JESSE M. FURMAN, District Judge:
In 2014, author Michael Lewis published a bestselling book titled Flash Boys: A Wall Street Revolt, in which he argued that "high-frequency traders" have been able to gain an unfair advantage in the stock market, in part because stock exchanges and "dark pools" — alternative venues for trading stocks — have enabled those traders to obtain and trade on market data faster than other investors. A litany of lawsuits followed in short succession, asserting various theories of liability. See, e.g., Lanier v. BATS Exchange, Inc., 105 F.Supp.3d 353, No. 14-CV-3745 (KBF), 2015 WL 1914446 (S.D.N.Y. Apr. 28, 2015) (state-law claims against various stock exchanges); Strougo v. Barclays PLC, 105 F.Supp.3d 330, No. 14-CV-5797 (SAS), 2015 WL 1883201 (S.D.N.Y. Apr. 24, 2015) (investor suit against the operator of a major dark pool); People ex rel. Schneiderman v. Barclays Capital Inc., 47 Misc.3d 862, 1 N.Y.S.3d 910 (N.Y.Sup.Ct. 2015) (state-law claims against the operator of a major dark pool). This multidistrict litigation ("MDL") proceeding involves a group of cases in that litany. In four cases, originally filed in this District, various investors (collectively, the "SDNY Plaintiffs") bring claims under the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 ("the Exchange Act"), 15 U.S.C. § 78a et seq., against seven stock exchanges — BATS Global Markets, Inc., Chicago Stock Exchange, Inc., Direct Edge ECN, LLC, the NASDAQ Stock Market LLC, NASDAQ OMX BX, Inc., New York Stock Exchange, LLC, and NYSE Area, Inc. (collectively, "the Exchanges") — as well as Barclays PLC and Barclays Capital Inc. (collectively, "Barclays"), a major financial institution and the subsidiary that operates its "dark pool." In a fifth action, Docket Number 15-CV-168, filed in the United States District Court for the Central District of California and later consolidated here by the Judicial Panel on Multidistrict Litigation
Now pending are three motions by Defendants, largely pursuant to Rule 12(b)(6) of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure, to dismiss the claims of Plaintiffs in all five cases (collectively, "Plaintiffs"). Significantly, the motions do not call upon the Court to wade into the larger public debates regarding high-frequency trading or the fairness of the U.S. stock markets more generally. That is, Lewis's book may well highlight inequities in the structure of the Nation's financial system and the desirability for, or necessity of, reform. For the most part, however, those questions are not for the courts, but for commentators, private and semi-public entities (including the stock exchanges), and the political branches of government, which — as Plaintiffs themselves observe — have already taken up the issue. (See Second Consol. Am. Compl. Violation Federal Securities Laws (14-CV-2811, Docket No. 252 ("SAC") ¶¶ 280-89 (describing investigations related to high-frequency trading by the United States Congress, the Federal Bureau of Investigation, the Department of Justice, the Commodity Futures Trading Commission, and the Securities and Exchange Commission)); Am. Class Action Compl. (15-CV168, Docket No. 30) ("Am. Compl.") ¶ 5 (describing actions taken by the New York Attorney General)). More to the point, the only question for this Court on these motions is whether the Complaints in these cases are legally sufficient to survive Defendants' motions. Applying well-established precedent from the United States Supreme Court, the United States Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit, and the California Supreme Court, the Court is compelled to conclude that they are not. Accordingly, and for the reasons stated below, Defendants' motions to dismiss are granted, although Great Pacific is granted leave to amend its complaint in 15-CV-168.
Generally, in considering a Rule 12(b)(6) motion, a court is limited to the facts alleged in the complaint and is required to accept those facts as true. See, e.g., LaFaro v. N.Y. Cardiothoracic Grp., PLLC, 570 F.3d 471, 475 (2d Cir.2009). A court may, however, consider documents attached to the complaint, statements or documents incorporated into the complaint by reference, matters of which judicial notice may be taken, public records, and documents that the plaintiff either possessed or knew about, and relied upon, in bringing suit. See, e.g., Kleinman v. Elan Corp., 706 F.3d 145, 152 (2d Cir.2013); Chambers v. Time Warner, Inc., 282 F.3d 147, 153 (2d Cir.2002). Thus, the following facts are taken from the relevant Complaints, exhibits attached thereto, and documents of which the Court may take judicial notice.
Prior to 1975, the U.S. stock market was fragmented among several stock exchanges. (SAC ¶ 43-44). In general, investors seeking to purchase a stock on a particular exchange interacted only with investors also trading on that exchange, and stocks were often traded at different prices on different exchanges. (See id. ¶ 43). In 1975, Congress amended the Exchange Act to, among other things, give the Securities and Exchange Commission ("SEC") authority to issue rules that would stitch the disparate exchanges into a single national market. See Pub.L. No. 94-29, § 7, 89 Stat. 111, codified at 15 U.S.C. § 78k-1. (SAC ¶ 44). Since those amendments, the SEC has enacted a host of regulations to fulfill Congress's vision of a unified national stock market. In 2005,
A consolidated feed includes information on (1) the price at which the latest sale of each stock traded on the exchanges occurred, the size of that sale, and the exchange on which it took place; (2) the current highest bid and lowest offer for each stock traded on the exchanges, along with the number of shares available at those prices; and (3) the "national best bid and offer," or "NBBO," which are the highest bid and lowest offer currently available across all the exchanges and the exchange or exchanges on which those prices are available. See NetCoalition v. SEC, 615 F.3d 525, 529 (D.C.Cir.2010), superseded by statute on other grounds, Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, Pub.L. No. 111-203, 124 Stat. 1376 (2010), as recognized in NetCoalition v. SEC, 715 F.3d 342 (D.C.Cir.2013); see also 17 C.F.R. § 242.600(b)(13). Regulation NMS also requires that exchanges and brokers immediately accept the most competitive offer for a particular stock when matching a buyer to a seller — meaning that, in theory, the NBBO for a particular stock is the price at which that stock should trade. See Regulation NMS, 70 Fed.Reg. at 37,501-02. (SAC ¶ 48). The consolidated feed effectively transforms the disparate exchanges into a single national market. After all, at any given point, an entity seeking to trade a stock should be able to identify the best available price on any of the registered exchanges and send its order to that exchange for execution. In theory, it no longer matters if that entity is located on Wall Street, while the best available offer is from a party in Chicago.
In 1998, in response to the growth of trading over electronic platforms and other emerging technologies, the SEC authorized electronic platforms to register as national exchanges. See Regulation of Exchanges and Alternative Trading Systems, SEC Release No. 34-40760, 63 Fed.Reg. 70844 (Dec. 22, 1998) ("Regulation ATS"). In the nearly two decades since then, and especially since the SEC enacted Regulation NMS, the stock markets have witnessed a dramatic rise in high-frequency trading ("HFT"). (SAC ¶¶ 66-69). Although there is no definitive definition of what constitutes HFT, the term generally refers to the practice of using computer-driven algorithms to rapidly move in and out of stock positions, making money by arbitraging small differences in stock prices — often across different exchanges — rather than by holding the stocks for an appreciable period of time. See, e.g., Strougo v. Barclays PLC, 105 F.Supp.3d 330, 336, No. 14-CV-5797 (SAS), 2015 WL 1883201, at *2 (S.D.N.Y. Apr. 24, 2015). (Accord SAC ¶¶ 66, 69). To enable them to engage in that arbitrage, high-frequency
The effects of HFT on the stock market are the subject of some controversy. Some commentators and, at points, the SEC, have stated that HFT firms have a positive effect on the market by creating significant amounts of liquidity, thereby permitting the national stock market to operate more efficiently and benefitting ordinary investors (including Plaintiffs). See, e.g., Regulation NMS, 70 Fed.Reg. at 37,500 ("Short-term traders clearly provide valuable liquidity to the market."). Others have sharply criticized the HFT firms' trading practices. Chief among their criticisms — and one that Plaintiffs forcefully adopt in their filings before the Court — is that the HFT firms use the speed at which they are capable of trading to identify the trading strategies being pursued by ordinary investors and react in a manner that forces ordinary investors to trade at a less advantageous price, with the HFT firm taking as profit a portion of the "delta" — that is, the difference between the price at which the ordinary investor would have traded and the price at which it actually traded as a result of the HFT firm's actions. For that reason, opponents of HFT, including Plaintiffs, often describe them as "predatory" or "toxic" trading strategies. More specifically, and as discussed further below, Plaintiffs allege that Defendants have provided the ingredients necessary for HFT firms to execute their predatory trading strategies and thereby enabled the HFT firms to exploit ordinary — that is, non-HFT — investors. (SAC ¶¶ 71-72). It is to those Defendants that the Court now turns.
The primary Defendants in this case — the Exchanges — are all self-regulatory organizations ("SROs") within the meaning of the Exchange Act. See 15 U.S.C. § 78c(a)(26) (defining SRO). (SAC ¶¶ 26-33). They are registered with the SEC pursuant to Section 6(a) of the Exchange Act, and they have developed and operate platforms on which an entity seeking to purchase a stock can be matched with an entity seeking to sell that same stock. See 15 U.S.C. § 78f; id. § 78c(a)(1). SROs are private entities that exercise regulatory authority delegated to them by the SEC, subject to "extensive" SEC regulation. See Lanier, 105 F.Supp.3d at 363, 2015 WL 1914446, at *8; see also DL Capital Grp., LLC v. Nasdaq Stock Mkt., Inc., 409 F.3d 93, 95 (2d Cir.2005) (explaining an SRO's regulatory authority). The Exchanges remain SROs even though they are now for-profit corporations, a status that the SEC authorized in 1998. See Regulation ATS, 63 Fed.Reg. at 70882-84; Domestic Sec., Inc. v. SEC, 333 F.3d 239, 243 (D.C.Cir.2003) (discussing Regulation ATS). (SAC ¶ 290).
The Exchanges make commissions off the trades placed on their platforms, meaning that the number of orders that are executed on an Exchange has a significant bearing on that Exchange's revenue. (See id. ¶ 49). Accordingly, the SDNY Plaintiffs allege (and it is hard to dispute) that each Exchange has an incentive to
The first feature involves the Exchanges' provision of "enhanced" or "proprietary" data feeds. These data feeds contain much of the same information that the Exchanges transmit to the Processor for inclusion in the consolidated feed, although in some instances they also provide additional or more detailed information regarding trading activity on the exchanges. (Id. ¶ 126). In addition, the data in the proprietary feeds are transmitted directly from an Exchange to the proprietary feed's subscribers. (Id. ¶ 118). See Exchange Act Release No. 34-67857, 2012 WL 4044880, at *2 (Sept. 14, 2012). By regulation, the Exchanges are not permitted to transmit the information in the proprietary feed any earlier than they transmit the information to the Processor for integration into the consolidated feed. See Exchange Act Release No. 34-67857, 2012 WL 4044880, at *8 (requiring the Exchanges to take "reasonable steps to ensure... that ... data relating to current best-priced quotations and trades through proprietary feeds [are released] no sooner than ... data [sent] to the ... Processor" for integration into the consolidated feed). But because the proprietary feed is transmitted directly from an exchange to a subscriber, and does not have to be integrated with information from other exchanges, it is typically delivered to subscribers before the same information is transmitted via the consolidated feed. (Cf. SAC ¶ 118). Applications to establish proprietary feeds are reviewed by the SEC, and the SEC has approved various such applications. See, e.g., Exchange Act Release No. 34-59606, 74 Fed.Reg. 13,293 (Mar. 26, 2009). In fact, Plaintiffs do not appear to dispute that the proprietary feeds at issue in this case were approved by the SEC.
The second practice or feature at issue involves allowing high-frequency traders the option of installing their servers at, or extremely close to, the servers used to operate the Exchanges. (SAC ¶ 108). This practice, known as "co-location," has the effect of shaving fractions of a second off the time it takes for a trader's server to interact with the Exchange's servers. (Id. ¶ 108-10). As with the proprietary feeds, applications are reviewed by the SEC, and the SEC has found such applications consistent with the Exchange Act. See Exchange Act Release No. 34-62961, 75 Fed. Reg. 59,299 (Sept. 27, 2010). Again, Plaintiffs do not appear to dispute that the co-locations at issue in this case were approved by the SEC.
The third and final feature at issue in this case is the Exchanges' creation of "hundreds" of complex order types. (SAC ¶ 142). An order type is a "preprogrammed command[]" that "traders use to tell exchanges how to handle their bids
Regulation NMS also contributed to the development of a series of alternative trading venues known as "dark pools." In contrast to the "lit" Exchanges — i.e., those that are required by to SEC to publish the best bid and offer available via the consolidated feed — dark pools are not required to publish transaction information until after the transaction closes, hence the reason they are called "dark" pools. (Id. ¶¶ 55-56). In theory, dark pools make it easier for a trader to purchase or sell large quantities of stock without moving the market or otherwise alerting other traders to its plans. (Id. ¶¶ 57, 60; Am. Compl. ¶ 19). Regulation NMS permitted investors to bypass the Exchanges and execute trades in a dark pool when the dark pool offered a more favorable price. (Id. ¶ 20). The ability to compete with the Exchanges on price evidently created a significant opportunity for dark pools to increase trading volume and, as a result, revenue.
Barclays, like most major financial institutions, operates a dark pool, known as "Barclays LX." (Id. ¶¶ 257, 259). As with the Exchanges, Barclays's dark pool generates revenue based in large part on the volume of trading. (SDNY Pls.' Mem. 13). And as with the Exchanges, HFT firms provide a significant source of potential trading volume and, therefore, revenue for Barclays LX. (Lead Pls.' Omnibus Mem. Law Opp'n Defs.' Mots. To Dismiss (14-MD-2589, Docket No. 26) ("SDNY Pls.' Mem.") 13; SAC ¶ 59). Plaintiffs contend that, by providing proprietary feeds and co-location services at prices that only HFT firms could afford, Barclays set out to capture this trading volume by rigging its dark pool in favor of the HFT firms. (See, e.g., id. ¶ 275; SDNY Pls.' Mem. 14). Apparently recognizing that ordinary investors might refuse to trade in a dark pool rigged in favor of "predatory" HFT firms, however, Barclays also marketed its dark pool to ordinary investors as a "safe" place for them to trade, with very little aggressive HFT trading. (SAC ¶¶ 268-74; Am. Compl. ¶¶ 4, 32, 34-35). Additionally, Barclays introduced a service called Liquidity Profiling, through which Barclays categorized firms using the dark pool as either aggressive, neutral, or passive, and
In evaluating a motion to dismiss pursuant to Rule 12(b)(6), a court must accept all facts set forth in the complaint as true and draw all reasonable inferences in the plaintiff's favor. See, e.g., Burch v. Pioneer Credit Recovery, Inc., 551 F.3d 122, 124 (2d Cir.2008) (per curiam). Significantly, however, the Supreme Court has made clear that a court should not accept non-factual matter or "conclusory statements" set forth in a complaint as true. See Ashcroft v. Iqbal, 556 U.S. 662, 686, 129 S.Ct. 1937, 173 L.Ed.2d 868 (2009). Instead, a court must follow a two-step approach in assessing the sufficiency of a complaint in the face of a Rule 12(b)(6) motion. See id. at 680-81, 129 S.Ct. 1937. First, the court must distinguish between facts, on the one hand, and "mere conclusory statements" or legal conclusions on the other hand; whereas the former are entitled to the presumption of truth, the latter are not and must be disregarded. See id. at 678-79, 129 S.Ct. 1937. Second, the court must "consider the factual allegations in [the] complaint to determine if they plausibly suggest an entitlement to relief." Id. at 681, 129 S.Ct. 1937. A claim is facially plausible "when the plaintiff pleads factual content that allows the court to draw the reasonable inference that the defendant is liable for the misconduct alleged." Id. at 678, 129 S.Ct. 1937 (citing Bell Atl. Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544, 556, 127 S.Ct. 1955, 167 L.Ed.2d 929 (2007)). A plaintiff must show "more than a sheer possibility that a defendant acted unlawfully," id., and cannot rely on mere "labels and conclusions" to support a claim, Twombly, 550 U.S. at 555, 127 S.Ct. 1955. If the plaintiff's pleadings "have not nudged [his or her] claims across the line from conceivable to plausible, [the] complaint must be dismissed." Id. at 570, 127 S.Ct. 1955.
The SDNY Plaintiffs contend that the Exchanges violated the Exchange Act by engaging in a manipulative scheme in which they enabled HFT firms to exploit ordinary investors trading on the Exchanges in return for which the HFT firms directed their considerable trading activity to the Exchanges. (SDNY Pls.' Mem. 7-8). The essence of the alleged scheme is as follows. Motivated by the need to increase trading volume, and therefore revenue, and recognizing that the HFT firms represented a large — and growing — share of total trading volume, the Exchanges began "catering" their business operations to the needs of the HFT firms. (Id. at 6-7). Specifically, they began offering products, such as proprietary feeds and co-location, whose primary value was to shave minute fractions of a second off the time it takes to receive and respond to information from the Exchanges. (Id. at 8-10). Such services are valuable only to HFT firms, as only they stand to profit from very small decreases in the time it takes to respond to information regarding activity on the Exchanges; in any case, the Exchanges priced the services at such "exorbitantly high" rates that they were worthwhile only for HFT firms and thus "de facto" limited
Through these actions, the Exchanges enabled the HFT firms to amass a significant speed advantage over ordinary investors and to employ trading strategies that exploited that speed advantage to the detriment of ordinary investors. The SAC details the various strategies that HFT firms used to exploit Plaintiffs as a result of this scheme. The specifics of those strategies are not relevant here. Instead, it suffices to say that each of the strategies depended on the HFT firms' ability to recognize Plaintiffs' trading behavior and, in a fraction of a second, react to that behavior in a manner that permitted the HFT firms to trade ahead of Plaintiffs, thereby making a small profit and causing Plaintiffs to trade at less favorable prices than they would have otherwise. (SAC ¶¶ 237-251). In enabling the HFT firms to execute those strategies, the SDNY Plaintiffs allege, the Exchanges' actions "rigged the[] markets in favor of HFT firms." (SDNY Pls.' Mem. 7).
As a threshold matter, the Court must briefly address the Exchanges' argument that the Court lacks subject-matter jurisdiction over the SDNY Plaintiff's claims. See Steel Co. v. Citizens for a Better Env't, 523 U.S. 83, 93-102, 118 S.Ct. 1003, 140 L.Ed.2d 210 (1998) (holding that the Court may not assume subject-matter jurisdiction and resolve a case on the merits). The Exchanges contend that the Court lacks subject-matter jurisdiction because the Exchange Act creates a comprehensive regulatory scheme pursuant to which claims based on actions by the Exchanges must be presented first to the SEC, with any appeal of the SEC's decision going directly to the Court of Appeals. (Exchanges' Mem. 17-24). That argument, however, is unpersuasive. The SDNY Plaintiffs allege that the Exchanges operated their business in a manner that ran afoul of the federal securities laws, violations of which are typically redressable in federal district court. Put simply, the question of whether Section 10(b) reaches the Exchanges' conduct goes to the merits of the SDNY Plaintiffs' claims and does not implicate the Court's authority to hear the case. Cf. Morrison v. Nat'l Australia Bank Ltd., 561 U.S. 247, 254, 130 S.Ct. 2869, 177 L.Ed.2d 535 (2010) (holding that the question of "what conduct § 10(b) reaches" is a "merits question," not one that goes to subject-matter jurisdiction).
The cases upon which the Exchanges rely do not call for a contrary conclusion. First, the Exchanges rely on cases involving questions of preemption. (Reply Mem. Law Supp. Exchanges' Mot. To Dismiss Second Consol. Am. Compl. Pursuant Fed.R.Civ.P. 12(b)(1) and 12(b)(6) (14-MD-2589, Docket No. 28) ("Exchanges' Reply Mem.") 3 (citing, e.g., Lanier, 105 F.Supp.3d at 365, 2015 WL 1914446, at *10)). The question of whether the "structure of the Exchange Act" displaces claims under Section 10(b), however, is an issue of preclusion, not preemption, as it involves the interaction of different provisions of federal law. See POM Wonderful LLC v. Coca-Cola Co., ___ U.S. ___, 134 S.Ct. 2228, 2236, 189 L.Ed.2d 141 (2014). Second, the Exchanges cite cases in which a party was appealing from a decision by the
Next, the Exchanges argue that, even if the Court has jurisdiction, Plaintiffs' claims are barred by the doctrine of absolute immunity. (See Exchanges' Mem. 24-36). It is well established "that an SRO and its officers are entitled to absolute immunity from private damages suits in connection with the discharge of their regulatory responsibilities." Standard Inv. Chartered, Inc. v. Nat'l Ass'n of Sec. Dealers, Inc., 637 F.3d 112, 115 (2d Cir.2011) (quoting DL Capital Grp., 409 F.3d at 96). That is because the Exchanges "perform[] a variety of regulatory functions that would, in other circumstances, be performed by the SEC — an agency [that] is accorded sovereign immunity from all suits for money damages." DL Capital Grp., 409 F.3d at 97. Thus, "in light of [the Exchanges'] special status and connection to the SEC," they are, "out of fairness[,]... accorded full immunity from suits for money damages" when taking action pursuant to this special status. Id. (internal quotation marks omitted).
As in other contexts, absolute immunity provides an SRO with "protection not only from liability, but also from the burdens of litigation, including discovery, and should be `resolved at the earliest possible stage in litigation.'" In re Facebook, Inc., IPO Sec. & Derivative Litig.,
Significantly, the motive or reasonableness of the actions in question is irrelevant to the analysis. See, e.g., id. at 95-96; accord Bogan v. Scott-Harris, 523 U.S. 44, 54, 118 S.Ct. 966, 140 L.Ed.2d 79 (1998) (holding that whether a government official is absolutely immune "turns on the nature of the act, rather than on the [official's] motive or intent"). Instead, "the decision to extend absolute immunity depends `upon the nature of the governmental function being performed.'" DL Capital Grp., 409 F.3d at 99 n. 4 (quoting D'Alessio, 258 F.3d at 104-05). Thus, the fact that the Exchanges in this case are now for-profit corporations does not, by itself, deprive them of absolute immunity. See, e.g., id.; cf. NYSE Specialists, 503 F.3d at 91 & n. 1 (holding that the defendant exchange was entitled to absolute immunity even though it was "no longer a nonprofit corporation, following a merger which commenced after the filing of [the] lawsuit"). For similar reasons, and as the SDNY Plaintiffs conceded at oral argument (Tr. 33-34), it does not matter if an Exchange, in performing a regulatory function, is also motivated by the desire for profit or some other business purpose. Cf. Weissman v. Nat'l Ass'n of Sec. Dealers, 500 F.3d 1293, 1298-99 (11th Cir.2007) (holding that an SRO is not protected by absolute immunity for actions that have no regulatory dimension and relate solely to the SRO's business interests). Instead, the sole question is whether the alleged misconduct falls within the scope of the quasi-governmental powers delegated to the Exchanges — in which case absolute immunity applies — or outside the scope of those powers — in which case it does not. (See Exchanges' Reply Mem. 7 ("[A]bsolute immunity applies to SRO activities that are incident to their regulatory functions, but not to exclusively non-regulatory functions.")).
With those standards in mind, the Court turns to the three practices of the Exchanges that the SDNY Plaintiffs challenge in this case: co-location services, the proprietary data feeds, and complex order types. (See SDNY Pls.' Mem. 7-11). Whether absolute immunity applies to the provision of co-location services is easily answered. It does not. Notably, although the Exchanges frame absolute immunity as a dispositive defense with respect to all of the SDNY Plaintiffs' claims (see Exchanges' Mem. 29 (stating that "the Exchanges' immunity for proprietary feeds and co-location is dispositive"), their memorandum
By contrast, the Exchanges are absolutely immune for their creation of complex order types. As noted, the order types permitted by an Exchange define the ways in which traders can interact with that Exchange. See Exchange Act Release No. 34-74032, 2015 WL 137640, at *2 ("Order types are the primary means by which market participants communicate their instructions for the handling of their orders to the exchange."). By establishing a defined set of order types, the Exchanges police the ways in which users of an exchange are able to interact with each other. See id. In so doing, the order types establish a framework by which buyers of stocks are matched with sellers. The creation of new order types — including complex ones — thus plainly "relates to the proper functioning of the regulatory system," for which the Exchanges enjoy absolute immunity. NYSE Specialists, 503 F.3d at 96 (quoting D'Alessio, 258 F.3d at 106); see also DL Capital Grp., 409 F.3d at 95 (stating that the "regulatory powers and responsibilities" that Congress delegated to stock exchanges include the duty "to develop, operate, and maintain" their markets, "to formulate regulatory policies and listing criteria" for the markets, "and to enforce those policies and rules, subject to the approval of ... the SEC"). It is thus unsurprising that new or modified order types are among the Exchanges' rules that the SEC reviews under Exchange Act Section 6(b), 15 U.S.C. § 78f(b), to ensure that they, among other things, prevent "fraudulent and manipulative acts and practices." See, e.g., Exchange Act Release No. 34-69419, 78 Fed. Reg. 24,449, 24,453 (Apr. 25, 2013); Exchange Act Release No. 34-63777, 76 Fed. Reg. 5630, 5634 (Feb. 1, 2011).
In arguing to the contrary, the SDNY Plaintiffs contend that the complex order types at issue are "outside of [the Exchanges'] capacity as SROs" because they were created for business purposes and at the request of the HFT firms. (SDNY Pls.' Mem. 37-38). Relatedly, they assert that the complex order types are "products" and that the Exchanges do not have immunity for the development of a product. (Tr. 32). These contentions, however, amount to little more than an argument that the Exchanges should be denied absolute immunity because they acted with an improper motive — whether it be to profit or to satisfy the HFT firms (and thereby, presumably, profit). But, as noted, motive is irrelevant to the absolute immunity question. See DL Capital Grp., 409 F.3d at 98 ("[A]bsolute immunity spares the official any scrutiny of his [or her] motives...." (internal quotation marks omitted)).
The final challenged feature of the Exchanges — their provision of proprietary data feeds — is a closer call, but also falls within the scope of the quasi-governmental powers delegated to the Exchanges.
In arguing otherwise, the SDNY Plaintiffs rely again on the alleged profit motives of the Exchanges. (SDNY Pls.' Mem. 33). As discussed above, however, the immunity analysis turns solely on the nature of the conduct at issue; motive is irrelevant. See NYSE Specialists, 503 F.3d at 98 n. 3; DL Capital Grp., 409 F.3d at 98. The SDNY Plaintiffs also emphasize that the proprietary data feeds are not mandated by the SEC and that their information is determined by the market rather than the SEC. (SDNY Pls.' Mem. 33-34). But that does not render them entirely non-regulatory in nature. The SEC has concluded that, although it could regulate the content of proprietary data feeds, Congress wanted as much of the regulatory regime as possible dictated by the market rather than regulatory fiat. See Exchange Act Release No. 34-59039, 73 Fed.Reg. 74,770, 74,771 (Dec. 9, 2008); see also Regulation NMS, 70 Fed.Reg. at 37,566-68. There is no reason to conclude that the SEC's choice of regulatory paradigm —
The cases cited by the SDNY Plaintiffs do not require a contrary conclusion. In each of those cases, the Court concluded that the relevant exchange's conduct was entirely non-regulatory; that is, the action in question had only a business purposes and was not taken pursuant to any delegated or quasi-governmental authority. See Weissman, 500 F.3d at 1299 (concluding that there was "no quasi-governmental function served by ... advertisements" promoting a particular equity traded on an exchange); Facebook, 986 F.Supp.2d at 452 (concluding that NASDAQ was not immune for a negligence claim based on the malfunction of its software because "[t]here are no immunized or statutorily delegated government powers to design,... to ... test ... or to fix computer software when it is malfunctioning"); Opulent Fund, 2007 WL 3010573, at *5 (holding that NASDAQ is not immune for creating an index of stocks and promoting the index in order facilitate the development of derivative trading on its exchange). By contrast, the dissemination of data regarding trades — whether through the proprietary data feeds or the consolidated feed — is not exclusively non-regulatory in nature.
In sum, the Court concludes that the Exchanges are absolutely immune from suit based on their creation of complex order types and provision of proprietary data feeds, both of which fall within the scope of the quasi-governmental powers delegated to the Exchanges. That conclusion is reinforced by the fact that the SEC has ample authority and ability to regulate those activities and address any improprieties by the Exchanges; the Second Circuit has instructed that a court evaluating a claim of absolute immunity should "consider `whether there exist alternatives to
Even if the Exchanges were not absolutely immune from suit for much of the conduct at issue in these cases, the SDNY Plaintiffs' Complaints would be subject to dismissal for failure to state a claim. As noted, the Complaints plead two sets of claims: one set of claims under Section 10(b) of the Exchange Act and Rule 10b-5, which make it unlawful "[t]o use or employ, in connection with the purchase or sale of any security[,] ... any manipulative or deceptive device or contrivance in contravention of ... rules and regulations" promulgated by the SEC, 15 U.S.C. § 78j(b); and a second set of claims under Section 6(b) of the Exchange Act, which requires the Exchanges to adopt rules and regulations that, among other things, "prevent fraudulent and manipulative acts and practices" and to abide by those rules and regulations, 15 U.S.C. § 78f(b). The Court will address each set of claims in turn.
First, the SNDY Plaintiffs bring a manipulative-scheme claim under Section 10(b) and Rule 10b-5(a) and (c). (SDNY Pls.' Mem. 48-61). As noted, Section 10(b) makes it unlawful "[t]o use or employ, in connection with the purchase or sale of any security, any manipulative or deceptive device or contrivance in contravention of such rules and regulations as the Commission may prescribe as necessary or appropriate in the public interest or for the protection of investors." Employees' Ret. Sys. of Gov't of the Virgin Islands v. Blanford, 794 F.3d 297, 304-05 (2d Cir.2015) (quoting 15 U.S.C. § 78j(b)). To state a manipulative-scheme claim, a plaintiff must allege "(1) manipulative acts; (2) damage (3) caused by reliance on an assumption of
In light of those requirements, the SDNY Plaintiffs' Section 10(b) claims fail as a matter of law for at least two reasons.
The provision of co-location services and proprietary data feeds does not qualify as manipulative under these definitions. In particular, the SDNY Plaintiffs fail to allege that the Exchanges misrepresented or failed to disclose material information regarding either the proprietary data feeds or co-location services. To the contrary, as another Court within this District recently observed, the Exchanges did not conceal the availability of proprietary data
Second, and more broadly, the SDNY Plaintiffs fail to allege primary violations by the Exchanges themselves. Instead, the most that the Complaints can be said to allege is that the Exchanges aided and abetted the HFT firms' manipulation of the market price. It is well established, however, that Section 10(b)'s "proscription does not include giving aid to a person who commits a manipulative or deceptive act." Cent. Bank of Denver, 511 U.S. at 177, 114 S.Ct. 1439. The SDNY Plaintiffs do point to an extensive list of actions by the Exchanges that they contend constitute manipulative acts on which primary liability may be premised. (SDNY Pls.' Mem. 52-54). In each instance, however, the Exchange's actions merely enabled an HFT firm to execute a transaction, and it was the transaction itself that caused the allegedly artificial effect on the market. That is, to the extent that the SDNY Plaintiffs allege an artificial effect on the market, that effect was caused by the HFT firms' trades themselves, not by the Exchanges' provision of co-location services, proprietary data feeds, and complex order types to the HFT firms. Put simply, without the trades, there would be no effect on the market at all. It follows that the SDNY Plaintiffs' manipulative-scheme claim against the Exchanges fails as a matter of law and must be dismissed. See, e.g., Stoneridge Inv. Partners, LLC v. Scientific-Atlanta, 552 U.S. 148, 161, 128 S.Ct. 761, 169 L.Ed.2d 627 (2008) (finding that Plaintiff had alleged only that the defendant aided and abetted a securities violation where it was a third party that effected the fraudulent transactions and "nothing [the defendant] did made it necessary or inevitable for [the third party] to record the transactions as it did"); Fezzani, 716 F.3d at 25 ("[K]nowing and substantial assistance in ... facilitating the [securities] fraud ... do[es] not meet the standards for private damage actions under Section 10(b).").
The SDNY Plaintiffs' claims under Section 6(b) of the Exchange Act fail as a matter of law for a different reason: In 1975, Congress comprehensively amended Section 6(b). See 15 U.S.C. § 78k-1; Pub.L. No. 94-29, § 7, 89 Stat. 111 (1975).
The Court turns then to Plaintiffs' claims against Barclays. The SDNY Plaintiffs bring claims against Barclays, as they did against the Exchanges, under Section 10(b) of the Exchange Act and SEC Rule 10b-5; Great Pacific brings claims under California State law. Although the statutory regimes are distinct, and for that reason must be considered separately, the claims are based largely on the same actions by Barclays and, ultimately, fail for much the same reason: Plaintiffs fail to identify any manipulative acts on which they reasonably relied.
The SDNY Plaintiffs contend that Barclays perpetrated a manipulative or fraudulent scheme to exploit ordinary investors trading in its dark pool. (SDNY Pls.' Mem. 68-69). The alleged scheme consisted of two broad components. First, Barclays allegedly disclosed to HFT firms important, otherwise non-public information regarding transactions in the dark pool. For example, it provided at least some HFT firms with the "logic" of the servers operating the dark pool, which enabled those firms to refine their aggressive trading strategies. (SAC ¶ 278; see also Am. Compl. ¶ 62). Second, Barclays either failed to establish or actively undermined various protections for ordinary investors using its dark pool. For example, Barclays allegedly overrode its Liquidity Profiling product — so that certain HFT firms would appear less aggressive and, therefore,
These allegations fail to state a claim for at least two independent reasons. First, as they did with respect to the Exchanges, the SNDY Plaintiffs fail to adequately plead that Barclays committed any manipulative acts. As noted, a manipulative act is one that sends "a false pricing signal to the market" and therefore does not reflect the "natural interplay of supply and demand." ATSI, 493 F.3d at 100; see Ernst & Ernst, 425 U.S. at 199, 96 S.Ct. 1375 (observing that the term "`manipulative'... connotes intentional or willful conduct designed to deceive or defraud investors by controlling or artificially affecting the price of securities"). The SDNY Plaintiffs' do not allege any actions by Barclays that meet that definition. For example, one of the SDNY Plaintiffs' principal allegations is that Barclays overrode the Liquidity Profiling assessments of certain HFT firms. (SDNY Pls.' Mem. 14; SAC ¶ 277). But the SDNY Plaintiffs do not explain how such overrides themselves could have affected the price at which securities traded in the dark pool. The same goes for the allegations regarding co-location and information regarding the logic of the servers operating the dark pools. Although these actions may have made it easier for HFT firms to trade ahead of ordinary investors, the SDNY Plaintiffs do not explain how the actions themselves could have affected, much less artificially affected, the prices at which securities traded in the dark pool. See Stoneridge, 552 U.S. at 161, 128 S.Ct. 761.
Once again, at most, the SDNY Plaintiffs' allegations amount to the contention that Barclays aided and abetted the HFT firms by creating the conditions through which the HFT firms affected the prices of securities in the dark pool. (See, e.g., SDNY Pls.' Mem. 14 ("Barclays provided HFT firms with certain benefits and information... thereby allowing the HFT firms to effectively engage in predatory trading." (emphasis added))). But, as noted in the Court's discussion of the SDNY Plaintiffs' claims against the Exchanges, Section 10(b) and Rule 10b-5 create liability only for primary violations of those provisions; there is no liability for aiding and abetting another's violation. See Fezzani, 716 F.3d at 24-25. Simply creating the background market conditions is therefore insufficient to state a claim under Section 10(b) or Rule 10b-5. See Stoneridge, 552 U.S. at 160-62, 128 S.Ct. 761; Fezzani, 716 F.3d at 23-24.
Nor can the SDNY Plaintiffs rely on Affiliated Ute Citizens of Utah v. United States, 406 U.S. 128, 92 S.Ct. 1456, 31 L.Ed.2d 741 (1972), which held that "if there is an omission of a material fact by one with a duty to disclose, the investor to whom the duty was owed need not provide specific proof of reliance," Stoneridge, 552 U.S. at 159, 128 S.Ct. 761 (citing Affiliated Ute, 406 U.S. at 153-54, 92 S.Ct. 1456). For one thing, it is not even clear that the Affiliated Ute presumption applies in a manipulation case. See Levitt v. J.P. Morgan Sec. Inc., 710 F.3d 454, 468 n. 9 (2d Cir.2013). Assuming it does, however, the presumption is not available where a plaintiff's theory is based entirely, or even primarily, on misrepresentations as opposed to omissions. See, e.g., Starr ex rel. Estate of Sampson v. Georgeson Shareholder, Inc., 412 F.3d 103, 109 n. 5 (2d Cir.2005); see also, e.g., Joseph v. Wiles, 223 F.3d 1155, 1162 (10th Cir.2000) ("Affiliated Ute's holding is limited to omissions as opposed to affirmative misrepresentations."); Burke v. Jacoby, 981 F.2d 1372, 1378-79 (2d Cir.1992) (noting the distinction between a misrepresentation theory, which requires that the plaintiff "demonstrate that he or she relied on the misrepresentation" and an omission theory, for which "[a]ll that is necessary is that the facts withheld be material in the sense that a reasonable investor might have considered them important in the making of th[e] decision" (internal quotation marks omitted)). Thus, to rely on the Affiliated Ute presumption, the SDNY Plaintiffs must, at a minimum, show that their claims are based primarily on Barclays's omissions of material information rather than misrepresentations.
They fail to do so, as their theory of liability is based primarily, if not entirely, on Barclays's alleged misrepresentations, with any omissions playing only a minor role in exacerbating the misrepresentations' effect. After all, the gravamen of the SDNY Plaintiffs' claims is that Barclays promoted its dark pool as a safe
Perhaps recognizing the weakness of their claims about the applicability of the fraud-on-the-market and Affiliated Ute presumptions, the SDNY Plaintiffs indicated at oral argument that they were really inviting the Court to apply a novel presumption of reliance based on the fairness and integrity of the market. (Tr. 57-58, 61). In support of doing so, the SDNY Plaintiffs point to a footnote in the Second Circuit's decision in Fezzani, which observes — in plain dictum — that "[t]here may ... be some merit to a modified presumption of reliance in market manipulation cases" where the plaintiff alleges that it relied on the price as "being set by an active, arms-length market." Fezzani, 716 F.3d at 21 n. 2. The Court declines the SDNY Plaintiffs' invitation. For one thing, it was not until oral argument that the SDNY Plaintiffs clarified that they were invoking this novel presumption of reliance, rather than the two presumptions discussed in their papers. See United States v. Barnes, 158 F.3d 662, 672 (2d Cir.1998) ("Normally, we will not consider arguments raised for the first time in a reply brief, let alone at or after oral argument." (internal quotation marks omitted)). In addition, an integrity-of-the-market presumption, as the SDNY Plaintiffs appear to conceive of it, would effectively excuse a plaintiff from pleading or proving reliance for any market-manipulation claim simply by asserting that the actions at issue somehow affected the fairness of the market or the extent to which the transaction price was the product of an "arms-length market." In doing so, it would all but eliminate the reliance requirement for a market manipulation claim against any entity involved in the operation of a market for securities, a result that would be inconsistent with the Second Circuit's repeated reiteration of the reliance requirement in market-manipulation cases. See, e.g., Wilson, 671 F.3d at 129; ATSI, 493 F.3d at 101; see also In re UBS Auction Rate Sec. Litig., No. 08-CV-2967 (LMM), 2010 WL 2541166, at *28 n. 19 (S.D.N.Y. June 10, 2010) (declining to recognize a "novel `integrity of the market' presumption" and noting that that plaintiffs had "not pointed to any support in existing case law or statute which suggests it is a valid theory upon which Plaintiffs can obtain a presumption of reliance"). In short, the SDNY Plaintiffs are not entitled to any presumption of reliance. Given that, and given that they do not allege actual reliance, their claims against Barclays must be dismissed for failure to state a claim.
That leaves Great Pacific's claims under California state law for (1) the common law tort of concealment, (2) violation of California's False Advertising Law, Cal. Bus. & Prof.Code § 17500 ("FAL"), and (3) violation of California's Unfair Competition Law, Cal. Bus. & Prof.Code § 17200 ("UCL"). (Pl.'s Mem. Law Opp'n Barclays' Mot. To Dismiss Am. Compl. (14-MD-2589, Docket No. 27) ("Great Pacific Mem.") 8-25). Great Pacific alleges that Barclays committed the tort of concealment and violated the FAL and UCL by failing to disclose: (1) the amount of aggressive trading in its dark pool; (2) that it was actively recruiting HFT firms to trade in its dark pool; and (3) the significant limitations of Liquidity Profiling. (Id. at 10-15). The Court will address those allegations in connection with Great Pacific's concealment claim and then turn to its claims under the FAL and UCL.
A concealment claim under California law requires that
Lovejoy v. AT & T Corp., 92 Cal.App.4th 85, 96, 111 Cal.Rptr.2d 711 (2001); accord In re Easysaver Rewards Litig., 737 F.Supp.2d 1159, 1177 (S.D.Cal.2010). Even where the parties do not otherwise have a fiduciary relationship, a commercial transaction between them can create a duty to disclose material facts related to representations made in conjunction with that transaction. See Warner Constr. Corp. v. City of L.A., 2 Cal.3d 285, 85 Cal.Rptr. 444, 466 P.2d 996, 1001 (1970); Hoffman v. 162 N. Wolfe LLC, 228 Cal.App.4th 1178, 175 Cal.Rptr.3d 820, 828 n. 11 (6th Dist.2014) (similar). Thus, "where a party [to a transaction] volunteers information,... the telling of a half-truth calculated to deceive is fraud," even if the statement is not literally false. See Barnes & Noble, Inc. v. LSI Corp., 849 F.Supp.2d 925, 936 (N.D.Cal.2012) (internal quotation marks omitted); Hoffman, 175 Cal.Rptr.3d at 831.
Significantly, the requirement that a plaintiff prove that he "would not have acted as he did if he had known of the concealed or suppressed fact," Lovejoy v. AT & T Corp., 92 Cal.App.4th at 96, 111 Cal.Rptr.2d 711, requires a plaintiff to plead and prove reliance. See, e.g., Murphy v. BDO Seidman, LLP, 113 Cal.App.4th 687, 6 Cal.Rptr.3d 770, 781 (2d Dist.2003) (dismissing common law fraud claims as to the plaintiffs who had failed to allege reliance); see also Rozay's Transfer v. Local Freight Drivers, Local 208, 850 F.2d 1321, 1328-1331 (9th Cir.1988) (discussing reasonable reliance as an element of a claim for fraudulent concealment); In re Lehman Bros. Sec. & ERISA Litig., 903 F.Supp.2d 152, 190 (S.D.N.Y.2012) ("[U]nder California law, a plaintiff must plead that he or she actually relied on the alleged misrepresentation." (internal quotation marks and alteration omitted)).
As noted, Great Pacific's concealment claim is premised the alleged failure of Barclays to disclose: (1) the amount of aggressive trading in its dark pool; (2) that it was actively recruiting HFT firms to trade in its dark pool; and (3) the significant limitations of Liquidity Profiling. (Great Pacific Mem. 10-15). The Court will address each allegation in turn.
Great Pacific points to two ways in which Barclays allegedly concealed the amount of aggressive trading in its dark pool. First, it contends that Barclays distributed misleading promotional materials, including a chart that depicted the largest traders in the dark pool and, according to Great Pacific, insinuated that aggressive trading represented only a small percentage of total activity in the dark pool; Great Pacific also asserts that a similar chart was provided to members of the putative class and that some versions of the chart omitted "Tradebot" — "a particularly `toxic' HFT" firm. (Great Pacific Mem. 10; Am. Compl. ¶¶ 44-49). Great Pacific's theory of concealment with respect to these charts, however, is not entirely clear. To the extent it argues that the omission of Tradebot constituted concealment, the claim must fail because Great Pacific fails to allege that it ever received — much less relied upon — that version of the chart. (See Great Pacific Mem. 11 ("[A]ll the references to the misleading chart from which Barclays concealed the presence of Tradebot are to the chart included in the `Liquidity Profiling-Protecting You in the Dark' pitchbook that, according to the NYAG, was disseminated by Barclays during the Class Period to other members of the Class." (emphasis added))). Great Pacific alleges that even the chart including Tradebot "le[ft] the clear message that very little trading in the pool was `aggressive.'" (Am. Compl. ¶ 40). But while Great Pacific describes the chart in some detail — e.g., explaining how it used colors and shapes to illustrate the difference between passive and aggressive trading — it does not provide any explanation of how the chart was misleading or why it did not accurately illustrate the actual nature of trading in Barclays's dark pool. (Id.; see Great Pacific Mem. 9-12 (failing to explain why the chart containing Tradebot was misleading or contain a material omission)). Absent any explanation of why the chart was misleading, it plainly cannot serve as the basis for a concealment claim.
Second, Great Pacific argues that Barclays failed to disclose the true level of aggressive trading in the dark pool, stating — in the same promotional materials
Additionally, Great Pacific contends that Barclays's representations were false by alleging that Barclays itself disclosed to an HFT firm that aggressive trading constituted 25% of trading in its dark pool. (Am. Compl. ¶ 52). That argument, however, relies on a comparison of apples to oranges. The 14% figure provided by Barclays and supposedly relied upon by Great Pacific encompassed all trading in the dark pool. (Id. ¶¶ 41, 50). The 25% figure, by contrast, corresponded only to the orders taking liquidity. (Id. ¶ 52). That is, the 25% figure described only a subset of the orders in the dark pool. Great Pacific does not point to any information suggesting that the subset is representative of all trades in the dark pool or that the subset is more aggressive than the other trades in the dark pool. It follows that the difference between these numbers does not support the conclusion that Barclays concealed material information. See Okla. Firefighters Pension & Ret. Sys. v. Student Loan Corp., 951 F.Supp.2d 479, 496-97 (S.D.N.Y.2013) (rejecting a claim under Section 10(b) in part because the plaintiffs "compare[d] apples to oranges" in comparing "two determinations requir[ing] wholly different accounting judgments and calculations"); see also Fait v. Regions Fin. Corp., 655 F.3d 105, 113 (2d Cir.2011) (holding where an alleged fraudulent or material misstatement could not be judged against an "objective standard," to state a viable claim, the "plaintiff must allege that [the] defendant's opinions were both false and not honestly believed when they were made"). Finally, and in any event, Great Pacific's claims regarding the 2013 and 2014 measures of aggressive trading fail both for the foregoing reasons and because Great Pacific does not provide any details regarding where or in what context Barclays made those statements. Vess v. Ciba-Geigy Corp. USA, 317 F.3d 1097, 1106 (9th Cir.2003) ("Averments of fraud must be accompanied by the who, what, when, where, and how of the misconduct charged." (internal quotation marks omitted)). Accordingly, Great Pacific fails to plead a claim for concealment based on Barclays's representations regarding the amount of trading in the dark pool.
Next, Great Pacific contends that Barclays's efforts to court HFT firms, especially aggressive HFT firms, constituted concealment because Barclays knew that ordinary investors were using the dark pool for the purpose of avoiding such firms. (Great Pacific Mem. 12-14). Great Pacific thus appears to contend that Barclays's suggestion that its dark pool was safe and that it was taking steps to limit aggressive trading obligated it to disclose to Great Pacific that it was also taking steps to court HFT firms and provide those firms with information that could be used to further their exploitative trading strategies. (Id. at 13). In other words, Barclays's statements regarding the safety of the dark pool were, Great Pacific alleges, the sort of "half-truth calculated to deceive" from which a duty to disclose material information can arise. Hoffman, 175 Cal.Rptr.3d at 831. Great Pacific identifies three principal actions that were allegedly inconsistent with Barclays's statements regarding the safety of its dark pool and that it was therefore obligated to disclose. (Great Pacific Mem. 13). These are (1) "disclos[ing] information to the HFTs to encourage them to increase their activity" in the dark pool, including the "logic" of the servers operating the dark pool; (2) working with the HFT firm Tradebot to change its rating so as to appear less aggressive; and (3) providing HFT firms with transaction information, including volume by participant type and toxicity level. (Id. at 12-13 (internal quotation marks omitted); see Am. Compl. ¶ 62).
Whether or not Barclays's failure to disclose this information in promoting its dark pool constituted a material omission, Great Pacific nevertheless fails to state a concealment claim on these allegations because it fails to adequately plead reasonable reliance. In discussing reliance, Great Pacific asserts that it "would have acted differently" had it known about Barclays's recruitment of HFT firms and that Barclays's omissions were material to its decision-making. (Am. Compl. ¶¶ 7, 68, 85; Great Pacific Mem. 17). But Great Pacific fails to provide any nonconclusory allegations explaining the connection between the alleged omissions and its decision to trade (or not to trade) in Barclays's dark pool. That is, Great Pacific has not provided any plausible basis for the conclusion that it would have acted differently had it known about Barclays's alleged interaction with HFT firms. See, e.g., Herskowitz v. Apple Inc., 940 F.Supp.2d 1131, 1148 (N.D.Cal.2013) (holding that simply alleging that a plaintiff reasonably relied on the defendant's statement is insufficient to adequately plead reliance under Rule 9(b)); In re Lehman Bros. Sec. & ERISA Litig., 903 F.Supp.2d 152, 190 (S.D.N.Y.2012) (applying Mirkin v. Wasserman, 5 Cal.4th 1082, 1093, 23 Cal.Rptr.2d 101, 858 P.2d 568 (1993), to conclude that the plaintiffs had not sufficiently pleaded reliance where they alleged only that "it is probable, if not certain, that it would not have purchased the subject ... [s]ecurities absent the misrepresentations and concealment of information" contained in certain documents when they never alleged that they had actually read the documents); Dotson v. Metrociti Mortgage, No. S-10-CV-3484 (KJM)(DAD), 2011 WL 3875997, at *4 (E.D.Cal. Aug. 31, 2011) (holding that a plaintiff does not adequately plead reliance by suggesting that it continued performing an action without "mak[ing] clear the connection, if any, between the fraud and the[] continued [action]").
The closest Great Pacific comes to alleging such a connection is its statement that it wanted to "avoid venues" in which HFT firms traded. (Am. Compl. 68). But the Amended Complaint does not include any non-conclusory allegations from which the
Moreover, to the extent that Great Pacific suggests that it avoided venues in which any HFT firms traded and that, based on Barclays omissions, it mistakenly believed that the Barclays's dark pool did not contain HFTs (Am. Compl. ¶¶ 60, 68), any such reliance was plainly unreasonable. After all, in the same presentation discussed above — that is, the presentation on which Great Pacific alleges it relied as the basis for claims in this lawsuit — Barclays stated that 30% of its dark pool was composed of electronic liquidity providers, "Barclays' term for high[-]frequency traders." (Am. Compl. ¶ 39; id., Ex. A, at 8; id., Ex. A, at 9). As such, no juror could conclude that it was reasonable for Great Pacific to have believed that Barclays's dark pool did not contain a significant number, much less any, HFT firms. See, e.g., Manderville v. PCG & S Grp., 146 Cal.App.4th 1486, 55 Cal.Rptr.3d 59, 69 (4th Dist.2007) ("[W]hether a party's reliance was justified may be decided as a matter of law if reasonable minds can come to only one conclusion based on the facts." (internal quotation marks omitted)). Accordingly, Great Pacific fails to plead a claim for concealment based on Barclays's recruitment of HFT firms.
Great Pacific's final theory of concealment is that Barclays represented that its Liquidity Profiling service could monitor and protect against "aggressive" HFT firms when, in reality, it "offered little or no benefit to [Great Pacific] and Barclays' other clients." (Great Pacific Mem. 14 (internal quotation marks omitted); Am. Compl. 54, 56). As noted, Liquidity Profiling involved two steps. First, Barclays categorized firms trading in the dark pool as either aggressive, neutral, or passive. (Id., Ex. A at 8-9). Second, it gave traders using the dark pool the option to block entities with certain ratings from trading against it. (Am. Compl., Ex. A at 8-9). Great Pacific identifies several alleged shortcomings with Liquidity Profiling and
Once again, Great Pacific's claim founders on the reliance requirement. Notably, Great Pacific concedes that it never used, or sought to use, the counterparty blocking service of Liquidity Profiling. (Great Pacific Mem. 15). Instead, Great Pacific claims that it relied on the effectiveness of Liquidity Profiling when deciding to trade in the dark pool because it "wanted to avoid trading in venues where proprietary or predatory traders existed." (Am. Compl. ¶ 68; Great Pacific Mem. 15 n. 13). As the Barclays presentation attached to the Amended Complaint makes clear, however, Liquidity Profiling was never intended, or advertised, as a way to remove predatory or toxic HFT firms from the dark pool. (See Am. Compl., Ex. A). To the contrary, the counterparty blocking feature (the one that Great Pacific alleges was ineffective) was premised on the fact that HFT firms were trading in the dark pool. Put simply, to the extent that Great Pacific alleges it relied on the Liquidity Profiling service, that reliance was unreasonable as a matter of law. See, e.g., Manderville v. PCG & S Grp., 146 Cal.App.4th 1486, 55 Cal.Rptr.3d 59, 69 (4th Dist.2007) ("[W]hether a party's reliance was justified may be decided as a matter of law if reasonable minds can come to only one conclusion based on the facts." (internal quotation marks omitted)); see also, e.g., Davis v. HSBC Bank Nevada, N.A., 691 F.3d 1152, 1163 (9th Cir.2012) (dismissing the plaintiffs' fraudulent concealment claim under California law after concluding that the plaintiff "cannot demonstrate justifiable reliance on the purported failure to disclose"); Hoffman, 175 Cal.Rptr.3d 820 at 833 ("After establishing actual reliance, the plaintiff must show that the reliance was reasonable by showing that (1) the matter was material in the sense that a reasonable person would find it important in determining how he or she would act; and (2) it was reasonable for the plaintiff to have relied on the misrepresentation." (internal citations omitted)).
Finally, the Court turns to Great Pacific's claims under the FAL and UCL. Claims under the FAL and UCL involve similar elements and, for that reason, courts frequently analyze them together. See, e.g., In re Sony Gaming Networks & Customer Data Sec. Breach Litig., 903 F.Supp.2d 942, 969 (S.D.Cal. 2012) (treating the reliance requirement under the UCL and FAL as identical); Kwikset Corp. v. Superior Court, 51 Cal.4th 310, 120 Cal.Rptr.3d 741, 246 P.3d 877, 883-84 (2011). The scope of the UCL is comprehensive: It "prohibits, and provides civil remedies for, unfair competition, which it defines as any unlawful, unfair or fraudulent business act or practice." Id., 120 Cal.Rptr.3d 741, 246 P.3d at 883 (internal quotation marks omitted). "Unlawful" practices under the UCL include "anything that can properly be called a business practice and that at the same time is forbidden by law be it civil, criminal, federal, state, or municipal, statutory, regulatory, or court-made." Sybersound Records, Inc. v. UAV Corp., 517 F.3d 1137, 1151-52 (9th Cir.2008) (internal quotation marks and alterations omitted). Fraudulent practices include anything that is likely to deceive members of the general public.
To possess standing under the UCL or FAL, "a plaintiff's economic injury [must] come `as a result of' the unfair competition or a violation of the false advertising law." Kwikset, 120 Cal.Rptr.3d 741, 246 P.3d 877 at 887. The California Supreme Court has determined that the phrase "`as a result of requires a showing of a causal connection or reliance on the alleged misrepresentation.'" Id. (internal quotation marks omitted). Where a plaintiff's claims sound in fraud, as Great Pacific's claims do here, the plaintiff "must demonstrate actual reliance on the allegedly deceptive or misleading statements, in accordance with well-settled principles regarding the element of reliance in ordinary fraud actions." Id., 120 Cal.Rptr.3d 741, 246 P.3d 877 at 888 (quoting In re Tobacco II Cases, 46 Cal.4th 298, 93 Cal.Rptr.3d 559, 207 P.3d 20, 26 (2009)). Further, in a putative class action, the UCL and the FAL require that the named class representative establish reliance; the other members of the class are not required to do so. See, In re Sony Gaming Networks, 903 F.Supp.2d at 969 & n. 24; Kwikset, 51 Cal.4th at 326-27 & n. 9, 120 Cal.Rptr.3d 741, 246 P.3d 877. Finally, fraud-based claims under the UCL or FAL must meet Rule 9(b)'s heightened pleading standards. See In re HSBC BANK, USA, N.A., Debit Card Overdraft Fee Litig., 1 F.Supp.3d 34, 54 (E.D.N.Y.2014); In re Ferrero Litig., 794 F.Supp.2d 1107, 1114 (S.D.Cal.2011) (citing Vess v. Ciba-Geigy Corp. USA, 317 F.3d 1097, 1103-06 (9th Cir.2003)).
Applying those standards here, Great Pacific's UCL and FAL claims fail as a matter of law. First, Great Pacific's claims premised on Barclays's alleged failure to adequately disclose the level of aggressive trading in its dark pool are deficient for the same reason its related concealment claim was: The Amended Complaint does not identify any materially false or misleading statement by Barclays. See Hughes v. Ester C Co., 930 F.Supp.2d 439, 467 (E.D.N.Y.2013) (observing that a claim under the FAL requires "statements in the advertising [that] are untrue or misleading" (internal quotation marks omitted)); VP Racing Fuels, Inc. v. Gen. Petroleum Corp., 673 F.Supp.2d 1073, 1088 (E.D.Cal.2009) (same). Second, Great Pacific's UCL and FAL claims premised on Barclays's courtship of HFT firms and its Liquidity Profiling service fail because, as with its concealment claims, Great Pacific fails to allege reasonable reliance on any of Barclays's statements or omissions. As noted, fraud-based claims under the UCL and FAL require that "the named Class members... allege actual reliance to have standing." In re Sony Gaming Networks & Customer Data Sec. Breach Litig., 903 F.Supp. at 970; Kwikset Corp. v. Superior
Perhaps recognizing its failure to adequately allege actual reliance, Great Pacific urges the Court to adopt a presumption of reliance based on the California Supreme Court's decision in In re Tobacco II Cases, which involved a UCL claim against various tobacco companies. (Great Pacific Mem. 21). With respect to the reliance requirement of the UCL, the Court adopted the holdings of two lower courts that a showing of actual reliance on a particular statement was unnecessary because the defendant tobacco companies had engaged in a "decades-long campaign... to conceal the health risks of [their] product while minimizing the growing consensus regarding the link between cigarette smoking and lung cancer and, simultaneously, engaging in saturation advertising targeting adolescents, the age group from which new smokers must come." Tobacco II Cases, 93 Cal.Rptr.3d 559, 207 P.3d at 40 (internal quotation marks omitted). The Court reasoned that, in light of that campaign, it would be impossible to demonstrate actual reliance on any particular statement, and thus held that the plaintiffs could instead presume reliance on the defendants' ubiquitous, "saturation" advertising campaign. Id. The Court, however, limited the presumption to cases "where ... a plaintiff alleges exposure to a long-term advertising campaign," id., and courts have declined to apply it to UCL and FAL claims in the absence of such a substantial campaign, see, e.g., Mazza v. Am. Honda Motor Co., 666 F.3d 581, 596 (9th Cir.2012) ("Honda's product brochures and TV commercials fall short of the "extensive and long-term [fraudulent] advertising campaign" at issue in the Tobacco II Cases" (alteration in original)); Marchante v. Sony Corp. of Am., 801 F.Supp.2d 1013, 1019 (S.D.Cal.2011) (finding the parallel with the Tobacco II Cases "unconvincing" where the plaintiff alleged only a "minute fraction of what was alleged in the tobacco cases" and therefore declining to presume reliance); Pfizer Inc. v. Superior Court, 182 Cal.App.4th 622, 105 Cal.Rptr.3d 795, 805 (2d Dist.2010) (declining to apply the Tobacco II Cases presumption to Listerine's "effective as floss campaign," which was limited in scope and lasted for only about six months).
In light of that limitation, there is no basis to apply the Tobacco II Cases presumption here. The Amended Complaint identifies only one purported advertisement to which Great Pacific was exposed during the class period — a presentation containing a discussion of Liquidity Profiling. (Am. Compl. ¶¶ 39-42).
For the reasons stated above, Defendants' motions to dismiss the Complaints in these cases are GRANTED, and the Complaints are dismissed in their entirety. That leaves only the question of whether Great Pacific and the SDNY Plaintiffs should be granted leave to amend their complaints for a second and third time, respectively. The SDNY Plaintiffs do not ask for leave to amend, and the Court will not grant them leave sua sponte, both because amendment would likely be futile and because, in granting leave to file a second amended complaint, the Court expressly warned the SDNY Plaintiffs that they would not be given another opportunity to address the issues raised in Defendants' motions to dismiss. See, e.g., Clark v. Kitt, No. 12-CV8061 (CS), 2014 WL 4054284, at *15 (S.D.N.Y. Aug. 15, 2014) (holding that the plaintiff's failure to remedy the complaint's deficiencies identified by an earlier motion to dismiss "is alone sufficient ground to deny leave to amend"); see also, e.g., Ruotolo v. City of N.Y., 514 F.3d 184, 191 (2d Cir.2008) (affirming the district court's denial of leave to amend in part because of the previous opportunities that the plaintiff had received to amend the complaint). (See 14-CV2811, Docket No. 246).
Great Pacific, however, does seek leave to amend (Great Pacific Mem. 25), and its request is on firm ground given "the liberal standard set forth in Rule 15" of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure. Loreley Fin. No. 3 Ltd., 797 F.3d at 190. As discussed, many of the deficiencies in the Amended Complaint turn on Great Pacific's failure to plead sufficient facts to establish a plausible claim rather than an inherently flawed legal theory. And while Great Pacific was also granted leave to amend its complaint after Barclays's initial motion to dismiss and warned that it would not be given another opportunity to address the deficiencies alleged by Barclays (see Barclays's Reply Mem. 10), the initial motion and the present motion are not identical and the earlier amendment was made "in the critical absence of a definitive ruling." Loreley Fin. No. 3 Ltd., 797 F.3d at 190. Put simply, the Court cannot say that Great Pacific is unable to plead facts sufficient to survive a motion to dismiss and, therefore, that amendment would necessarily be futile. See Lucente v. Int'l Bus. Machines Corp., 310 F.3d 243, 258
As discussed at the outset of this Opinion and Order, the Court's task in deciding the present motions was not to wade into the larger public debate about HFT that was sparked by Michael Lewis's book Flash Boys. Lewis and the critics of HFT may be right in arguing that it serves no productive purpose and merely allows certain traders to exploit technological inefficiencies in the markets at the expense of other traders. They may also be right that there is a need for regulatory or other action from the SEC or entities such as the Exchanges and Barclays. Those, however, are debates and tasks for others. The Court's narrow task was, instead, to decide whether the Complaints in these cases were legally sufficient to survive Defendants' motions to dismiss. Having concluded that they are not, the Complaints must be and are dismissed. The Clerk of Court is directed to terminate 14-MD-2589, Docket Nos. 7, 15, and 23, and to close all member cases except for 15-CV-168.
SO ORDERED.