JESSE M. FURMAN, United States District Judge:
This litigation, general familiarity with which is assumed, arises from alleged defects in the ignition switches and other features of certain General Motors vehicles. Some of the claims brought against General Motors LLC ("New GM") — those relevant to the present motion — are brought by Plaintiffs on behalf of putative classes of GM car owners and lessors whose vehicles were subject to recalls and who now seek to recover "economic losses," on the theory that they overpaid for their vehicles because "a car with a safety defect is worth less than a car without a safety defect." In re Gen. Motors LLC Ignition Switch Litig., No. 14-MD-2543 (JMF), 2016 WL 3920353, at *7 (S.D.N.Y. July 15, 2016). After several rulings on the viability of economic loss claims under the law of various jurisdictions, the parties and the Court selected three "bellwether" states — California, Missouri, and Texas (collectively, the "Bellwether States") — for summary judgment, class certification, and Daubert motion practice. See ECF No. 4499, at 2; ECF No. 4521. Thereafter, New GM filed a motion for summary judgment with respect to the claims of the putative classes in each Bellwether State. See ECF No. 5858.
In an Opinion and Order entered on August 6, 2019, the Court granted New GM's motion in several noteworthy respects. See ECF No. 7019; In re Gen. Motors LLC Ignition Switch Litig., 407 F.Supp.3d 212 (S.D.N.Y. 2019) ("Order"). In particular, the Court reached three "significant conclusions." Id. at 217. First, the Court held "that, in all three Bellwether States, Plaintiffs' benefit-of-the-bargain damages are properly measured as the lesser of (1) the cost of repair or (2) the difference in fair market value between the Plaintiffs' cars as warranted and those same cars as sold." Id. Second, the Court explained: "[T]hat means that evidence of New GM's post-sale repairs is relevant to the calculation of Plaintiffs' damages and, indeed, could theoretically eliminate those damages altogether." Id. Third, and most significantly, the Court concluded that, "whether or not Plaintiffs' claims for `cost-of-repair' damages could survive New GM's motion," Plaintiffs' "claims for `difference-in-value' damages" could not because Plaintiffs' sole evidence of such damages — the expert testimony of Stefan Boedeker — was insufficient as a matter of Bellwether State law to establish the existence of damages, an essential element of any such claim. Id. at 216-217, 213-240. In closing, the Court acknowledged that its ruling "change[d] the landscape in dramatic ways," and predicted that Plaintiffs might "petition for certification of an interlocutory appeal." Id. at 241.
True to the Court's prediction, Plaintiffs now move for certification of an interlocutory appeal. See ECF No. 7055. But they do so only in the alternative. The primary relief they seek is reconsideration of several portions of the Court's ruling. For the reasons that follow, the Court concludes that there is no basis to that request and, thus, denies Plaintiffs' motion for reconsideration. But, in no small part because of the significance of the Court's ruling to resolution of this complex litigation, the Court concludes that appellate review would be worthwhile, and thus grants Plaintiffs' motion for certification of an interlocutory appeal.
The Court begins with Plaintiffs' motion for reconsideration. Plaintiffs' motion
Here, Plaintiffs seek reconsideration of three aspects of the Court's summary judgment Opinion and Order. First, they challenge the Court's conclusion that, under California law, benefit-of-the-bargain damages may be mitigated, including through post-sale recalls and repairs. ECF No. 7056 ("Pls.' Mem."), at 3-8. Second, they argue that Texas law does not allow complete mitigation of benefit-of-the-bargain damages sustained by plaintiffs whose products manifested defects. Pls.' Mem. 8. Third, and most significantly, they urge the Court to reverse its holding that the evidence — in particular, Boedeker's expert analysis — is insufficient as a matter of law to establish benefit-of-the-bargain damages based on a difference in value. Pls.' Mem. 8-16. The Court will address each of these arguments in turn.
In its Opinion and Order, the Court held that in each of the Bellwether States, including California, "a plaintiff's duty to avoid or mitigate damages means that post-sale repairs are relevant to the calculation of benefit-of-the-bargain damages, even though such damages are initially calculated according to the bargain that was struck at the time of sale." Order, 407 F.Supp.3d at 222-23; see also id. at 225 ("California law also recognizes the relevance of post-sale mitigation . . . to the calculation of a monetary award under any of Plaintiffs' theories."). The California Plaintiffs argue that this holding contradicts California law and Ninth Circuit precedent. Pls.' Mem. 3-8. They further argue that, under U.S. Bank Nat'l Ass'n v. Bank of Am., N.A., 916 F.3d 143 (2d Cir. 2019) and, more foundationally, under Factors Etc., Inc. v. Pro Arts, Inc., 652 F.2d 278
The Court disagrees. As an initial matter, the California Plaintiffs may have waived their argument that U.S. Bank Nat'l Ass'n and Factors required this Court to give "conclusive deference" to the Ninth Circuit's interpretation of California law because they did not raise that argument in their opposition to New GM's motion for summary judgment. See, e.g., Phillips v. City of New York, 775 F.3d 538, 544 (2d Cir. 2015) (holding that "arguments. . . raised for the first time in [a] motion for reconsideration" are "not properly presented to the district court" and are therefore "waived"); see also ECF Nos. 6059, 6987 (failing to mention Factors or argue that conclusive deference is owed to the Ninth Circuit's interpretation of California law). To be sure, the precedential effect of authority is not generally subject to waiver. See Pls.' Mem. 2. If a district court failed to follow a Supreme Court precedent, for example, no one would say that the losing party waived the right to complain because it failed to cite a case for the basic proposition that a district court is bound by the Supreme Court. But Factors deference is not a conventional precedential rule of that sort, and, as the California Plaintiffs concede, it does not always apply. See Reply 3 (noting that Factors does not require deference to decisions that "disregarded clear signals from the state's highest court pointing toward a different rule" (quoting Factors, 652 F.2d at 283)); see also Factors, 652 F.2d at 283 ("A federal court in another circuit would be obliged to disregard a state law holding by the pertinent court of appeals if persuaded that . . . prior state court decisions had been inadvertently overlooked."). Thus, a party seeking to invoke Factors deference should — if only as a matter of prudence — bring it to the attention of the other side and the court and should not assume that a court will properly apply it sua sponte. The California Plaintiffs also contend that, even if Factors deference were subject to waiver, they did not waive the argument because they made it immediately after "the Court explicitly declined to follow Ninth Circuit precedent for the first time." Reply 1. But a party cannot excuse its failure to make an argument on the ground that the court has not yet rejected it. Were it otherwise, it would undermine the well-established proposition that a losing party may not use a motion for reconsideration to "examin[e] a decision and then plug[] the gaps of a lost motion with additional matters." Carolco Pictures, Inc. v. Sirota, 700 F.Supp. 169, 170 (S.D.N.Y. 1988) (internal quotation marks omitted).
The Court need not decide whether Plaintiffs waived their argument about the deference owed to the Ninth Circuit's case law, however, because — contrary to their contention — that court has not held that mitigation is irrelevant to a party's entitlement to benefit-of-the-bargain damages under California law. Indeed, the Ninth Circuit did not even address mitigation in the two decisions the California Plaintiffs cite. In Pulaski & Middleman, LLC v. Google, Inc., 802 F.3d 979 (9th Cir. 2015), the Ninth Circuit stated that damages calculations "need not account for benefits received after purchase." Id. at 989. The post-sale benefits at issue in Pulaski, however, were "direct economic benefits" derived from the advertisements that the plaintiffs claimed were displayed in less valuable locations than had been promised. Id. at 984; see also id. at 989. Similarly, in Nguyen v. Nissan North America, Inc., 932 F.3d 811 (9th Cir. 2019), the Ninth Circuit criticized the district court for "focus[ing] the damages inquiry on [the] potential
The California Plaintiffs also rely on Pulaski, Nguyen, and other California cases for the proposition that benefit-of-the-bargain damages are measured at the time of purchase. See Pls.' Mem. 5 (quoting Pulaski, 802 F.3d at 989, and Nguyen, 932 F.3d at 821, and citing Stout v. Turney, 22 Cal.3d 718, 150 Cal.Rptr. 637, 586 P.2d 1228, 1232 (1978)); Reply 2-3 (citing Pulaski, Nguyen, and In re Lenovo Adware Litig., No. 15-MD-2624-RMW, 2016 WL 6277245, at *21 (N.D. Cal. Oct. 27, 2016)). The Court agrees with that general proposition, but — as it explained — "it does not follow that subsequent events cannot mitigate or otherwise reduce a plaintiff's entitlement to such damages." Order, 407 F.Supp.3d at 222 n.5; accord Victorino v. FCA US LLC, No. 16-CV-1617-GPC (JLB), 2019 WL 5268670, at *7 (S.D. Cal. Oct. 17, 2019) ("According to . . . the same expert in Nguyen, the . . . defect can be remedied and class members can be made whole and receive the value they bargained for at the point of sale."). The California Plaintiffs argue that, as "a matter of substantive law" in California, post-sale repairs do not mitigate damages because of the state's "particular[ ] concern[ ] with protecting the safety of consumers." Pls.' Mem. 3-4; see also id. at 7-8. But it is not necessarily true that states pursue their interests using every possible policy tool and at all costs, and the California Plaintiffs cite no case indicating an intention to protect consumer safety by permitting double recovery. In fact, the Supreme Court of California has explicitly noted that "a party may ultimately be unable to prove a right to . . . restitution" or damages when its injury is fully mitigated. Clayworth v. Pfizer, Inc., 49 Cal.4th 758, 111 Cal.Rptr.3d 666, 233 P.3d 1066, 1087 (2010); see also In re Myford Touch Consumer Litig., No. 13-CV-3072 (EMC), 2016 WL 7734558, at *19 (N.D. Cal. Sept. 14,
In a last-ditch effort, the California Plaintiffs assert that they would not receive a windfall if the Court were to adopt their position regarding post-sale mitigation. See Pls.' Mem. 6-8. According to the California Plaintiffs, the proposed damages model precludes a windfall by "account[ing] for the recall repairs and their timing, and demonstrates that the amount of overpayment damages increases or decreases according to the length of time between a consumer's purchase and the availability of recall repair." Id. at 6. The California Plaintiffs also assert that an "alternative construction" of the damages model, posited by another expert, Dr. Joshua Gans, would be "consistent with the theory of harm that between purchase and recall purchasers of at-issue vehicles were driving around at a greater degree of risk." Id.
These arguments fail. For one thing, the California Plaintiffs did not rely on Dr. Gans's "alternative construction" of damages in their earlier motion, and any such argument is therefore waived. See ECF No. 6059, at 21 (relying on Dr. Gans only for his opinion that the damages model offered by Boedeker is "conceptually appropriate"); see also, e.g., Tachiona ex rel. Tachiona v. Mugabe, 186 F.Supp.2d 383, 385 (S.D.N.Y. 2002) ("[Local Civil Rule 6.3] does not grant license for a party to advance new facts, issues or arguments not previously presented to the Court.") (internal quotation marks omitted) (quoting Morse/Diesel, Inc. v. Fidelity & Deposit Co. of Md., 768 F.Supp. 115, 116 (S.D.N.Y. 1991)). Additionally, the theory of damages based on risk of physical harm is inconsistent with the California Plaintiffs' claims for economic loss. See Arroyo v. Chattem, Inc., 926 F.Supp.2d 1070, 1079 n.11 (N.D. Cal. 2012) ("Financial loss cases typically arise when there is no alleged injury to the Plaintiff other than the financial loss itself."); Whitson v. Bumbo, No. C 07-05597-MHP, 2009 WL 1515597, at *5-6 (N.D. Cal. Apr. 16, 2009) (holding that the purchaser of a defective product lacked standing under the benefit-of-the-bargain theory because the safety risk neither materialized nor impeded performance, and the purchaser did not have to repair, replace, or sell the defective product at a reduced price). The California Plaintiffs cite no cases holding that plaintiffs may recover damages for a risk of physical harm that did not materialize, let alone that such risk can be characterized as economic loss. To the extent that the California Plaintiffs now assert that they actually experienced diminished performance of their vehicles and that such injuries cannot be mitigated by later repairs, their arguments falter for same reasons that the arguments of the Texas Plaintiffs — to which the Court turns next — falter.
In short, the Court is unpersuaded that it committed any error when it ruled that, under California law, "a plaintiff's duty to avoid or mitigate damages means that post-sale repairs are relevant to the calculation of benefit-of-the-bargain damages." Order, 407 F.Supp.3d at 222-23. More to the point for present purposes, Plaintiffs do not come close to meeting the strict standards that would call for reconsideration of that ruling.
Plaintiffs devote a mere paragraph in their opening brief to their next argument:
Putting aside whether Plaintiffs' scant briefing is adequate to raise their argument, the argument falls short for two independent reasons. First, as New GM contends, see Opp'n 11, this theory of damages is new and, thus, was waived. The Texas Plaintiffs contend that, throughout this litigation, they have asserted claims for "the difference in value between dangerously defective cars unwittingly purchased and . . . cars without known safety defects" and that such claims encompass damages from performance problems associated with the defects. Reply 5. Were that the case, however, their claims would lump together two very different types of damages: (1) lost asset value of a vehicle associated with physical divergence from the vehicle promised, and (2) damages associated with malfunctions actually experienced. Cf. Nguyen, 932 F.3d at 819 (differentiating a legal theory "based on the performance of the allegedly defective clutch system" from one based on the "system itself, which [the plaintiff] claims is defective"). Although, as a matter of linguistics, a claim for "the difference in value" might be sufficiently broad to encompass the latter type of damages, such a claim does not provide adequate notice of the performance-based theory of harm. See Davis v. Perez, No. 16-CV-0784-NLH-JS, 2018 WL 2113267, at *9 n.7 (D.N.J. May 8, 2018) ("[I]ntroducing a new theory of injury at the summary judgment phase is highly prejudicial in that Defendant has had no notice of such a theory and therefore no ability to respond."). Additionally, the Texas Plaintiffs presented this theory of damages in their opposition to summary judgment only glancingly, noting merely that, "[w]hatever the efficacy of the recall repairs, they were too late to save Plaintiffs from the ill-effects of the defects." ECF No. 6059, at 32. Notably, in all of their briefing — that is, on summary judgment and here — Plaintiffs do not cite a single case holding that, under Texas law, damages related to manifested defects are even recoverable. See id.; Pls.' Mem. 8; Reply 4-5.
Second, and in any event, Plaintiffs' argument falls short on its own terms. For starters, Plaintiffs' new theory is entirely unsupported by expert evidence. Boedeker's testimony and model — Plaintiffs' sole evidence for their damages model — focus on Plaintiffs' willingness to pay at the point of sale and do not distinguish among Plaintiffs based on the nature or frequency of manifestation of defects. And, more fundamentally, as the Court previously held, no plaintiff can recover benefit-of-the-bargain damages under Texas law unless a defect manifests. In re Gen. Motors Ignition Switch Litig., 257 F.Supp.3d 372, 450-52 (S.D.N.Y. 2017). By definition, therefore, in every instance where Texas courts have applied the lesser-of rule, they have done so in a case involving manifestation. See, e.g., Orr Chevrolet, Inc. v. Courtney, 488 S.W.2d 883 (Tex. Civ. App. 1972). Absent manifestation, a plaintiff would have had no claim in the first instance. That point makes Plaintiffs' failure to cite a single case holding that repairs
The cases that Plaintiffs cite in their reply do not call for a different result — and not merely because they waited until their reply to cite them for the first time. See Chepilko v. Cigna Life Ins. Co. of New York, 952 F.Supp.2d 629, 633 (S.D.N.Y. 2013) (holding that an argument "made for the first time in reply papers on a motion for reconsideration" is "plainly untimely"). Citing Mays v. Pierce, 203 S.W.3d 564, 579-80 (Tex. App. 2006), Plaintiffs claim that they may be entitled to "both benefit-of-the-bargain damages and out-of-pocket expenses (including repair costs)." Reply 5. But Mays did not implicate repair costs. Instead, the expenses at issue in Mays were incidental or consequential damages and were not incurred in order to obtain that which the defendant had promised but failed to provide. See Mays, 203 S.W.3d at 570, 579. In fact, in that case, the plaintiff never completed the work that the defendant had abandoned. Id. at 570. Second, relying on Arthur Andersen & Co. v. Perry Equipment Corp., 945 S.W.2d 812, 817 (Tex. 1997), Plaintiffs claim — somewhat inconsistently — that, in cases involving deceit, Texas law allows a plaintiff to recover "the greater of out-of-pocket or benefit-of-the-bargain damages." Reply 5 (emphasis added). Plaintiffs thus suggest that the Texas Supreme Court meant that plaintiffs can recover the greater — not the lesser — of repair costs or diminution-in-value damages. But Arthur Andersen also did not involve repair costs. In that case, "out-of-pocket" damages referred to "the difference between the value the buyer has paid and the value of what he has received." Arthur Andersen, 945 S.W.2d at 817. "Benefit-of-the-bargain" damages, by contrast, "measure the difference between the value as represented and the value received." Id. The measures differ only when the buyer paid an amount other than the value as represented, which is not what Plaintiffs allege here. Thus, Plaintiffs' cases do not undermine the Court's conclusion that, as a matter of Texas law, plaintiffs are entitled to the lesser of diminution-in-value damages or the cost of repair.
In sum, Plaintiffs provide no reason to reconsider the Court's ruling with respect to mitigation of damages under Texas law either.
That leaves Plaintiffs' most significant challenge to the Court's ruling. In the Opinion and Order, the Court held that, under each Bellwether State's law, the diminution in value caused by a vehicle's alleged hidden defect is calculated as the difference between the market value of a non-defective vehicle for which the plaintiff bargained and the market value of the vehicle had the defect been disclosed. Order, 407 F.Supp.3d at 223-26 (California); id. at 226-30 (Missouri); id. at 228-31 (Texas). Market value, in turn, is the price associated with the intersection of the demand curve (which reflects consumers' willingness to pay) and the supply curve (which reflects producers' willingness to sell). Id. at 233-34; see Black's Law Dictionary (11th ed. 2019) (defining "fair market value" as "[t]he price that a seller is willing to accept and a buyer is willing to pay on the open market and in an arm's-length transaction; the point at which supply and demand intersect"). In order to prove market value, then, a party must present evidence of both willingness to pay and willingness to sell. Order, 407 F.Supp.3d at 233 ("Evidence that fails to account for both [supply and demand] is not evidence of market value.").
Applying these principles, the Court held Plaintiffs' evidence was insufficient
Plaintiffs urge the Court to reconsider this conclusion. They argue that the Court's conclusion is "contrary to fundamental principles of economics" and violates Comcast v. Behrend, 569 U.S. 27, 35, 133 S.Ct. 1426, 185 L.Ed.2d 515 (2013), which "requires the damages model to be tethered to the plaintiffs' theory of liability." Pls.' Mem. 9, 10-12. They also contend that the Court's analysis and conclusion rests on a misinterpretation of other court decisions regarding conjoint analyses. See id. at 12-15. The Court will address each of these contentions in turn.
Plaintiffs begin by arguing that, "[u]nder the Court's reasoning, damages would be based on factors that have no relationship to the actual harm that the defendant did or did not cause." Id. at 9 (internal quotation marks and alteration omitted). This, they contend, "is contrary to fundamental principles of economics," violates the Supreme Court's decision in Comcast, and "effectively eliminates damages as a matter of law in certain cases when a defendant knowingly sells an inferior or even dangerous product. . . ." Id. These arguments are unpersuasive.
Plaintiffs' Comcast argument is most easily rejected because Comcast is simply inapposite. The question in Comcast was "whether certification was appropriate under Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 23(b)(3)." 569 U.S. at 29, 133 S.Ct. 1426. Construing Rule 23, the Court held that, "at the class-certification stage (as at trial), any model supporting a plaintiff's damages case must be consistent with its liability case." Id. at 35, 133 S.Ct. 1426 (internal quotation marks and citation omitted). There is, to put it mildly, something counterintuitive about Plaintiffs' relying on that holding to argue that the Court held them to too high a burden. More fundamentally, however, the case is irrelevant because this Court's ruling was based on substantive Bellwether State law and concerned neither Rule 23 nor class certification. Finally, and in any event, the Court's Opinion and Order did not create "a mismatch" between Plaintiffs' liability theory and damages model, as Plaintiffs contend. Pls.' Mem. 10. Plaintiffs' liability theory is indeed "that they paid GM for one thing (defect-free safe vehicles) but received another (dangerously defective vehicles)." Id. But — contrary to their assertion — their damages model and evidence does not, under applicable Bellwether State law, "measure[ ] the difference between what Plaintiffs . . . thought they were buying. . . and what they received." Id.
A simple graph makes the point clear:
Were the Court to agree with Plaintiffs that economists need not consider the quantity of products that would be sold with known defects (at least where, as here, there is no direct market evidence of market price of the defective product), it would blatantly disregard the requirement that diminution-in-value damages must be measured by the difference in market price. That is because the sellers might not
Plaintiffs' other arguments regarding the implications of the Court's holding are also easily dismissed. Contrary to Plaintiffs' assertion, the Court's holding does not cause "consumers who have suffered identical harm [to be] compensated differently." Pls.' Mem. 11. Plaintiffs claim that, under the Court's logic, consumers who purchase identical steel that is produced by different manufacturers but that turns out to have the very same defect would be compensated differently merely because one manufacturer might be willing to sell at a lower price than the other. Id. But damages are determined by the price in the market writ large, not the prices that one or two idiosyncratic sellers might be willing to accept. Plaintiffs also argue that the Court's ruling "untethers the amount of damages from the severity of the wrongful conduct." Id. But that is not the case. Instead, it ties the measurement of damages to the difference in market value, as required by Bellwether State law. Order, 407 F.Supp.3d at 220 ("[E]ach Bellwether State measures benefit-of-the-bargain damages in cases like this one as the lesser of the cost to repair the defective vehicle or the difference in market value between the vehicle as bargained for and the vehicle as it was actually sold."). And the state law that compels the Court's holding compensates injured parties for the market value they lost and, under appropriate circumstances, permits punitive damages awards to deter willful conduct.
Finally, Plaintiffs argue that Boedeker's analysis "approximat[es] the but-for market price" by using a vertical supply curve, which they claim is permissible in light of the "mandate to construe damages broadly" and the proposition that a plaintiff need only provide "some reasonable basis of computation of damages." Pls.' Mem. 9 (citing Nguyen, 932 F.3d at 817-18 and Pulaski, 802 F.3d at 989). For reasons explained below, however, under Bellwether State law, a diminution in market value cannot be calculated without reference to willingness to sell. General statements to the effect that the law should be "liberally construed," Nguyen, 932 F.3d at 817-18 (internal quotation marks omitted) (quoting Cal. Civ. Code § 1760), do not allow the Court to assume a vertical supply curve and a seller willing to sell at any price. A damages model incorporating a vertical supply curve could conceivably succeed if it were supported by evidence that, in fact, sellers would accept anything consumers are willing to pay. Here, however, Plaintiffs point to no such evidence. To the contrary, Boedeker himself testified that the supply curve is not vertical. ECF No. 6075, Exhibit 34 ("Boedeker Dep."), at 63 ("In general, cars as a good do have an elastic supply curve."); see also ECF No. 7334-5. Thus, Plaintiffs' assertion that Boedeker's analysis approximates but-for market price is plainly incorrect.
That leaves Plaintiffs' contention that the Court misinterpreted several cases to support its conclusion that Boedeker's conjoint analysis is insufficient evidence of market price because it entirely neglects the supply curve. See Pls.' Mem. 12-15. Once again, Plaintiffs fail to persuade.
Plaintiffs first argue that the Court mistakenly relied on Saavedra v. Eli Lilly & Co., No. 2:12-CV-9366 (SVW) (MANx), 2014 WL 7338930 (N.D. Cal. Dec. 18,
But, of course, the fact that a conjoint analysis under such circumstances might not accurately reflect market demand says nothing about whether it accurately reflects willingness to sell and supply. In fact, Plaintiffs admit that the Saavedra court also criticized the conjoint analysis for "looking only to consumer demand while ignoring supply," thereby "convert[ing] the lost-expectation theory from an objective evaluation of relative fair market values to a seemingly subjective inquiry of what an average consumer wants." Id. at *5 (further criticizing plaintiffs' lost utility theory because "[t]he Court . . . found no case holding that a consumer may recover based on consumers' willingness to pay irrespective of what would happen in a functioning market (i.e. what could be called sellers' willingness to sell)."); see Pls.' Mem. 13. This comment is neither "unclear" nor "misplaced," see Pls.' Mem. 13; instead, it is an independent, and sufficient reason for the court's rejection of the conjoint analysis. That is, the expert's failure to consider supply was itself dispositive; that failure was made worse by the fact that, in the Saavedra court's view, "the prescription drug market is not an efficiently functioning market," Saavedra, 2014 WL 7338930, at *5, but it was a fatal flaw in its own right.
Plaintiffs seek to undermine Saavedra's persuasive force by noting that it approvingly cited Apple, Inc. v. Samsung Electronics Co., No. 11-CV-1846 (LHK), 2014 WL 976898 (N.D. Cal. Mar. 6, 2014), in which the plaintiffs asserted claims for patent infringement. Plaintiffs argue that Apple is inapposite because damages for patent infringement are measured "based on a defendant's wrongful profits . . . and are unrelated to whether the end consumer received the benefit of the bargain." Pls.' Mem. 13. But that reads too much into Apple. There, the court considered whether the plaintiffs had provided sufficient evidence of a causal nexus between Samsung's infringement of Apple's patents and alleged irreparable harm to support an injunction. See Apple, 2014 WL 976898, at *9. To demonstrate a causal nexus, a party may, inter alia, present "evidence that a patented feature significantly increases the price of a product." Id. at *12 (internal quotation marks omitted). The
Plaintiffs float one other reason the Court should not apply Apple's holding to benefit-of-the-bargain damages: because the judge who decided Apple later issued two opinions allegedly "approving the use of actual real-world supply in consumer litigation." Pls.' Mem. 13, 14-15 (citing Hadley v. Kellogg Sales Co., 324 F.Supp.3d 1084, 1104-06 (N.D. Cal. 2018) and In re Arris Cable Modem Consumer Litig., 327 F.R.D. 334, 372-73 (N.D. Cal. 2018)). Putting aside the potentially false premise that two opinions written by the same judge must be consistent with one another, Plaintiffs incorrectly characterize both Hadley and this Court's Order as holding "that it is only proper to use actual quantity supplied to calculate damages when the `inferior' product is already on the market." Pls.' Mem. 14. Neither Hadley nor this Court held that it is ever proper to assume a vertical supply curve when measuring damages. Instead, both opinions require plaintiffs to present evidence of willingness to sell to determine market price (and then multiply the quantity actually supplied, held constant, by the price premium to determine total damages for the class). As this Court explained, Hadley also held that the particular conjoint analysis at issue did "adequately account[ ] for supply-side factors," Hadley, 324 F. Supp. 3d at 1106, because the survey estimated consumers' preferences for various features by asking about a "range of prices. . . mirror[ing] those actually observed in the market" for products with or without those features, id. at 1103. See Order, 407 F.Supp.3d at 238-39. That is, the plaintiffs in Hadley had real-world evidence of the inferior product's price and, thus, willingness to sell.
Finally, the Court also disagrees with Plaintiffs' assertion that its conclusion is supported by neither Zakaria v. Gerber Products Co., No. LA-CV-15-200 (JAK), 2017 WL 9512587 (C.D. Cal. Aug. 9, 2017), nor In re NJOY, Inc., 120 F.Supp.3d 1050 (C.D. Cal. 2015). Plaintiffs claim that Zakaria "expressly distinguished cases, like this one, in which an expert uses real-world prices and real-world supply." Pls.' Mem. 14. But Zakaria distinguished cases in which an expert had used real-world prices of products known to have the inferior attribute, not of the challenged product. Zakaria, 2017 WL 9512587, at *19-20. Such questions enable "hedonic regression[s] that account[ ] for supply and market factors." Id. at *20 (quoting In re NJOY, 120 F. Supp. 3d at 1121). Zakaria distinguished the Hadley line of cases, and Plaintiffs do not argue that Boedeker's analysis is consistent with that line. See Pls.' Mem. 14-15. Moreover, in Zakaria itself, as here, the conjoint analysis "showed only how much consumers subjectively valued [the alleged mislabel], not what had occurred to the actual market price of [the challenged product] with or without the label. Thus, regardless [of] whether consumers were willing to pay a higher price for the labelled product, the expert's opinion did not contain any evidence that such a higher price was actually paid; hence, no evidence of restitution or actual damages was proffered." Zakaria v. Gerber Products Co., 755 F. App'x 623, 625 (9th Cir. 2018), aff'g 2017 WL 9512587.
In short, Plaintiffs fail to demonstrate that the Court misinterpreted the relevant case law addressing conjoint analyses — let alone that the Court did so to a degree that would support reconsideration.
For the foregoing reasons, Plaintiffs' arguments for reconsideration fall short. Accordingly, their motion for reconsideration must be and is DENIED in its entirety.
The Court turns, then, to Plaintiffs' alternative motion: for certification of an interlocutory appeal. See ECF No. 7055, at 2; Pls.' Mem. 16-18. Pursuant to 28 U.S.C. § 1292(b), district courts have "first line discretion to allow interlocutory appeals." Swint v. Chambers Cty. Comm'n, 514 U.S. 35, 47, 115 S.Ct. 1203, 131 L.Ed.2d 60 (1995); see also Koehler v. Bank of Bermuda Ltd., 101 F.3d 863, 866 (2d Cir. 1996) (recognizing "the special ability a trial court possesses to assess the efficiency of an immediate appeal"). A district court may certify an order for such an appeal if the moving party shows that the order (1) "involves a controlling question of law" about which (2) "there is substantial ground for difference of opinion," and (3) "an immediate appeal from the order may materially advance the ultimate termination of the litigation." 28 U.S.C. § 1292(b); see Atlantica Holdings, Inc. v. Sovereign Wealth Fund Samruk-Kazyna JSC, No. 12-CV-8852 (JMF), 2014 WL 1881075 (S.D.N.Y. May 9, 2014). District courts must weigh each of those factors and determine whether, taken together, certification of interlocutory appeal is appropriate. See Figueiredo Ferraz Consultoria e Engenharia de Projeto Ltda. v. Republic of Peru, No. 08-CV-492 (WHP), 2009 WL 5177977, at *2 (S.D.N.Y. Dec. 15, 2009) (holding that failure to establish one factor "is not fatal to certification, particularly when other factors strongly counsel in favor of a consolidated appeal"). Applying those standards in the unique circumstances of this case — complex and substantial multidistrict litigation — the Court concludes interlocutory appeal is appropriate.
First, the Court has no difficulty finding that its Opinion and Order decides
Whether the questions decided by the Court are questions "of law" is a closer issue. New GM argues that an appeal would not present "pure question[s] of law that the reviewing court could decide quickly and cleanly without having to study the record." Opp'n 25 (internal quotation marks omitted) (quoting In re Facebook, Inc. IPO Sec. and Deriv. Litig., 986 F.Supp.2d 524, 536 (S.D.N.Y. 2014)). There is some force to that contention, but the Court ultimately disagrees. An appeal would not, as New GM argues, require the Second Circuit to particularly "study the record." There is no dispute, for example, that Boedeker's report intends to measure diminution in market value on a per-vehicle basis by measuring consumers' willingness to pay for vehicles known to have specified defects and assuming that New GM or other sellers would accept that amount. On appeal, therefore, the question for the Second Circuit would be purely legal: Under Bellwether State law, is such an assumption permissible? This question does not require review of the record, and thus does not preclude certification of interlocutory appeal. See 16 Charles Alan Wright, Arthur R. Miller & Edward H. Cooper, Federal Practice & Procedure § 3930 (3d ed. 2008) ("If summary-judgment rulings depend more on questions of law than investigation of the record for genuine issues ... interlocutory appeal may be appropriate.").
Next, the Court concludes that the question is one about which there is a substantial difference of opinion. As the Court's summary judgment Opinion and Order makes clear, many district courts have held that conjoint analyses may validly be used to measure diminution in market value. Order, 407 F.Supp.3d at 238-40. Although the Court believes that, for the reasons discussed previously and above, such cases are ultimately distinguishable, the result reached by the Court is certainly in tension with some of them. And while
Finally, the Court concludes that interlocutory appeal would substantially advance the litigation. "Although technically the question of whether there is a controlling issue of law is distinct from the question of whether certification would materially advance the ultimate termination of the litigation, in practice the two questions are closely connected." Credit Bancorp, Ltd., 103 F. Supp. 2d at 227. The third factor is therefore satisfied for many of the same reasons as the first. In addition, immediate appeal serves the interests of judicial economy, because reversal after trial might well require a new trial, as there will be no evidence of diminution-in-value damages in the trial record. And because the Court's summary judgment ruling arises in the context of an MDL, the efficiencies to be gained by interlocutory appeal are particularly substantial. For example, if any of the cases affected are remanded, appeals may be taken in any of the circuits in which they originated. The likelihood of duplicative appeals and potentially conflicting conclusions is inconsistent not only with the purposes of Section 1292(b), but also the MDL procedure. See Hill v. Henderson, 195 F.3d 671, 678 (D.C. Cir. 1999) ("An appeal before re-transfer enhances the likelihood of achieving the coordination benefits sought by § 1407 (the `just and efficient conduct' of multidistrict actions), as the circuit of the § 1407 transferee court can give the issues a unified treatment, and its interlocutory decision is likely to be accepted as binding law of the case once the cases are transferred back to their courts of origin."); In re WorldCom, Inc. Sec. Litig., Nov. 02-CV-3288 (DLC), 2003 WL 22953644, at *8 (S.D.N.Y. Dec. 16, 2003) ("In multidistrict litigation ... the better practice may be to allow appeal of appropriate issues before the transferred cases are returned for trial."). The fact that the Court's ruling likely impacts a large number of claims further counsels in favor of appeal. See Klinghoffer, 921 F.2d at 24 ("[T]he impact that an appeal will have on other cases is a factor that we may take into account in deciding whether to accept an appeal that has been properly certified by the district court."); Long Island Lighting Co. v. Transamerica Delaval, Inc., 648 F.Supp. 988, 991 (S.D.N.Y. 1986) ("Certification may possibly be more freely granted in big cases." (citing 16 Wright, Miller, & Cooper § 3929) (internal quotation marks omitted)).
In the Court's judgment, the weight of these factors, taken together, supports certification. Admittedly, had the questions decided by the Court arisen in the context of simpler, more conventional litigation, the Court would not have found the need for immediate appeal as pressing. In weighing the statutory factors, the Court is mindful that, as a result of certain structural features of large multidistrict litigation, if appellate review of the summary judgment ruling is to be had, it would likely have to be interlocutory. As others have recognized, "the usual object of MDL management, especially with bellwether
In short, because the issue to be appealed "is a close one," Order, 407 F.Supp.3d at 234, the consequences of the ruling are "dramatic," id. at 240-41, and the likelihood of review after a final judgment slim — due to the pressures exerted by the realities of litigation of this size and complexity — the Court finds it appropriate to resolve doubt in favor of certification.
For the reasons stated above, Plaintiffs fail to persuade the Court that it erred in its summary judgment ruling, and they certainly do not satisfy the strict standards that govern motions for reconsideration. Nevertheless, although the question is a close one, the Court concludes that certification of an interlocutory appeal is appropriate. The Court does not make this decision lightly. An interlocutory appeal (if the Second Circuit accepts it) would result in potentially lengthy delay, and this litigation is already in its sixth year, with no end in sight absent a settlement. But the Court is not infallible. And, in the judicial system of this Nation, it is not intended to be final. Cf. Brown v. Allen, 344 U.S. 443, 540, 73 S.Ct. 397, 97 S.Ct. 469 (1953) (Jackson, J., concurring) (observing that the Supreme Court is "not final because [it is] infallible, but [is] infallible only because [it is] final"). Yet, absent an interlocutory appeal, the Court might well have the only — and thus final — word on these important issues.
The Clerk of Court is directed to terminate ECF No. 7055.
SO ORDERED.