that case, the court affirmed that “the local

ownership rule furthers diversity at the local level and is necessary in the ‘public interest’

under § 202(h),” 
id. at 160,
but held that the FCC had not justified different definitions of

“voices” in the local television and radio-television cross-ownership rules. 
Id. at 165.
The court held that the Commission had “failed to demonstrate” why it excluded non-

broadcast media from the ownership rules’ eight-voices test. 
Id. On remand,
the agency modified the Local Television Ownership Rule. The

Commission determined the old local television rule was not necessary to further public

interest in competition and viewpoint diversity. Order ¶ 133. But the Agency determined

that some ownership limits remained necessary to promote competition. 
Id. The modified
rule permits common ownership of up to two commercial stations in markets

                                             163
that have 17 or fewer full-power commercial and non-commercial stations, and up to

three commercial stations in markets that have 18 or more stations. 
Id. ¶ 186.
The

Agency also prohibited combinations which would result in a single entity acquiring more

than one station ranked in the top four in the market based on audience share. 
Id. Therefore, the
rule prohibits ownership of more than one television station in any market

with fewer than five television stations.106 
Id. The new
local television limits are

reproduced in the following table:


 Number of stations in a Market                    Number of combinations allowed
 four or fewer                                     No combinations (per operation of the
                                                   top-four restriction).
 five to seventeen                                 Two stations may be combined, as long as
                                                   both of the combining stations are not in
                                                   the top four.
 eighteen or more                                  Three stations may be combined, as long
                                                   as two of the combining stations are not in
                                                   the top four.

          The Commission found the common ownership of television stations in local

markets can “result in consumer welfare enhancing efficiencies,” by eliminating

redundant expenses and increasing opportunities for “cross-promotion and counter-

programming.” 
Id. ¶ 14
7. These efficiencies would enable local broadcasters to better

compete with cable and digital providers and would also “spur the transition to digital

television,” which the FCC identified as a goal in the public interest. 
Id. ¶ 14
8.



  106
        This aspect of the Rule will be referred to as the top-four rule.

                                                164
       Such common ownership was not found to have a detrimental effect on audience

ratings. 
Id. ¶ 15
0. Importantly, the Commission concluded that “owners/operators of

same-market combinations have the ability and incentive to offer more programming

responsive to the needs and interests of their communities and that in many cases, that is

what they do.” 
Id. ¶ 164.
In fact, “[a]udience share data . . . reveals that common

ownership of two broadcast televison stations has generally improved audience ratings.”

Id. ¶ 15
0.

       According to the Commission, the new rule does not compromise its diversity

goals because the modified caps ensure at least six firms in markets with twelve or more

stations. 
Id. ¶ 207.
The Commission explained that it would permit additional

concentration in markets with less than twelve television stations because the economies

of local stations justified an increase in market concentration as markets get smaller. 
Id. ¶ 201.
Indeed, the Commission noted that its local television rule—designed to protect

competition—necessarily also protects diversity. 
Id. ¶¶ 178,
180. Additionally, the

Commission pointed out that television broadcast stations are not the only media

contributing to viewpoint diversity in local markets. Numerous other sources for news

are available, even within the delivered video market. See, e.g., 17 F.C.C.R. 26,901,

26,909-52 ¶¶ 15-111.

       In regard to the top-four restriction, the Commission explained, “in local markets,

there is a general separation between the audience shares of the top four-ranked stations

and audience shares of the other stations in the market.” Order ¶ 195. Therefore, these

                                            165
mergers would often lead to significant increases in market consolidation. In addition,

the Commission found that combinations of the top-four stations were less likely to yield

public interest benefits in terms of local news or improved technology. 
Id. ¶ 199.
       The FCC further justified the specific numerical caps in its local television

ownership rule by employing the Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission’s

“standard approach” to evaluating competitive harms of an increase in horizontal market

concentration: as noted, the Herfindahl-Hirschmann Index. In developing the new local

ownership tiers, the FCC looked to the HHI used in merger analysis, selecting an HHI of

1800 as the benchmark for competitively suspect combinations. The DOJ/FTC merger

guidelines recognize the HHI level of 1800 as the maximum level for “moderate”

concentration. The FCC selected the upper bound for moderate concentration, instead of

the lower bound of 1000, in recognition of the competitive pressures exerted by the cable

networks. 
Id. ¶ 192.
The ownership rules ensure that in markets with 12 or more

stations, there will be at least six competing firms. 
Id. ¶ 207.
Six equal-sized

competitors in a market corresponds to an HHI of 1800. While the rule allows for fewer

firms in smaller markets, the Commission explained that such increased levels of

concentration were justified by the economics of smaller market stations. 
Id. ¶ 201.
       The Commission justified its assumption of equal-share television stations.

Television market shares vary widely. 
Id. ¶ 193.
Due to shifts in programming

popularity and product innovation, market shares in broadcasting are more fluid than in

other industries. The Commission found that television shares can shift substantially over

                                            166
the life of a firm’s investment in a particular station. Thus, in constructing its rules, the

Commission focused on “a firm’s ‘capacity’ to deliver programming”—i.e., “the number

of licenses that a firm controls in a market.” 
Id. As the
Commission explained, license

caps— as opposed to limits on market share— are well-suited to serve the Commission’s

diversity goals. 
Id. ¶¶ 129,
178. The Commission’s amendment of the local television

rule is well-supported by the record and would provide a benchmark for future revisions.

          3.     Local Radio Ownership Rule

          For many years the Commission limited local radio ownership to no more than one

AM and FM station with overlapping signal contours. See, e.g., Amendment of Section

73.3555 of the Commission’s Rules, 4 F.C.C.R. 1723, 1723 ¶¶ 5-6 (1989). In 1992 the

Commission relaxed its rules to permit common ownership of radio stations in line with

the size of various local market tiers. Revision of Radio Rules and Policies, 7 F.C.C.R.

2755, 2776 ¶ 40 (1992), on reconsideration, 7 F.C.C.R. 6387 (1992). In its 1992

rulemaking, the Commission considered using the Arbitron rating service to define radio

markets, and the number of stations in the market. 
Id. at 2778
¶ 45. In the end, however,

the Agency decided to define radio markets based on signal contour overlap.107

          Section 202(b)(1) of the 1996 Act required the FCC to revise its limits on the

number of stations an entity could own in a particular market by adjusting both the market

tiers and the numerical limits. See Implementations of Sections 202(a) and 202(b)(1) of



  107
        The contour-overlap methodology is discussed in detail infra pp. 175-178.

                                              167
the Telecommunications Act of 1996 (Broadcast Radio Ownership), 11 F.C.C.R. 12,368

(1996). The 1996 Act expanded multiple radio station ownership rights by setting the

following common ownership limits: eight stations in markets with forty-five or more

stations, with five or fewer in the same service (AM or FM), § 202(b)(1)(A); seven

stations in markets with thirty to forty-four stations, with four or fewer in the same

service, § 202(b)(1)(B); six stations in markets with fifteen to twenty-nine stations, with

four or fewer in the same service, § 202(b)(1)(C); and five stations in markets with fifteen

to twenty-nine stations, with three or fewer in the same service, provided that no single

entity could own more than fifty percent of the stations in such market, § 202(b)(1)(D).

Congress authorized the FCC to further relax these limitations in order to permit greater

common ownership if such ownership “will result in an increase in the number of radio

broadcast stations in operation.” § 202(b)(2). The limits are summarized below:


 Number of commercial         Number of stations a         Number of stations a party may
 stations in market:          party may own:               own which are of the same
                                                           service (AM or FM):
 45 or more                   8                            5
 between 30 and 44            7                            4
 between 15 and 29            6                            4
 14 or fewer                  5 [with the exception        3
                              that a party cannot own
                              more than 50% of the
                              stations in such market]

The new limits imposed by Congress will be regularly reviewed as the 1996 Act required

the FCC to review biennially (now quadrennially) its media ownership rules and modify

                                             168
or repeal those it found not “necessary in the public interest.” 1996 Act, § 202(h).

       At the time Congress instituted these changes, the FCC defined a radio market as

the geographic area covered by the overlapping contours of the stations proposed for

common ownership. See 47 C.F.R. § 73.3555(a)(1) (1995). Under that definition, local

markets were determined with reference to stations’ “principal community

contour”— essentially, the area reached by a station’s signal at a certain level of strength.

See 
id. § 73.3555(a)(3).
For each proposed combination of stations, the local market was

defined by “the number of . . . stations whose principal community contours overlap, in

whole or in part, with the principal community contours of the stations” that were

proposed to be commonly owned. 
Id. Nothing in
the 1996 Act addressed the

methodology for defining radio markets or identifying the number of radio stations in a

market for purposes of the ownership rules.

       The FCC initiated a rulemaking to change the definition of radio markets. 1998

Biennial Reg’y Review—Review of the Commission’s Broadcast Ownership Rules and

Other Rules Adopted Pursuant to Section 202 of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 15

F.C.C.R. 11,058, 11,091-94 (2000). In this review, the Commission expressed concern

that its method of defining markets and identifying stations in the market led to

“unrealistic results,” and were both “illogical” and “contrary to Congress’ intent.” 
Id. 11093-94 ¶
65, 67. Therefore, the Commission commenced a proceeding seeking

comment on whether and how it should modify the way in which it “determine[s] the

dimensions of radio markets and count[s] the number of stations in them.” Definition of

                                             169
Radio Markets, 15 F.C.C.R. 25,077 ¶ 1 (2001). The FCC eventually consolidated that

rulemaking with another proceeding regarding the local radio ownership rules, Rules and

Policies Concerning Multiple Ownership of Radio Broadcast Stations in Local Markets;

Definition of Radio Market, 16 F.C.C.R. 19,861 ¶ 1, and then rolled the entire proceeding

into the 2002 biennial review. See Omnibus NPRM, 17 F.C.C.R. at 18,506.

       Since the passage of the 1996 Act, record evidence demonstrates dramatic

transformation in the radio industry. In each of the last six years, about 20% of U.S. radio

stations have changed hands in a frenzy of deal-making. From 1996 to 2002, the number

of radio stations owners declined by 34% even though the number of commercial stations

increased by 5.4%. Within individual markets, small numbers of large owners often

dominate. The audience shares of the top four firms in smaller markets are even higher

than in larger markets. The audience share of the top four firms in markets 51-100 and

101-289 is 92.5% and 93.9% respectively. This has led to high market concentrations, as

measured by the HHI. When conducting its 2002 biennial review, the FCC was faced

with significant consolidation in radio markets.

       In the Order at issue, the Commission determined that it should retain the

numerical limits in the local radio rule, but that it should revise the contour overlap

method. The FCC proposed to replace the contour-overlap methodology with a

geographic methodology, based on the Arbitron Metro Survey Areas. Arbitron, the

principal radio rating service in the country, has defined radio markets (called Arbitron

Metros) for most of the more populated urban areas of the country. Arbitron Metros are

                                             170
based on Metropolitan Areas established by the Office of M anagement and Budget.

        The geography-based, Arbitron Market definition relies on the market definitions

of Arbitron radio rating service, a private entity that measures local radio station

audiences for its customer stations. See Order ¶¶ 275-76.108 Additionally, the Agency

decided to include commercial and non-commercial stations that are licensed to a

community in the relevant Arbitron Metro,109 as well as stations located outside the Metro

that attract a minimum level of listenership in the Metro, see 
id. ¶¶ 279-81,
295, in

calculating the relevant local radio market.

        The Commission identified several flaws in the manner in which it presently

defines radio markets, the contour-overlap market definition. 
Id. ¶ 239.
One major flaw

is known as the “Pine Buff” problem or “numerator-denominator” inconsistency. The

FCC described the inconsistency this way:

        [A] party is deemed to own only those stations that are represented in the
        numerator, i.e., stations that have mutually overlapping principal
        community contours. In calculating the denominator, however, any radio
        station whose principle community contour overlaps the principal


  108
     The Commission recognized, “Arbitron Metros do not cover the entire country.”
Order ¶ 282. There are 287 Arbitron Metros, which cover 60% of the commercial radio
stations, 30% of the counties, and 78% of the population above age 12 in the United
States, including Puerto Rico. 
Id. Accordingly, the
Commission initiated a new
rulemaking proceeding to “develop radio market definitions for non-Metro areas.” 
Id. ¶ 283.
The use of one kind of radio definition in some markets and a different kind of
definition in others does not render the rule irrational.
  109
    “Metro” is Arbitron’s term for a geographic radio market, consisting of a particular
county or set of counties with a boundary defined by Arbitron. See Order ¶¶ 275, 277 &
n.582.

                                               171
       community contour of at least one of the radio stations in the numerator is
       counted as being in the market, regardless of who owns the station. As a
       result, the denominator may include radio stations that are owned by the
       same party that owns the radio stations represented in the numerator.
       Because those stations are counted in the denominator, they are by
       definition “in” the market, but they would not count against the party’s
       ownership limit in that market unless their principal community contours
       overlap the principal community contours of all the radio stations in the
       numerator.

Id. ¶ 253.
       Numerator-denominator inconsistency causes two potential problems. First,

because commonly owned stations in the denominator are not counted in the numerator, a

party could use its own radio stations to increase the size of a market and “bump” itself

into a higher ownership tier. The more common occurrence, according to the FCC, is that

the inconsistency allows a party to own radio stations in the relevant market without

having those stations count against the party’s ownership limits. The contour-overlap

methodology thus allows entities to circumvent the ownership limits, which are intended

to promote competition and “to protect against excessive concentration levels in local

radio markets.” 
Id. ¶ 254.
       The FCC also determined this irrationality in the contour-overlap methodology

could not be fixed. If commonly owned stations are excluded from the denominator, then

market size would be contingent upon who owned what station, “a distinction that would

be both unprincipled and unprecedented in the history of competition analysis.” 
Id. ¶ 255.
If all commonly owned stations in the denominator are included in the numerator, “a

party’s ownership level in a particular market may be overly inflated by outlying stations

                                            172
far from the area of concentration.” 
Id. Further, the
FCC’s interim adoption of a

modified contour-overlap methodology for non-Arbitron Metro areas does not repudiate

these findings. The FCC concluded temporary use of the old method was unavoidable

during the pendency of the rulemaking process. 
Id. ¶ 283.
And because this method was

well-understood, it at least had the benefit of permitting orderly processing of radio

station applications. The FCC noted, however, that the adjustments made could only

“minimize the more problematic aspects of that system.” 
Id. ¶ 285.
       The contour-overlap approach is contrary to traditional antitrust principles, which

employ “relevant geographic markets” for purposes of competition analysis. Though

radio stations are signal-based products, the FCC effectively addressed this point by

noting: “[r]adio stations serve people, not land,” and “people in the United States tend to

be clustered around specific population centers.” 
Id. ¶ 273.
This is demonstrated by the

fact that the 287 Arbitron Metros cover only 30% of the counties in the United States, but

cover 78% of the population above the age of twelve. 
Id. ¶ 282.
It is also noteworthy

that the Justice Department often treats Arbitron Metros as the relevant market for

antitrust purposes. See United States v. CBS Corp. and Am. Radio Sys. Corp., Proposed

Final Judgment and Competitive Impact Statement, 63 Fed. Reg. 18036, 18044-45

(Apr. 13, 1998). “The fact that radio signals are not congruent with geographic

boundaries does not undermine the logic of relying on geographic areas to define radio

markets.” Order ¶ 273.

       In addition, the “subjective market” problem has other drawbacks. Because

                                            173
stations with larger signal contours are more likely to create larger radio markets, the

contour-overlap methodology disproportionately encourages the consolidation of

powerful stations relative to smaller stations. Also, radio stations may overlap only a

very small portion of a given “market.” So while they are part of that market, these

stations may be unable to serve effectively the listeners or advertisers affected by the

proposed consolidation. Finally, the fact that every “market” is unique frustrates the

FCC’s ability to benchmark and compute the level of consolidation in a given area.

       The FCC not only discussed the flaws in the contour-overlap methodology but also

addressed concerns raised about the Arbitron Metro methodology. As the FCC conceded,

“any methodology we develop may create anomalous situations in certain instances. But

we cannot agree that our inability to achieve perfection in every instance justifies

maintaining the current system.” 
Id. ¶ 263.
The FCC established safeguards to deter

parties from attempting to manipulate Aribtron market definitions. Specifically, a radio

station licensed by a community outside the Metro will not be considered “home” to a

Metro for purposes of the ownership rules until that change has been in place for two

years. Similarly, changes in Metro boundaries will be subject to a similar two year rule.

The FCC believed these safeguards will ensure that changes made to Arbitron Metros will

be made “to reflect actual market conditions and not to circumvent the local radio

ownership rule.” 
Id. ¶ 278.
       The FCC cited several reasons why the Arbitron Metro methodology is a more

rational way to define radio markets than the contour method. As stated, Arbitron Metros

                                             174
are consistently considered the relevant geographic market for antitrust purposes.

Arbitron market definitions are also industry standards. It is reasonable for an agency to

rely on industry defined standards. See AT&T Corp. v. FCC, 
220 F.3d 607
, 627 (D.C.

Cir. 2000) (stating that the FCC’s reliance on “industry-approved metrics” in lieu of

conducting its own competition study was not arbitrary and capricious).

       Whether the contour-overlap methodology or the Arbitron Metro methodology

more effectively promotes competition between radio stations cannot easily be quantified.

Cf. 
NCCB, 436 U.S. at 796
-97 (rejecting argument that the rulemaking record did not

demonstrate the new rule would in fact lead to increased diversity and stating that

“diversity and its effects” are “elusive concepts” and “not easily defined”). “To restrict

the Commission’s action to cases in which tangible evidence appropriate for judicial

determination is available would disregard a major reason for the creation of

administrative agencies, better equipped as they are for weighing intangibles by

specialization, by insight gained through experience, and by more flexible procedure.”

FCC v. RCA Communications, Inc., 
346 U.S. 86
, 96 (1953) (internal quotations omitted).

As discussed, the FCC provided several reasons why it believed the Arbitron M etro

methodology is superior to the contour-overlap methodology. This type of “line-

drawing” determination is entitled to “broad leeway” and deference. 
Sinclair, 284 F.3d at 159
. An agency is “free to change its position” if it supplies “adequate data and a

reasoned analysis to support the change.” Natural Resources Def. Council, Inc. v. E.P.A.,

790 F.2d 289
, 298 (3d Cir. 1986). The FCC met this burden with respect to its decision to

                                            175
switch from the contour-overlap market definition to Arbitron Metros.

       Having settled on a revised local radio market definition, the Commission

reaffirmed the ownership tiers established by Congress in the 1996 Act. The Commission

emphasized that “[n]umerical limits help to keep the available capacity from becoming

‘locked-up’ in the hands of one or a few owners, and thus help prevent the formation of

market power” in competing for listeners. Order ¶ 288. The Commission observed that

“[t]he current tiers ensure that, in markets with between 27 and 51 radio stations, there

will be approximately five or six radio firms of roughly equal size,” and that many of the

top 100 metro markets fall within that range. 
Id. ¶ 289.
Finding “that the concentration

levels permitted by the current rule represent a reasonable and necessary balance for radio

broadcasting that comports with general competition theory,” the Commission “decline[d]

to relax the rule to permit greater consolidation.” 
Id. ¶ 290.
The Commission also

decided against more restrictive limits. The Commission recognized, however, “that

greater levels of concentration may be needed to ensure the potential for viability of radio

stations in smaller markets.” 
Id. ¶ 292.
       As with broadcast television, the Commission found that radio audience shares can

change over time, and an appropriate evaluation of radio markets structure must take into

account that licenses provide radio stations with the capacity to provide more popular

programming. See 
id. ¶ 288.
The Commission’s assumption of equal shares when

choosing its ownership limits takes account of these considerations. The Commission

recognized that over the life of a firm’s investment in a radio station, the market share of

                                             176
all stations in the market can shift substantially. Accordingly, the Commission chose an

approach that counts all stations in the market as having similar capacity to compete for

listeners. In evaluating the local radio ownership limits, the Commission sought “both to

ensure a healthy, competitive radio market by enabling radio owners to achieve

significant efficiencies though consolidation of broadcast facilities,” while at the same

time “ensur[ing] that such consolidation does not . . . stifl[e] competitive incentives.” 
Id. ¶ 293.
         I agree with the Commission’s determination that numerical limits on radio station

ownership help preserve the limited number of station licenses from being monopolized

by a few owners and help prevent the formation of market power. While interested

parties may have struck the balance at a different point, or suggested rules that promoted

different market structures, the line was the Commission’s to draw. NCCB, 
436 U.S. 814
-

15. The record supports its reasonable decision, which is neither arbitrary nor capricious.




         The Commission also revised its rule to count noncommercial stations as part of

the local radio market in order to account for the fact that such stations exert competitive

pressures in the listening and program production markets. Order ¶ 239. The Agency

found because “noncommercial stations . . . receive a significant listening share in their

respective markets,” their existence “exerts competitive pressure on all other radio

stations in the market.” 
Id. ¶ 295.
Additionally, noncommercial stations count in

determining the size of the local market. 
Id. The FCC
also determined it would prohibit

                                             177
the transfer of station combinations that violate the local radio ownership rule at the time

of sale, subject to a limited exception for sales to “eligible entities.” 110 
Id. ¶ 489.
The

FCC found the disadvantages of allowing the transfer of combinations which do not

comport with the ownership limits are not outweighed by countervailing considerations,

such as owners’ expectancy. 
Id. ¶ 487.
        The FCC determined that Joint Sales Agreements 111 should be attributable to the

brokering licensee under the new rules.112 
Id. ¶ 317.
Where an entity owns or has an

attributable interest in one or more stations in a local radio market, joint advertising sales

of another station in that market for more than 15 percent of the brokered station’s

advertising time per week will result in counting the brokered station toward the

brokering licensee’s ownership caps. 
Id. The FCC
justified this change in the attribution

rule with its finding that in-market JSAs above the 15% threshold convey to the brokering

entity a degree of “influence or control” sufficient to warrant attribution under the

  110
     The FCC defined “eligible entities” as companies with six million dollars or less in
annual revenue. Order ¶ 489. Only such entities may acquire non-compliant
combinations. Eligible entities may not transfer a grandfathered combination aquired
after the adoption date of this Order to a non-eligible entity unless the transferor entity
held the combination for a minimum of three years. 
Id. ¶ 490.
  111
     A typical radio Joint Sales Agreement authorizes the broker to sell advertising time
for the brokered station in return for a fee paid to the licensee. The broker is generally
given the authority to “hire a sales force for the brokered station, set advertising prices,
and make other decisions regarding the sale of advertising time.” Order ¶ 316.
  112
     The FCC previously attributed Local M arketing Agreements (LMAs) in both radio
and television. Revision of Radio Rules and Policies, 7 F.C.C.R. 2755, 2788-89; Review
of the Commission’s Regulations Governing Attribution of Broadcast and Cable/MDS
Interests, 14 F.C.C.R. 12,559, 12,612 (1999).

                                              178
ownership rules. 
Id. ¶ 318.
The FCC gave licensees two years from the effective date of

its Order to terminate sales and programming agreements that do not comply with the

modified local radio ownership rules, and declined to allow any transfers on non-

compliant combinations that included the newly attributable sales and programming

agreements. 
Id. ¶¶ 325,
491. I find the Commission’s conclusions in the Local Radio

Ownership Rule to be reasonable, and clearly not arbitrary and capricious.

       For the reasons stated, I believe the Agency sufficiently supported its rule changes.

The Commission’s decisions were neither arbitrary nor capricious, were supported by the

record and are in the public interest. The majority affirms some of the Commission’s

conclusions as well. I concur with the majority in its affirmance of certain of the

Commission’s conclusions. For the Cross-Ownership Rules, I agree the Commission’s

decision not to retain a ban on newspaper/broadcast cross-ownership is justified under §

202(h) and is supported by record evidence, and the Commission’s decision to retain

some limits on common ownership of different-type media outlets was constitutional and

did not violate § 202(h). For the Local Television Ownership Rule, I agree the

Commission’s decision to retain the top-four restriction is justified and the threshold

challenges to the Commission’s regulatory approach fail. For the Local Radio Ownership

Rule, I agree the Commission justified the switch to Arbitron Markets, that the

Commission was warranted in including noncommercial stations, and the transfer

restriction and attribution of Joint Sales Agreements should be upheld. I now turn to those

areas where the majority finds the Commission’s decisions unsupported.

                                            179
                      IV. Engaging Flaws Found by the M ajority

A.     Cross-Ownership Rule and the Diversity Index

       The majority criticizes the weight given to the Internet in the Diversity Index, as

well as the Commission’s decision to attribute equal market shares to different outlets

within the same media type. The majority also finds the Commission inconsistently

derived the Cross Media Limits from the Diversity Index. Finally, the majority requires

specific notice of the Diversity Index on remand.

       Before addressing these conclusions, it bears reiterating, as the Supreme Court

recognized in FCC v. NCCB, that “[d]iversity and its effects are . . . elusive concepts, not

easily defined let alone measured without making qualitative judgments on both policy

and First Amendment 
grounds.” 436 U.S. at 796-97
(internal quotations omitted). In

reviewing the Agency’s methodological choices and line-drawing in these areas, the

Commission’s determinations deserve deference. See 
Sinclair, 284 F.3d at 159
.

Furthermore, I agree with the Commission’s explanation that the Diversity Index is not

the final rule, nor the sole consideration relied upon, but rather a tool created to provide

the Cross Media Limits with empirical footing. As such, the Agency’s choice and

formulation of a metric should be granted deference unless it can be shown to be

unreasonable. The majority falls short of such a showing.

       1.     Weight Attributed to the Internet

       The Order concludes that diversity is best measured by outlets that provide local

news. Order ¶ 391. The majority claims the Diversity Index grants too much weight to

                                             180
the Internet, understating the level of market concentration and overstating the level of

diversity in a given market. 113 Although conceding the Internet contributes to viewpoint

diversity, the majority states, “we believe that the Commission gave too much weight to

the Internet in deriving the Cross-M edia Limits.” But the Commission’s line-drawing is

not arbitrary or capricious. The majority has substituted its judgment for that of the FCC.

        Although the majority finds the exclusion of cable from the Diversity Index to be

justified, it holds the FCC’s differential treatment of the Internet versus cable is

unsupported. The FCC excluded cable because of serious doubts as to the extent cable

provided independent local news as opposed to merely transmitting broadcast signals.

The majority finds the Internet also largely transmits local news by providing another

platform for local newspapers and broadcast stations. The majority holds the FCC must

somehow discount responses that relied on websites that republished information reported

by a broadcast or newspaper counterpart, or provide more persuasive evidence of

significant independent local news on the Internet.

        To provide a reference point, the FCC’s distinction between cable and the Internet

is distinguishable from the Commission’s unsupported and conflicting definition of

“voices” in Sinclair. 
See 284 F.3d at 162-65
. In that case, the Court of Appeals for the

D.C. Circuit noted the choice of eight competing voices and the definition of voices in the



  113
    I note at the outset the Commission created the Diversity Index with the intention to
“understat[e] the true level of viewpoint diversity.” Order ¶ 400. This makes the
majority’s conclusion even less persuasive.

                                             181
Commission’s local television rule “are quintessentially matters of line drawing invoking

the Commission’s expertise in projecting market results.” 
Id. at 162.
But the court

invalidated the Commission’s definition of voices because the FCC did not adequately

explain why it included only broadcast television stations as voices. 
Id. at 165.
The court

also found the Commission failed to explain its different definitions of “voices” in its

local ownership rule and its cross ownership rule. 
Id. at 162.
       In the Order at issue in Sinclair, the Commission provided two reasons for limiting

its definition of voices. The first was a Roper Study, which “at no point . . . compare[d]

broadcast to non-broadcast television as sources of news, much less as sources of local

news. Rather the Roper study simply indicated that nearly 70% of adults get most of their

news from television . . . .” 
Id. at 163.
The second reason “involved ‘the unresolved

questions about the extent to which [non-broadcast] alternatives are widely accessible and

provide meaningful substitutes to broadcast stations.’” 
Id. at 164
(quoting Local

Ownership Order P. 33, 64 Fed Reg. 50,651). The Commission concluded that “in the

absence of ‘definitive empirical studies quantifying the extent to which the various media

are substitutable in local markets,’ the ‘unresolved questions’ on substitutability

precluded further relaxation of local ownership restrictions.” 
Id. The court
determined

that this “wait-and-see approach . . . cannot be squared with [the Commission’s] statutory

mandate . . . to ‘repeal or modify’ any rule that is not ‘necessary in the public interest.’”

Id. (quoting Fox
Television 
Stations, 280 F.3d at 1042
.).

       In this Order, the Commission’s methodologies, studies and analyses are

                                             182
significantly more comprehensive than in the Local Ownership Order reviewed in

Sinclair. The Commission has presented valid reasons to exclude cable from the

Diversity Index while including the Internet at a weight of 12.5%. Although not perfect,

the MOW G studies are a significant improvement over the study in Sinclair, which did

not compare broadcast television to cable television as a source of news. In the Order

reviewed here, the Commission presents evidence on the substitutability of various media

as news sources. See Order ¶ 409. The studies relied on by the Commission, the

Diversity Index, and resulting Cross-Ownership Rule represent a reasonable approach to

establish rational guidelines and are not arbitrary or capricious.

        Contending the Internet provides predominantly national news, the majority

disputes whether the Internet is a significant source of local news. The majority also

notes that most people who go online for local news merely check the websites of their

local newspaper or broadcast stations. The survey relied on by the Commission, MOWG

Study No. 8, did not identify which websites respondents used as sources of local news. 114

This omission can be fine-tuned on the next round of reviews, but, in my mind, because it

does not approach the level of arbitrary or capricious action, it need not be remanded,

further delaying the implementation of the Commission’s rules. The Commission



  114
     The majority discusses a follow-up question where respondents who used the
Internet as a news source were asked which sites they had used in the past seven days as a
source of local or national news. The most predominant response was “other” (34.9%).
If anything, this response demonstrates that varied, independent sources exist on the
Internet.

                                             183
responds that the Internet provides online-only news sites such as Salon.com,115 online-

only collections of news such as the Drudge Report, 116 and otherwise provides a vast

universe of information not contained in local newspapers or broadcasts.117 Order ¶ 427.

        Although formal local news sites on the Internet are occasionally online platforms

for newspapers and broadcast stations, individuals may nonetheless receive news from

various local websites that directly transmit their own “news,” rather than collect it as

“news.” Reply Comments of Media Gen., Inc., at 15-16. As the Commission noted,

“[a]lthough many local newspaper and broadcast stations maintain websites with news

content, that does not begin to plumb the extent of news sources on the Internet.” Order ¶

427. I agree. The majority contends the FCC should have discounted responses

suggesting Internet use was constrained to online platforms for real world media. Even

assuming the Commission had sufficient data to make such a calculation in this biennial

review, it is not clear 12.5% was an inappropriate weight to attribute to the Internet. With

future Internet growth, the Internet familiarity of the next generation of media users, and

the fact that local information can be received outside of one’s geographic locality, the

  115
    Salon.com (www.salon.com) is an online subscription magazine with independently
produced content, though much of this content does not qualify as “local” news.
  116
     The Drudge Report (www.drudgereport.com) is an online collection of news that is
not independently produced, though the news is independently prioritized and displayed.
  117
     The majority criticizes the Commission for citing two websites that do not specialize
in independent local news—www.salon.com and www.drudgereport.com. These sites
were noted as compilations of news unique to the Internet. The Commission is not
required to provide examples of independent local websites in the Order. The record fills
this gap.

                                             184
Commission likely understated the Internet media share. These considerations only

emphasize that determining the appropriate weight for each media source is as much art

as science, and the choice of 12.5% was reasonable.

        At several places in the Order, the Commission supported its chosen weight for the

Internet in the Diversity Index. The FCC found, “[t]he web provides an unrestrained

forum for the dissemination and consumption of ideas.” Order ¶ 119. The Commission

also found that the Internet “is becoming a commonly-used source for news, commentary,

community affairs and national/international information.” 
Id. ¶ 365.
These findings are

amply supported by record evidence. See Media Gen. Comments, App. 9; see also Media

Gen. Reply Comments. Comments from Media General, as well as those from Hearst

Corporation (referenced in the Order at ¶ 365) pointed to the existence of a significant

number of local, independent websites on the Internet.118 Comments providing examples

of websites with local content explicitly noted these examples represented a fraction of

the websites with local content existing on the W orld Wide W eb. See Media General

Comments, 22-23 n.50 (“Indeed, there is no way in which M edia General’s work could

ever result in an exhaustive and complete list . . . . With more work, the totals could have

easily trebled or quadrupled.”). In its Order, the Commission noted 30 million websites

existed in 2000. Order ¶ 117. The meteoric growth in the number of sites, as well as the



  118
    Some websites referenced in the comments are online platforms for newspapers or
broadcast stations. The existence of such sites does not discredit the existence of
numerous independent websites cited in the record however.

                                            185
sheer number of sites further belie the majority’s contention that independent local

content does not exist in substantial amount on the Internet. In formulating its Diversity

Index, the Commission made clear it looked to potential sources of viewpoint. 
Id. ¶ 425.
The sheer number of available outlets on the Internet supports the Internet’s inclusion at

12.5%.

       Moreover, the record contains a significant number of websites for local

government bodies and civic organizations. See, e.g., Hearst Corp. Comments, MM

Docket No. 01-235, at 11 & n.36, Apps. A, C. As the Commission found, “[t]here is a

virtual universe of information sources on the Internet and there are websites not

maintained by existing news media conveying information on everything from fringe

political groups to local civic events. We cannot pretend that these are not in the

‘diversity’ mix simply because only a small number of people may visit them.” Order ¶

427. The majority responds that “to accept [the Commission’s] ‘universe of information’

characterization of the Internet’s viewpoint diversity, we would also have to disregard the

Commission’s professed intent to focus its consideration of viewpoint diversity on media

outlets.” The majority continues, “local governments are not, themselves, ‘media outlets’

for viewpoint-diversity purposes. Like many entities, they just happen to use a particular

media outlet—the Internet— to disseminate information.”

       I cannot agree with the majority’s characterization. Government web sites are

media outlets within the media type of the Internet. Particular websites—like stations

within the televison and radio mediums—are outlets. See Order ¶ 427 & n.939 (referring

                                            186
to websites, stations, and publications as “information sources,” not “types” of media).

Also, the Commission has not excluded government and civic organization websites from

its consideration in the Diversity Index. The Commission specifically avoided this sort of

content analysis. See 
id. ¶ 424.
These sites are relevant to diversity so long as they

provide news and current affairs. The majority falls short of showing these sites fail to

provide this service.119 Again, the choice not to exclude local government web sites from

the diversity mix is a choice properly within the purview of the Agency. Their inclusion

is neither arbitrary nor capricious.120

        Beyond specific websites, other factors, discussed in the Order, support the

weight the Commission attributed to the Internet. According to the Commission, the

Internet lends itself to diverse viewpoints because of its combination of breadth and


  119
     To cite one of a multitude of examples, the website for the City of Philadelphia,
www.phila.gov., has a specific section for Philadelphia news. See www.phila.gov/news.
This section of the website posts many news releases of interest to Philadelphia residents
and others. The website also contains a link to mayoral initiatives.
http://www.phila.gov/mayor/initiatives/index.html. These services are substantially
different from those provided by comics and classified advertisements. See Order ¶ 424
(explaining the Commission would not count the comics or classifieds of a newspaper
toward viewpoint diversity because “it is not clear that the service has anything to do with
news and current affairs.”). The website also contains a link to the Philadelphia City
Council homepage, which contains member bios, committee information as well as
council agendas. See www.phila.gov/citycouncil/index.html.
  120
     The following list provides some of the websites cited in the record:
www.albanycounty.com, www.sfgov.org, www.sanantonio.gov, www.cityofseattle.net,
www.phila.gov, www.acps.k12.va.us, and www.cityofglensfalls.com. These are local
government and chamber of commerce websites that include information such as
government meeting minutes, city budget reports, local community news, local human
interest stories, and calendars of events.

                                            187
accessibility. As the Order noted, “accessing Web content is a highly individualized

activity.” Order ¶ 118. Simply typing a search into a search engine can produce

numerous relevant websites. The breadth of the Internet allows access to specific issues

at the click of a mouse. For example, a recent search revealed a number of websites

relating to the extension of a bike path on the Schuylkill River in Center City

Philadelphia. See e.g., http://freetheriverpark.typepad.com/ (newsletter of path access

advocacy group) (last visited June 24, 2004);

http://www.centercityresidents.org/SRPaccess.htm (letter in support of park access from

Center City Resident’s Association) (last visited June 24, 2004).

       Moreover, the Internet is unconstrained and provides a forum for a limitless

number of voices and viewpoints. Recognizing the potential for viewpoint dissemination,

political groups have taken their message to the Internet en masse. See e.g., Larry Fish,

New Web Politics: Social Networking, Phila. Inquirer, April 27, 2004, at B1 (discussing

political candidates’ use of the Internet as a campaign tool). Media watchdog sites

provide an alternative to a specific political view in significant numbers. See e.g., Jim

Ruttenberg, New Internet Site Turns Critical Eyes and Ears to the Right, N.Y. Times, May

3, 2004, at A21 (describing Internet site, www.mediamatters.org, where liberal

commentators monitor and counter conservative online and on-air commentators).

Internet news sites have sprouted specifically to provide independent, local news. A

particularly good example is the Independent Media Center of Philadelphia, see

www.phillyimc.org, which over one million people have visited to access independent

                                            188
news since its founding in 2000. See www.phillyimc.org/about.shtml. Finally,

interactive possibilities on the Internet such as message boards and chat rooms permit

virtually unlimited viewpoint dissemination from a multitude of independent “sources.”

The Commission recognized the unique qualities of the Internet as they relate to diversity:

        Whereas other forms of media allow for only a finite number of voices and
        editorially-controlled viewpoints, the Internet provides the forum for an
        unlimited number of voices, independently administered. Furthermore,
        content on the Web is multi-media; it can be read, viewed, and heard
        simultaneously. Since Web pages are stored on Web-hosting file servers,
        accessing Web content is a highly individualized activity, and any
        individual with access to a Web browser can access all available Web
        content 24-hours a day throughout the world.

Order ¶ 118.

        After reviewing numerous websites referenced in the FCC’s Order and supporting

comments, I am convinced that the Commission acted reasonably by including the

Internet in the Diversity Index at 12.5%. With over 70% of Americans now online,121 the

FCC acted reasonably in counting the Internet as a significant addition to the media

marketplace. Assigning the Internet a reasonable percentage of the overall market is a

task within the range of Agency discretion. In any event, its assigned weights cannot be

termed arbitrary and capricious. The Commission has committed to review the

apportioning of media shares in its next review. Order ¶ 414; see also Am. Family Ass’n,



  121
    A recent study indicates that the number of Americans with Internet access has
topped 200 million, or nearly three-fourths of the population older than two. See US
Online Population Tops 200 Million: Survey, available at
www.communicate.com/news_display.php?newsID=54.

                                           189

2004 U.S. App. LEXIS 9051
, at *23 (discussing the Commission’s “duty to evaluate its

policies over time to ascertain whether they work—that is, whether they actually produce

the benefits the Commission originally predicted they would”) (internal quotations

omitted). Each review should bring the Diversity Index—or whatever metric the

Commission chooses to measure diversity—closer to the true manner in which

individuals actually get their information. Based on today’s media marketplace,

excluding the Internet from the Diversity Index, or limiting its importance, would have

sent the Commission down an arbitrary path. The Cross Media Limits and the underlying

Diversity Index constitute a worthy benchmark from which the Commission can continue

to refine its Cross Ownership Rule. The Commission’s rules are clearly not arbitrary and

capricious.

       As noted, I believe the Commission supported its treatment of the Internet in the

Cross-Media Limits. Nonetheless, in the coming years, the Internet will present

challenges for the Commission. In future quadrennial reviews, the FCC may want to

reconsider how the Internet fits into the traditional concepts of measuring viewpoint

diversity, especially the emphasis on local news. By nature, the Internet is uniform

everywhere. Its content is not dependent on geographic or metropolitan boundaries. This

fact should not undervalue this critical media as an important source for the dissemination

of diverse information. In this respect, new modes to characterize diversity may be

required. The Internet allows a dentist in Iraq to post a weblog with daily entries and

photos from Baghdad for viewing anywhere in the world. See

                                            190
http://healingiraq.blogspot.com (last visited May 23, 2004). Because this information

may not qualify as “local news,” it does not follow it should be excluded from the

viewpoint diversity mix. Although independent news is all-important, the ability to

replicate and distribute news on the Internet, long after its original published date, may

cause the Commission to rethink its sole emphasis on “independent” sources when

crafting future rules.

          2.     Equal Market Shares Within Media Type in the Diversity Index

          The majority finds the Commission did not justify its decision to assign outlets of

the same media type equal market shares. As noted, the FCC first apportioned shares

based on actual use figures. But when weighing outlets within the same medium, it

counted outlets equally.122 In light of its expertise and delegated authority to make these

kinds of policy choices, as well as the underlying goal of viewpoint availability, I would

affirm the Commission’s decision to focus on media availability, rather than market

share. Therefore, I would affirm the Commission’s use of equal shares. Whether the

assumption of equal market shares within media types is the perfect solution to a complex

regulatory problem in every market is subject to legitimate debate. But I see no

principled basis to invalidate the Commission’s reasoned approach.

          In constructing the Diversity Index, the FCC concluded that actual use data is

reliable for differentiating among media types because a respondent who relies on


  122
        The Commission only deviated from this approach with the Internet. See Order ¶
426.

                                               191
television for local news will probably not switch to radio or newspaper because of

inherent differences between the media. Order ¶ 409. When it came to weighing outlets

within the same medium, however, the Commission decided to focus on an outlet’s

capacity to deliver information, rather than viewership or readership. This decision is

supported by certain rationales. 
Id. ¶¶ 421-25.
       Although it recognized other approaches were possible, the Commission adopted

the “underlying assumption . . . that all outlets have at least similar technical coverage

characteristics.” 
Id. ¶ 421.
While this may be less true for radio stations, the Commission

determined that Arbitron Metros truncate the service areas of larger, more powerful

stations, equalizing service areas. Additionally, there are generally enough radio stations

in a given market so that the per-station share is fairly small. 
Id. The Commission
found that substitutability within media types was much greater

than substitutability between media types. 
Id. ¶ 422.
So by breaking up the entire media

market based on viewership, and each specific media type based on an equal share theory,

the Commission chose a compromise that reflected individuals’ media preferences and

the relevant regulatory problem. The Commission provided the following common sense

example to support its two complementary approaches:

       A radio station owner is able to change format, say from classic rock to all-
       news, and thus change its impact on the marketplace of ideas. But a radio
       station switching to all-news does not thereby turn itself into the equivalent
       of a televison station nor does its impact on the marketplace of ideas
       become that of a televison station.

Id. 192 As
the FCC explained: “media outlets can rapidly expand their distribution of

content (including local news) at very low marginal cost.” 
Id. ¶ 423.
The FCC asserts

that actual use data within a media type is not as reliable because a media outlet could

conceivably increase or decrease its local news content. The majority cites the example

of the Home Shopping Network switching to a news format as an example of the

improbability of the Commission’s position. That the Home Shopping Network will

likely not switch formats does not negate the Commission’s explanation that program

shifts can and do occur. Radio stations do switch format.123 Furthermore, the

Commission found local news can be added to television broadcasts at low marginal cost,

especially in light of the efficiencies of cross-ownership. 
Id. Such a
programming

change could affect market share.

        The Commission determined that current programming of a specific media outlet

is not necessarily an accurate predictor of future programming. See Maurice E. Stucke

and Allen P. Grunes, Antitrust and the Marketplace of Ideas, 69 Antitrust L.J. 249, 277

(2001) (“‘[E]vidence of past production does not, as a matter of logic, necessarily give a

proper picture of a company’s future ability to compete.’ . . . Even if one could define



  123
      The record shows that the number of radio transfers since the 1996 Act is
unprecedented. Radio Indus. Review 2002: Trends in Ownership, Format and Finance.
Clearly, to the extent these transfers include programming choices, market share could be
fluid. One example of a programming shift likely to affect viewer-ship in many markets
is the emergence of liberal talk radio. See Thom Hartmann, Move Over, Right Wing
Radio – the Liberals are Coming, http://www.commondreams.org/views03/0519-03.htm
(last visited May 25, 2004.).

                                            193
markets and assign market shares in the marketplace of ideas, just how reliable would

these historic market shares be under dynamic market conditions?”) (quoting United

States v. Gen. Dynamics Corp., 
415 U.S. 486
, 501 (1974)). The majority finds this “does

not jibe with the Commission’s decision to assign relative weights to the different media

types themselves . . . .” This statement assumes the Commission must adopt a single

strategy for apportioning shares both within and among outlets, and moreover, this

strategy must perfectly account for the programming choices of newly acquired radio

stations as well as the Home Shopping Network. In my view, the majority imposes an

unreasonably high burden.

       The Commission noted that adopting a usage measure to determine the most

prominent sources for local news and public affairs would require difficult determinations

about which content constitutes local news. For example, the Commission posed the

question whether movie reviews should be considered. Order ¶ 424. Other gray areas

would require similar determinations. Again, the Commission’s goal is not to prescribe

what content citizens access, but to ensure that a large range of viewpoints are available

to the public. 
Id. ¶ 425.
The equal shares approach adopted by the Commission comports

with this goal. As one commentator noted:

       In the marketplace of ideas . . . what matters is the number of alternative
       information outlets available to consumers, not the current popularity . . . of
       the ideas communicated by each outlet. Each source of ideas available to a
       given consumer is equally significant from a First Amendment perspective.
       The rational way to measure the ‘share’ of each source of ideas available to
       a given set of consumers, therefore, is to give each source equal weight. It
       is availability and not usage of alternatives that should count, because it

                                             194
       makes no sense to view the FCC’s role as regulating the popularity, as
       opposed to the availability to consumers, of ideas and information. It is
       unpopular new ideas that may be of the greatest importance to the future.
       Such unpopular ideas are the essence of diversity in the marketplace of
       ideas.

Bruce M . Owen, Regulatory Reform: The Telecommunications Act of 1996 and the FCC

Media Ownership Rules, 2003 M ich. St. DCL L. Rev. 671, 692 (2003).

       The majority, apparently, would have chosen a different approach. But

disagreement with the Commission’s conclusions on such matters does not render those

conclusions arbitrary and capricious. The Commission is entitled to “implement its view

of the public-interest standard of the Act ‘so long as that view is based on consideration

of permissible factors and is otherwise reasonable.’” WNCN Listeners’ 
Guild, 450 U.S. at 594
(quoting 
NCCB, 436 U.S. at 793
). In breaking up media types by market share and

media outlets equally, in my view, the Commission incorporated public media

preferences, its diversity goals, as well as industry characteristics. The Commission’s

decision to attribute shares within media equally was reasonable as it took account of

permissible factors in light of the FCC’s public interest goals.

       3.     Deriving the Cross Media Limits from the Diversity Index

       The majority contends the Commission did not rationally derive its Cross Media

Limits from the Diversity Index results. The majority correctly notes deference to the

Commission’s judgment reaches its zenith when assessing the rationality of the agency’s

line-drawing endeavors, see 
NCCB, 436 U.S. at 814
-15, but then takes issue with the

“seemingly inconsistent” manner in which the line was drawn.

                                             195
       The majority overlooks the Commission’s statement that the Diversity Index is a

tool to help make judgments about cross-ownership, not the final rule. See Order ¶¶ 391,

435. As the Commission emphasized, the “cross-media limits are based on a set of

assumptions drawn directly from the record evidence in this proceeding . . . [and]

ultimately rest[] on our independent judgments about the kinds of markets that are most

at-risk for viewpoint concentration, and the kinds of transactions that pose the greatest

threat to diversity.” 
Id. ¶ 435
(emphasis added). In looking to the Diversity Index, the

Commission did not abdicate its judgment for formula.

       The Diversity Index—or the Cross Media Limits for that matter—will not provide

the perfect limits in every local market. As the Commission stated:

       [W]e are establishing rules of nationwide applicability. We desire,
       therefore, to provide the industry and the public with clear, easy to
       administer rules reflective of common market trends and characteristics.
       We recognize that, in any given market, the lines we draw here may appear
       under- or over-inclusive. Indeed, that quality inheres in the nature of
       proscriptive rules themselves.

Id. ¶ 453.
       The Commission decided to rely on bright-line rules in crafting its ownership

rules. 
Id. ¶ 80.
The FCC chose this approach because “bright line rules provide certainty

to outcomes, conserve resources, reduce administrative delays, lower transaction costs,

increase transparency of [the] process, and ensure consistency in decisions.” 
Id. ¶ 82.
As

a result of the Commission’s decision to adopt a bright-line rule rather than a case-by-

case approach, the rules will not always perfectly address the diversity needs of a given


                                            196
market. This characteristic is inherent in nationwide, prescriptive rules, and in my view

does not require remand.

       The majority finds the Commission allowed combinations (newspaper/television

station/50% radio limit) that resulted in higher Diversity Index increases, while

disallowing combinations (newspaper/television duopoly), which resulted in lower

increases. But the Cross Media Limits were not based solely on the Diversity Index. In

fact, the Commission directly addressed the majority’s purported “inconsistency:”

       To begin with, the public interest benefits of newspaper ownership (the
       benefits of cross-fertilization between media) likely are realized primarily
       in the first broadcast station co-owned in either service. Although there
       may be economic benefits to the owner from more extensive combinations,
       it is not clear that these benefits will accrue to the public in any meaningful
       way; at least the public interest component of these benefits is likely to
       decline incrementally as the number of stations increases. Given that no
       owner will be permitted, in accordance with our local ownership cap, to
       hold more than two television stations in a small to medium size market, a
       limit of one station in these markets for owners of local newspapers will
       maximize the public interest benefits, while reducing any loss in diversity.
       Although the loss of diversity that might result were that owner to add a
       significant radio presence in the market in the market warrants a further
       50% limit in the number of radio properties that owner might hold, such is
       not the case if a combination does not include any television properties.

Id.¶ 467 (emphasis added).

       A newspaper/television duopoly combination realizes diminishing cross-

fertilization benefits in comparison to the combination of a newspaper and the first station

in television or radio. Therefore, it was reasonable for the Commission to disallow

newspaper/duopoly combinations even when the Diversity Index increase might be lower

than that for newspaper/television station/50% radio combinations. It was rational for the

                                             197
Commission to deviate from the Diversity Index in creating its Cross Media Limits. This

example highlights that the Cross Media Limits primarily address the impact of cross-

ownership on diversity, without ignoring other ownership goals like competition and

efficiency.124

        Furthermore, the first task of the Diversity Index was to identify at-risk markets,

then identify at-risk cross-ownership combinations. As the Commission commented:

        Using our diversity index analysis and our independent judgment regarding
        desired levels of diversity, we first identify ‘at-risk’ markets that might
        already be thought to be moderately concentrated for diversity purposes.
        We then identify the types of transactions that pose the greatest risk to
        diversity, and impose specific limits on those transactions in at-risk
        markets.

Id. ¶ 442
(emphasis added). The “horizontal” lines the Commission drew in its Cross

Media Limits, i.e., the lines between small and medium markets, and medium and large

markets, are supported by the Diversity Index results. See 
id. App. D.
I would not vacate

and remand an effective methodology because its results do not correspond to the

Commission’s final rule for all combinations in all markets.

        The majority focuses on the methodological choices behind the Diversity Index

and overlooks the end result—the Cross Media Limits. The Agency recognized the

Diversity Index to be “a blunt tool” that is neither “perfect nor absolutely precise.” 
Id. ¶¶ 392,
398. I see no reason to invalidate any aspect of the Commission’s Index. The Cross


  124
     The majority also criticizes the Commission’s decision to allow newspaper + 1 TV
station + 50% radio station combinations in light of their HHI increases. But this decision
is a matter within the sound discretion of the Commission’s line-drawing authority.

                                             198
Media Limits were the first structural change to the Commission’s Newspaper/Broadcast

Cross-Ownership Rule in nearly thirty years. The Diversity Index lent transparency and

empirical footing to this massive undertaking. In my view, it was reasonable for the

Agency, both in designing the Diversity Index and in its final Cross Media Limits, to rely

on a balanced, empirical approach that will, as a result of § 202(h), be subject to periodic

reexamination.

       4.     Notice

       On remand, the majority advises the Commission to cure its “questionable” notice

of the Diversity Index. This admonition goes beyond the notice requirements of the

Administrative Procedure Act. Under the APA, an agency must publish notice of either

the terms or substance of the proposed rule or a description of the subjects and issues

involved. 5 U.S.C. § 553(b)(3). The Commission provided notice and opportunity to

comment on the newspaper/broadcast cross-ownership rule in two separate notices of

proposed rulemaking. See Newspaper/Broadcast NPRM, 16 F.C.C.R. 17,283 (2001);

2002 Biennial NPRM, 17 F.C.C.R. 18,503 (2002). As the majority recognizes, the

Commission gave notice that it was considering “creating a new metric” to “reformulate

[its] mechanism for measuring diversity and competition in a market,” and that it was

contemplating “design[ing] a test that accords different weights to different outlet types.”

Notice, 17 F.C.C.R at 18,539-40 ¶¶ 113-115. In the Newspaper/Broadcast NPRM, the

Commission discussed at length questions regarding diversity and competition in relation

to the Newspaper/Broadcast Cross-Ownership Rule, posing questions for public comment

                                            199
such as: “Is it possible that the effect on diversity will be different depending on the size

of the markets involved, or the predominance of newspapers and broadcast stations in a

particular local market.” 16 F.C.C.R. at 17,292 ¶ 18. These and other statements in the

NPRM s adequately addressed the subject of the new Cross Ownership Rule.

        As an analytical tool that informed the Commission’s judgments about how to

account for diversity in different markets, and the need for ownership limits in these

markets, the Diversity Index itself was formulated as a response to comments.

“Rulemaking proceedings would never end if an agency’s response to comments must

always be made the subject of additional comments.” Cmty. Nutrition Inst. v. Block, 
749 F.2d 50
, 58 (D.C. Cir. 1984). 125 As the majority notes, formulas derived from comments

do not need to be re-noticed unless prejudice will result. 
Id. (“The response
may . . . take

the form of new scientific studies without entailing the procedural consequences

appellants would impose, unless prejudice is shown.”). The Diversity Index provided an

empirical foundation for formulating the final rule. The choices made in creating this

empirical model were within delegated agency authority and were supported by the

record. I do not find the alleged lack of notice to be prejudicial. Every methodological

choice will have proponents and detractors, but so long as the choices are not arbitrary

and capricious, they are valid. I would not expand the settled notice and comment


  125
    As noted, the complexity of the Commission’s rulemaking requires a lengthy
rulemaking cycle. 
See supra
p.132 n.91. The majority’s suggestion that the Diversity
Index required an additional round of notice and comment would unnecessarily extend,
and delay, the Commission’s § 202(h) review process.

                                             200
requirements of § 553.

B.         Local Television Ownership Rule

           The majority upholds the top-4 limit in the Local Television Ownership Rule but

vacates and remands the chosen numerical limits “for the Commission to harmonize

certain inconsistencies and better support its assumptions and rationale.” 126

           The FCC justified the specific numerical caps in its intra-service rules (radio and

television) by employing the Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission’s

“standard approach” to evaluating competitive harms of an increase in horizontal market

concentration: the Herfindalh-Hirshmann Index (HHI). The DOJ/FTC M erger

Guidelines recognize the HHI level of 1800 as the maximum level for “moderate”

concentration. So the FCC designed its local television rule to keep markets within the

1800 limit. Order ¶¶ 192-93. As noted, the FCC selected the upper bound for moderate

concentration, 1800, instead of the lower bound, 1000, in recognition of the competitive



     126
      The majority also vacates and remands the Commission’s repeal of the Failed Station
Solicitation Rule, 47 C.F.R. § 73.3555 n.7. In my view, the Commission adequately
supported its decision to repeal this rule noting, “the efficiencies associated with
operation of the two same-market stations, absent unusual circumstances, will always
result in the buyer being the owner of another station in that market.” Order ¶ 225. The
Commission’s explanation took account of the public interest, because a “failed, failing,
or unbuilt station” cannot contribute to localism, competition, or diversity. 
Id. The Commission
reasonably determined that repealing the solicitation rule in such
circumstances would serve the public interest by preventing the licensee’s assets from
“exit[ing] the market.” 
Id. The Commission
concluded “the public interest benefits of
activating a dark or unbuilt station, outweigh[] the potential harm to competition or
diversity.” 
Id. The Commission
’s explanation for the repeal of the FSSR demonstrates
that its decision was not arbitrary and capricious, and was in the public interest.

                                                201
pressures exerted by the cable networks. 
Id. ¶ 192.
       An HHI score of 1800 corresponds to having six equal-sized competitors in a

given market. This led the FCC, in part, to determine in markets of 18 stations or more,

an entity could own three stations, while in markets with 5 to 17 stations, an entity could

own two stations. 
Id. ¶ 193.
The Commission allowed ownership of two stations in

markets with less than 12 stations— though this undercuts its 6 equal-sized competitors

goal—because the economics of local broadcast stations justify slight increases in market

concentration as market size decreases. 
Id. ¶ 201.
The FCC relied on data from the

National Association of Broadcasters showing that small-market stations have a harder

time competing for revenue than stations in larger markets. Thus, the local television rule

represents a “graduated tradeoff between optimal competition in the delivered video

market (six station owners) and recognition of the challenging nature of broadcast

economics in small to mid-sized markets.” 
Id. ¶ 202.
       In developing the new local ownership tiers, the majority concludes the FCC failed

to justify its chosen numerical limits. The majority contends that allowing triopolies in

large markets does not ensure that six equal-sized competitors will emerge because the

FCC does not take into account existing respective audience shares among stations in a

given market. The majority also finds the FCC cannot cite “fluid” market share as a basis

for regulation yet, elsewhere in the same Order, use market share differentials as

justification for retaining the top-four restriction. The FCC found, for example, “a

general separation between the audience shares of the top four-ranked [local] stations and

                                            202
the audience shares of other stations in the market.” Order ¶ 195.127 Furthermore, the

majority finds the FCC did not cite empirical support for its “equal-sized firm”

assumption, and that its assumption of equal market shares, 
id. ¶ 134,
to derive its limits

ignores reality. The majority finds that by assuming equal market shares the FCC

allowed combinations based on unrealistic market percentages. It maintains the Agency

did not rely on market share, but on a rudimentary “head count” of outlets. According to

the majority, the inconsistent treatment of market share both within and between rules

renders them arbitrary and capricious.128

        In my view, the Commission justified its decision to assume equal market shares.

The majority states the Commission sought to “ensure that markets would not exceed the

Merger Guidelines’ 1800 threshold for highly competitive markets.” This statement

portrays a heavier reliance on the Merger Guidelines than the Commission avowed. In




  127
     The Commission instituted its top-four restriction in part due to the generally high
market shares of the top-four stations in many markets. But this was not the sole
justification for the rule. The Commission determined, “combinations involving the top
four-ranked stations are less likely to yield public interest benefits such as new or
expanded local news programming,” since “such stations are already originating local
news.” Order ¶ 198. The “[t]op four-ranked stations also are more likely to have made
the transition to DTV [digital television] than other stations.” 
Id. ¶ 199.
  128
      The majority cites the example of Philadelphia, where the duopoly owner Viacom
could acquire a third station and potentially increase its audience share from 25% to 34%.
According to the majority, such a merger would raise Philadelphia’s HHI score to 2487.
But this assumes there would be no competitive buyers for the television station. It also
fails to account for the antitrust review of proposed mergers by the Department of Justice.
 Finally, the proposed combination would still face competition from 12 commercial and
5 noncommercial television stations, as well as a host of additional media.

                                            203
discussing the relationship between its local television ownership limits and the Merger

Guidelines, the Commission said: “a strict, overly simplistic application of the DOJ/FTC

Merger Guidelines would potentially prohibit some welfare enhancing mergers and allow

some anticompetitive mergers . . . .” Order ¶ 193. The Commission also stated:

       The DOJ/FTC M erger Guidelines . . . are written not for a specific industry,
       but rather as guidelines intended for application across all industries. Our
       rules are formulated for a specific market—the delivery of video
       programming—and are based on an extensive record on the extent of
       competition in this market and the effect of our current local TV ownership
       rule. This record allows us to craft a more finely-tuned rule for this
       industry.

Id. ¶ 192.
So, in fact, the Commission did not seek to “ensure” that no market would

exceed the Merger Guidelines’ 1800 threshold for highly competitive markets. Instead

the Merger Guidelines provided a “starting point” from which the public interest dictated

the final rule. 
Id. The majority
finds that no evidence supports the Commission’s equal share

assumption. I disagree. The FCC found that a station’s market share is too fluid to use as

a basis for regulation, so its decision to regulate instead a firm’s “capacity” to deliver

programming is justified. 
Id. ¶ 193.
Because product innovation and program choice

vary with each season, a firm’s market share is more fluid than in other industries. Thus,

the FCC focused on a firm’s capacity to deliver programming. 
Id. Over the
life of a

firm’s investment in a station, and the duration of its license, the market breakdown can

shift substantially. For example, recently launched broadcast stations now vie with the

“big four” for viewers. See 
id. ¶ 110.
As recently as 1995, two new broadcast networks

                                             204
UPN and WB were launched and now both compete—often successfully—for viewers

with the “big four” networks. See e.g.,

http://www.viacom.com/prodbyunit1.tin?ixBusUnit=30 (discussing growing popularity of

UPN network) (last visited May 25, 2004); see also Comments of Paxson

Communications Corp., at 20 (noting retention of the UHF discount is “likely to

encourage the emergence of a larger number of competitive broadcast networks to join

the existing seven.”). The Merger Guidelines, which the Commission looked to in setting

its local license caps, contemplate the possibility that in instances where current revenue

market shares are misleading indicators of competitive performance, equal shares can be

imputed to each competitor. DOJ/FTC M erger Guidelines § 1.41 n.15 (“Where all firms

have, on a forward-looking basis, an equal likelihood of securing sales, the Agency will

assign firms equal shares.”).

         Moreover, the majority discounts the Commission’s assertion that local limits

contribute to the Agency’s diversity goals. “Ensuring that several competitors remain

within each of the radio and television services, we also ensure that a number of

independent outlets for viewpoint will remain in every local market, thereby ensuring that

our diversity goal will be promoted.” Order ¶ 129; see also 
id. ¶ 178.
Commentators

have recognized that outlets, or sources, should be counted equally in the marketplace of

ideas:

         I conclude that independently-owned outlets for, or sources of, ideas and
         information generally should each be counted equally as separate sellers in
         the marketplace of ideas, with response to the consumers whom they can

                                             205
       reach (or the consumers who can reach them), without regard to the
       classification or popularity of their current content.

Bruce M . Owen, Regulatory Reform, 2003 Mich. St. DCL L. Rev. at 696.

       Though not flawless in all markets, the Commission soundly justified its

assumption of equal market shares as underpinning for its choice of license limits in its

local television rule. In reviewing assumptions made by the Commission in a different

context, the D.C. Circuit recently wrote:

       These assumptions appear rational on the current record. We have no
       obvious way of verifying the FCC’s assertion regarding the general
       characteristics . . . We must defer to the Commission’s expert judgment in
       the absence of record evidence indicating that the Commission’s
       assumption is a clear error of judgment, or a showing that the empirical
       assumption is facially implausible or inconsistent.

Am. Family Ass’n, 
2004 U.S. App. LEXIS 9150
, at *21-22. In my view, the majority has

not shown error approaching this standard. As agency line-drawing deserves deference,

and the Commission’s choice of equal market shares is neither arbitrary and capricious, I

see no basis for overturning this decision.

C.     Local Radio Ownership Rule

       The majority supports the Commission’s use of numerical limits in the local radio

ownership rule but finds the Commission did not support its decision to retain the existing

numerical limits established by § 202(b). The majority also vacates and remands the

“five equal-sized firms” starting point, which undergirds the local radio rule, claiming the

Commission’s decision is not supported by “substantial evidence.” In light of § 202(h), I

agree that the Commission must explain its decision to maintain the existing limits. But I

                                              206
find the Commission to have justified its choices.

        First, in reaching its conclusion, the majority employs too high a standard. The

Commission’s conclusions do not need to be supported by “substantial evidence.”

Rather, the Commission’s line-drawing is generally not overturned “unless a petitioner

can demonstrate that the lines drawn . . . are patently unreasonable, having no relationship

to the underlying regulatory problem.” 
Sinclair, 284 F.3d at 162
(internal quotations

omitted). The Commission’s actions did not “run counter to the evidence before it,” 
id. (quoting Motor
Vehicles, 463 U.S. at 43
), and the Commission “provide[d] a reasoned

explanation for its action.” 
Id. As discussed,
the FCC maintained the radio tiers established by Congress in the

1996 Act. The FCC explained that retaining the existing tiers would result in five roughly

equal-sized firms in each market. Order ¶ 289. The Commission explained its ownership

rules ensure there will be roughly five or six owners in markets with between 27 and 51

radio stations, which should allow competitive market performance. Id.129 Citing

economic literature, the FCC found that five equal-sized firms ensure fragmented,

competitive markets. See 
id. ¶ 289
n.609. The FCC also concluded the current limits are

not overly-restrictive based on data showing the top four stations in each metro market

are thriving in terms of revenue and audience share. 
Id. ¶ 290.


  129
     Similar to the local television rule, the Commission acknowledged the limits allow
for more consolidation in smaller markets where the viability of stations may require
greater levels of concentration. Order ¶¶ 292-93.

                                            207
       The majority asserts the economic studies on which the FCC relied do not support

its premise that a market with five equal-sized competitors is comparable in terms of

market performance to a fragmented, structurally competitive market. See 
id. ¶ 289
n.

609 (citing R. Selter, A Simple Model of Imperfect Competition Where Four Are Few and

Six Are Many, 2 Int’l J. Game Theory 141 (1973); Louis Phillips, Competition Policy: A

Game Theory Perspective Ch. 2 (Cambridge U. Press 1995); Timothy F. Bresnahan &

Peter C. Reiss, Entry and Competition in Concentrated Markets, 99 J. Pol. Econ. 977-

1009 (1991). The majority contends the Commission failed to respond to petitions urging

market structures other than equal-sized competitors, which could provide equally

competitive markets. From the other direction, the majority picks up the argument of

Citizen Petitioners that the game-theory articles should not be followed because they

conflict with the most recent rewriting of the Merger Guidelines, which suggest a HHI

score above 1800 corresponds with a highly concentrated market. Merger Guidelines §

151(c).

       The Commission may favor a certain market structure if it reasonably supports its

decision. The Commission is the appropriate body to choose between various equally

competitive market structures when formulating its rules. See Am. Family Ass’n, 
2004 U.S. App. LEXIS 9150
, at *16 (“Given that both options are rational, the FCC’s choice of

means is well within its discretion.”). In structuring its rules, the Commission chose to




                                            208
take into account that radio audience shares change over time,130 and an evaluation of

radio market structure must also take into account that licenses provide radio stations with

the capacity, and likely the incentive, to provide more popular programming. See Order ¶

288. It would be irrational if a radio station did not provide more popular programming

because it would surpass its allotted market share.

        In determining appropriate ownership tiers, the Commission’s use of antitrust

theory tailored to the radio industry is reasonable. The Commission is not required to

strictly follow the Merger Guidelines in creating its limits. As the majority recognizes,

antitrust regulation and FCC ownership regulation play different roles.131 While the

majority may have struck the balance at a different point, the line was the Commission’s

to draw. 
Sinclair, 284 F.3d at 162
.

        The majority is not convinced by the Commission’s assertion that five equal-sized

competitors “would emerge or actually have emerged under numerical limits.” Certainly,

“radio station groups with similar numbers of radio stations [can] have vastly different

levels of market power.” Order ¶ 290. This assertion, however, does not require the

Commission to adopt a market structure that ignores its other finding—that station shares


  130
    
See supra
p. 198 & n.123 (discussing the increase of license transfers in the radio
industry).
  131
      The Commission need not rely identically on the Merger Guidelines in its television
and radio rules. The majority recognizes the rules need not mirror each other, but then
criticizes the Commission for not following the Merger Guidelines to the same extent in
both rules. As the majority notes, radio markets may be different, in part, due to the
greater number of available stations in most markets.

                                            209
can be fluid. Additionally, as discussed in relation to the Local Television Ownership

Rule, an assumption of equal shares makes sense in terms of diversity, as each station has

the capability of disseminating information. As the local ownership rules support the

Commission’s diversity objectives as well, equal shares are reasonable, and clearly not

arbitrary and capricious. See 
id. ¶ 306
(“Our competition-based limits on local radio

ownership thus promote viewpoint diversity, not only ensuring a sufficient number of

independent radio voices, but also by preserving a market structure that facilitates and

encourages entry in the local media market by new and under-represented parties.”)

       The majority finds the Commission “does not explain why it could not take actual

market share into account when deriving the numerical limits.” But in its Order, the

Commission wrote:

       We also reject arguments that we incorporate a market share analysis into
       the local radio ownership rule or that we continue to ‘flag’ applications that
       propose radio station combinations above a certain market share . . . .
       Market share, however, must be considered in conjunction with the overall
       structure of the industry in determining whether market power is present.
       In radio, the availability of a sufficient number of radio channels is of
       particular importance in ensuring that competition can flourish in local
       radio markets. The numerical caps and the AM/FM service limits are
       designed to address that interest, and in our judgment, establishing a
       inflexible market share limit in our bright-line rule would add little, if any,
       benefit. We do not seek to discourage radio firms from earning market
       share through investment in quality programming that listeners prefer; our
       objective is to prevent firms from gaining market dominance through the
       consolidation of a significant number of key broadcast facilities. We do not
       believe that developing a market share limit would significantly advance
       that objective.

Order ¶ 300 (emphasis added).


                                             210
       The majority also points out the Commission has previously looked to market

share for measuring diversity and competition in local radio markets. Again, the

Commission expressly addressed its change in policy when it wrote:

       We recognize that our conclusion differs from the Commission's view in
       1992 that an audience share cap was necessary “to prevent consolidation of
       the top stations in a particular local market.” But the audience share cap
       was never intended to be more than a “backstop” to the new numerical
       limits the Commission had established, which for the first time allowed a
       party to own multiple radio stations in a local market. The audience share
       cap was eliminated as a result of the revisions to the local radio ownership
       rule that Congress mandated in the 1996 Act, which left only the numerical
       caps in place. But because of the problems associated with the contour-
       overlap market definition and counting methodologies, we could not rely
       with confidence on those numerical limits to protect against undue
       concentration in local markets. As a result, we began looking at revenue
       share in our "flagging" process and the interim policy that we established in
       the Local Radio Ownership NPRM. Now that we have established a
       rational system for defining radio markets and counting market participants,
       we believe that the numerical limits will be better able to protect against
       harmful concentration levels in local radio markets that might otherwise
       threaten the public interest.

Order ¶ 301. As noted, the Commission based its switch to the Arbitron Metro market

definition—which the majority affirms—in part, on the difficulty of guarding against

undue consolidation of market share under the old contour-overlap method. See Order ¶

257 (“[T]he contour-overlap system actually encourages consolidation of powerful radio

stations because stations with larger signal contours are more likely to create larger radio

markets, which make it more likely that a party would be able to acquire additional radio

stations in that market.”). With a more rational market definition, which, according to the

Commission, will make consolidation less likely, it was not arbitrary or capricious for the


                                            211
Commission to de-emphasize market share in crafting its ownership limits.

        In order to warrant judicial deference, an agency’s line-drawing decision must be

justified by a reasonable explanation and cannot run counter to the evidence. 
Sinclair, 284 F.3d at 162
; see also 
NCCB, 436 U.S. at 814
–15. No record evidence invalidates the

policy choices made by the Commission. Its assumptions and chosen limits correspond to

a reasonable market structure for radio programming markets. 132

        The Supreme Court has upheld FCC policy based on factual determinations “that

were primarily of judgmental or predictive nature.” 
NCCB, 436 U.S. at 814
(noting

“complete factual support is not possible or required; ‘a forecast of the direction in which

future public interest lies necessarily involves deductions based on the expert knowledge

of the agency’”) (quoting FPC v. Transcontinental Gas Pipe Line 
Corp., 365 U.S. at 29
).

I do not find § 202(h), or any other directive to the Agency, to require the Commission to

ignore its well-informed predictions about which types of markets best foster its public

interest goals, and consequently to create rules with these markets in mind.


  132
     The majority also finds the Commission failed to justify its retention of an AM
subcap. Order ¶ 294. I believe the Commission adequately supported the sub-caps. The
Commission explained that AM and FM stations have different technological
characteristics as well as different programming formats (AM stations often have
news/talk/sports or ethnic formats). 
Id. The Commission
originally adopted specific AM
and FM ownership limits in order to “prevent one entity from putting together a powerful
combination of stations in a single service that may enjoy an advantage over stations in a
different service.” Revision of Radio Rules and Policies, 7 F.C.C.R. 2755, 2778 ¶ 44.
The same rationale survives today. A limit on AM station ownership will continue to
create more robust competition within that frequency. Because, as the Commission
explained, the AM frequency is its own sub-market, ensuring competition in this
frequency is consistent with the public interest.

                                            212
                                   V.

For the foregoing reasons, I would affirm the Commission’s rules.




                                   213

Source:  CourtListener

Can't find what you're looking for?

Post a free question on our public forum.
Ask a Question
Search for lawyers by practice areas.
Find a Lawyer