Filed: Aug. 12, 1994
Latest Update: Mar. 02, 2020
Summary: Opinions of the United 1994 Decisions States Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit 8-12-1994 Allen-Myland, Inc. v. Int.nat'l Bus. Mach. Corp Precedential or Non-Precedential: Docket 93-1586, 93-5547 Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_1994 Recommended Citation "Allen-Myland, Inc. v. Int.nat'l Bus. Mach. Corp" (1994). 1994 Decisions. Paper 109. http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_1994/109 This decision is brought to you for f
Summary: Opinions of the United 1994 Decisions States Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit 8-12-1994 Allen-Myland, Inc. v. Int.nat'l Bus. Mach. Corp Precedential or Non-Precedential: Docket 93-1586, 93-5547 Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_1994 Recommended Citation "Allen-Myland, Inc. v. Int.nat'l Bus. Mach. Corp" (1994). 1994 Decisions. Paper 109. http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_1994/109 This decision is brought to you for fr..
More
Opinions of the United
1994 Decisions States Court of Appeals
for the Third Circuit
8-12-1994
Allen-Myland, Inc. v. Int.nat'l Bus. Mach. Corp
Precedential or Non-Precedential:
Docket 93-1586, 93-5547
Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_1994
Recommended Citation
"Allen-Myland, Inc. v. Int.nat'l Bus. Mach. Corp" (1994). 1994 Decisions. Paper 109.
http://digitalcommons.law.villanova.edu/thirdcircuit_1994/109
This decision is brought to you for free and open access by the Opinions of the United States Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit at Villanova
University School of Law Digital Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in 1994 Decisions by an authorized administrator of Villanova
University School of Law Digital Repository. For more information, please contact Benjamin.Carlson@law.villanova.edu.
UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
FOR THE THIRD CIRCUIT
No. 93-1586
ALLEN-MYLAND, INC.,
Appellant
V.
INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS MACHINES CORPORATION
ON APPEAL FROM THE UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
FOR THE EASTERN DISTRICT OF PENNSYLVANIA
(D.C. Civil Action No. 85-06166)
Argued January 24, 1994
Before: MANSMANN and NYGAARD, Circuit Judges and
SEITZ, Senior Circuit Judge
(Opinion Filed August 12, l994)
ROBERT G. LEVY, ESQUIRE (Argued)
WILLARD K. TOM, ESQUIRE
JOEL E. HOFFMAN, ESQUIRE
JAMES H. CLINGER, ESQUIRE
Sutherland, Asbill & Brennan
1275 Pennsylvania Avenue, N.W.
Washington, DC 20004-2404
CARL A. SOLANO, ESQUIRE
Schnader, Harrison, Segal & Lewis
1600 Market Street
Suite 3600
Philadelphia, PA 19103
Attorneys for Appellant
ROBERT N. FELTOON, ESQUIRE
Conrad, O'Brien, Gellman & Rohn
1515 Market Street
16th Floor
Philadelphia, PA 19102
EVAN R. CHESLER, ESQUIRE (Argued)
PETER T. BARBUR, ESQUIRE
Cravath, Swaine & Moore
825 Eighth Avenue
Worldwide Plaza
New York, NY 10019-7415
HOWARD WEBER, ESQUIRE
Davis, Scott, Weber & Edwards, P.C.
100 Park Avenue
New York, NY 10017
Attorneys for Appellee
ALAN J. WEINSCHEL, ESQUIRE
ROBERT P. STEFANSKI, ESQUIRE
LUCIA MANDARINO, ESQUIRE
Weil, Gotshal & Manges
767 Fifth Avenue
New York, NY 10153
Attorneys for Amici-Appellants1
OPINION OF THE COURT
NYGAARD, Circuit Judge.
Allen-Myland, Inc. ("AMI") appeals from the district court's
judgment in favor of IBM in this intricate antitrust tying case.
We conclude that the district court erred and will vacate its
judgment and remand the cause for further proceedings.2
1Amici consist of the Computer Dealers and Lessors
Association, Inc., Digital Dealers Association, and National
Association of Telecommunications Dealers.
2
Although upon review we concentrate on errors, it is well
to say at the outset that in a case that has been litigated as
vigorously as this one, either finding facts or reviewing those
findings for clear error is no easy task. The thirty-volume
record on appeal contains 17,469 pages of court filings, trial
and deposition transcripts, and exhibits. The district court, of
course, was in even a more difficult position. Over 3.5 million
pages of discovery documents were produced and 65 days of
deposition testimony were taken. The trial transcript alone
fills 1,750 pages, there were 2,750 pages of deposition testimony
admitted, and there were no fewer than 734 trial exhibits.
I. FACTS and PROCEDURE
A. Mainframes and Upgrades
The facts underlying this nine-year-old dispute are minutely
detailed and quite voluminous. The district court has set forth
these facts in great detail in its forty-four page opinion,
Allen-Myland, Inc. v. IBM Corp.,
693 F. Supp. 262 (E.D. Pa.
1988), and we will present only a brief summary here.
IBM is the world's largest manufacturer of large-scale
mainframe computers. These machines have the capacity to process
millions of records at a time and manage a tremendous volume of
information, making modern operations possible for large
corporations, public utilities and government agencies. Without
them, business would soon slow or halt. Mainframes are
physically large machines, generally occupying significant floor
space and requiring a full-time staff to keep them in operation.
Needless to say, they are quite expensive, with prices commonly
in excess of $1 million.
Mainframes are available in a wide range of computing
capacities, to fit the needs of each individual customer. One
common measure of capacity is computing speed, measured in
millions of instructions per second ("MIPS"). IBM mainframes may
also be upgraded, as its customers' computing needs change over
time, in what is known as a MIPS upgrade.
Many IBM mainframes are not purchased outright from IBM by
their end users, but are instead leased through third-party
leasing companies such as CMI and Comdisco.3 A mainframe will
typically be leased to several end users during its life cycle,
and then when obsolete will be scrapped. Often, when the lease
term expires and the mainframe returns to the lessor, the
computer will need to be reconfigured to meet the needs of the
next lessee.
Companies like AMI found a profitable market reconfiguring
mainframe computers such as the IBM 303X series.4 Lessors could
not afford to have their machines idle and generating no revenue
while waiting for a reconfiguration, yet IBM often took months to
install an upgrade. AMI, on the other hand, would turn the job
around in a matter of only a few days. Either AMI or the leasing
company would buy the required parts outright from IBM for
inventory on what were known as SWRPQ terms, meaning that IBM
installation was not included. It would then install the parts
in the user's computer, set up the appropriate software and test
the system. Old parts could often then be used on another
computer. Because the 303X series of computers was based on
"MST" circuit board technology, which required significant
technical skill and time to reconfigure, AMI was in a position to
3
IBM itself is barred from leasing computers to end users
under the terms of a 1956 consent decree entered into with the
United States in another antitrust case.
4
An "X" in an IBM model number indicates that several
numerical designators may be used in that position, e.g., 3031,
3033.
add considerable value in terms of its labor. As a result, AMI
grew into a company with $50 million in annual revenue.
In 1980, however, IBM introduced its next generation of
mainframe computers, the 308X series, which caused a major
erosion in AMI's reconfiguration business. These machines used a
new technology, the thermal conduction module, or TCM. A TCM is
essentially a water-cooled can containing a much greater density
of circuits than the system it replaced. Because more circuitry
can be placed in a TCM, there are fewer TCMs to replace; hence,
there is much less labor involved in performing an upgrade on a
TCM-based computer than on earlier models.
In marketing its 308X series, IBM used a policy known as net
pricing. Under this policy, IBM installation labor was bundled
in with the price of the parts for TCM-based MIPS upgrades; SWRPQ
pricing was either eliminated or was priced prohibitively high.
In addition, any old TCMs recovered from a mainframe during
reconfiguration became IBM's property. As a result, customers
desiring non-IBM installation of upgrades were required to pay
IBM's labor charge anyway. And because the net pricing policy
limited the supply of the TCMs on the open market, acquiring
parts from sources other than IBM became impractical.
IBM contended that net pricing's purpose was to insure that
the old TCMs recovered from reconfigured machines were returned
to IBM. TCMs are extremely durable and can easily be refurbished
to "equivalent to new" condition. IBM, faced with a
manufacturing capacity shortage, stated that it merely wanted to
refurbish TCMs that were returned for later reuse in a future
upgrade or in a brand-new machine. As for bundling the labor
charge, IBM contended its purpose was to ensure that it got its
TCMs back, which was enhanced when IBM personnel performed the
labor.
B. Procedural History
AMI, however, soon found that much of its reconfiguration
business was drying up and filed this action. AMI's four-count
complaint alleged that IBM violated sections 1 and 2 of the
Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1, 2, and also asserted state law
unfair competition and tortious interference claims. IBM
counterclaimed for copyright infringement of its software
programs and documentation manuals; IBM also asserted state law
counterclaims for breach of contract and tortious interference.
AMI's section 1 claim was tried in a bench trial, contending
that IBM had tied its upgrade installation services to the parts
needed to perform the upgrades.5 AMI alleged that this tying
arrangement constituted a per se violation of the Sherman Act;
alternatively, it asserted that the tie was still a section 1
violation under the rule of reason.
The district court found that IBM's net pricing structure
did not constitute a per se section 1 violation, for two reasons:
first, that IBM's share of the relevant market was not high
enough to impose per se liability,
id. at 270-83; and second,
5
In addition, AMI alleged that IBM's Installation and
Warranty Service Charge (IWSC) constituted an unreasonable
restraint of trade. The district court found for IBM on this
theory, and AMI has not appealed from that finding.
that net pricing did not foreclose AMI from a "viable business
opportunity,"
id. at 283-93. The court also found that net
pricing did not violate section 1 under a rule of reason analysis
because sufficient procompetitive reasons existed for it.6
Id.
at 293-98.
Later, the district court tried most of the remaining claims
and counterclaims, and concluded that AMI was liable to IBM for
copyright infringement and violations of the Lanham Act. Allen-
Myland, Inc. v. IBM Corp.,
746 F. Supp. 520 (E.D. Pa. 1990).7
The court also entered judgment for IBM on AMI's Sherman Act
section 2 claim, concluding that such a claim could not possibly
succeed unless its earlier ruling on market power were reversed.
Id. at 525 n.1, 559.
Meanwhile, IBM had filed another Lanham Act action against
AMI in the United States District Court for the Northern District
of Illinois, which was transferred to the Eastern District of
Pennsylvania. Moreover, certain issues concerning IBM's relief
against AMI on its counterclaims remained unresolved. On AMI's
motion, the district court issued an order under Fed. R. Civ. P.
54(b) declaring that its 1988 opinion resolving the antitrust
issues constituted a final judgment. Allen-Myland, Inc. v. IBM
Corp., 1993-1 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 70,244,
25 Fed. R. Serv. 3d
6
The district court's decision under the rule of reason has
not been appealed.
7
AMI later moved for reconsideration, but that motion was
denied. Allen-Myland, Inc. v. IBM Corp.,
770 F. Supp. 1004 (E.D.
Pa. 1991).
(Callaghan) 1353,
1993 WL 169849 (E.D. Pa. May 14, 1993). This
appeal followed.
II. OVERVIEW of the LAW of TYING ARRANGEMENTS
The overarching issue in this appeal is AMI's claim that the
district court erred when it found that net pricing was not a per
se violation of section 1 of the Sherman Act. In a tying
arrangement, the seller sells one item, known as the tying
product, on the condition that the buyer also purchases another
item, known as the tied product. Town Sound & Custom Tops, Inc.
v. Chrysler Motors Corp.,
959 F.2d 468, 475 (3d Cir.) (in banc),
cert. denied,
113 S. Ct. 196 (1992). Section 1 of the Sherman
Act declares only contracts in restraint of trade illegal. Thus,
the antitrust concern over tying arrangements is limited to those
situations in which the seller can exploit its power in the
market for the tying product to force buyers to purchase the tied
product when they otherwise would not, thereby restraining
competition in the tied product market. Market power is defined
as the ability "to raise prices or to require purchasers to
accept burdensome terms that could not be exacted in a completely
competitive market." United States Steel Corp. v. Fortner
Enters., Inc. ("Fortner II"),
429 U.S. 610, 620,
97 S. Ct. 861,
867-68 (1977).
On the other hand, if the seller does not have sufficient
power in the tying product market, buyers wanting to purchase the
tied product from another source will simply avoid the tie by
buying the tying product from another supplier. See Town
Sound,
959 F.2d at 476 (discussing Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v.
Hyde,
466 U.S. 2, 11-14,
104 S. Ct. 1551, 1558-59 (1984)). Such
a tie will not restrain an appreciable amount of trade, and
accordingly, will not constitute an antitrust violation.
The first inquiry in any section 1 tying case is whether the
defendant has sufficient market power over the tying product,
which requires a finding that two separate product markets exist
and a determination of precisely what the tying and tied product
markets are. See Jefferson
Parish, 466 U.S. at 21, 104 S. Ct. at
1562-63. If the defendant is found to have sufficient market
power in the tying product market, then the tie may be a "per se"
violation of the Sherman Act. This tie is condemned if the
probability that the contractual arrangement improperly restrains
trade is so high that a judicial inquiry into the actual
prevailing market conditions, including possible procompetitive
justifications for the tie, is deemed unprofitable.
Id. at 15-18
&
n.25, 104 S. Ct. at 1560-61 & n.25; Town
Sound, 959 F.2d at
477.
Assuming the court finds sufficient market power, it must
then decide whether "a substantial amount of interstate commerce"
has been affected by the tie. See, e.g., Town
Sound, 959 F.2d at
477. The Supreme Court has defined "substantial" in absolute
dollar terms as an amount which is not de minimis in terms of the
"total volume of sales tied by the sales policy under challenge .
. . ." Fortner Enters., Inc. v. United States Steel Corp.
("Fortner I"),
394 U.S. 495, 501-02,
89 S. Ct. 1252, 1257-58
(1969) ($190,000 sufficient).
Finally, to have standing to bring a private antitrust
action, the plaintiff must show "fact of damage," defined as some
harm flowing from the antitrust violation. Zenith Radio Corp. v.
Hazeltine Research, Inc.,
395 U.S. 100, 114 n.9,
89 S. Ct. 1562,
1571-72 n.9 (1969); Pitchford v. Pepi, Inc.,
531 F.2d 92, 98-99
(3d Cir. 1975), cert. denied,
426 U.S. 935,
96 S. Ct. 2649
(1976). The amount of the damage is not important for antitrust
standing; it is sufficient that some damage has occurred. There
must, however, be some causal link between the damage and the
violation of the antitrust laws. Put another way, the harm must
be one that the antitrust laws were designed to prevent.
Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc.,
429 U.S. 477, 488-89,
97 S. Ct. 690, 697 (1977).
III. SCOPE of the RELEVANT MARKET
A. Introduction
AMI asserts that the tying product is the "large-scale
mainframe computer," defined as computers that are "among the
largest in memory capacity, the fastest in computing speed, and
the most expensive of computers available." Allen-Myland, 693 F.
Supp. at 270-71. Alternatively, it sets forth two submarkets
consisting of the parts and services required for the conversion
and upgrade of either IBM mainframes or all manufacturers'
mainframes. AMI defines the tied product as the labor required
to install upgrades.
The district court found AMI's proposed market definition
and submarkets to be too narrow. When the court broadened the
market to include various substitutes that it believed shared
cross-elasticity of demand8 with large-scale mainframes, IBM's
market share dropped from as high as 79% to under 34.4%, too low
to impose per se liability. See Jefferson
Parish, 466 U.S. at
26-27, 104 S. Ct. at 1566 (30% market share insufficient); Times-
Picayune Publishing Co. v. United States,
345 U.S. 594, 611-12,
73 S. Ct. 872, 882 (1953) (33-40% market share insufficient).
The court stated:
Standing alone, AMI's market share evidence tends to
show that IBM enjoys substantial economic power.
However, AMI's definitions of large scale mainframes
and the relevant market are flawed in several respects
and tend to overstate IBM's market share and power.
Allen-Myland, 693 F. Supp. at 271. The district court defined
the relevant market to include not only large-scale mainframes,
but also added upgrades to large-scale mainframes, leased and
smaller capacity computers, peripheral products and software,
"box swaps," and upgrades using customer-provided parts to the
relevant market. To the extent that the district court's alleged
errors were in formulating or applying legal principles, our
review is, of course, plenary. We review the district court's
findings of fact, however, under the clearly erroneous standard
of review.
8
"The outer boundaries of a product market are determined
by the reasonable interchangeability of use or the
cross-elasticity of demand between the product itself and
substitutes for it." Brown Shoe Co. v. United States,
370 U.S.
294, 325,
82 S. Ct. 1502, 1523-24 (1962).
B. Leasing Companies
The district court first added leasing companies into AMI's
proposed market definition. It reasoned as follows:
Leasing companies, such as Comdisco and CMI,
purchase computer equipment from manufacturers and
lease it to users. From a consumer's standpoint, they
are an alternative source of computer equipment. They
compete with IBM. Leasing companies own approximately
40 percent of all large scale mainframe computers, as
defined by AMI. Prof. Levin testified that IBM's share
of the market would be reduced by an amount he was
unable to determine if leasing companies were taken
into account in AMI's market definition. If leasing
company transactions involving computers comparable and
in many cases identical to the large scale mainframes
marketed by IBM are included in the relevant market,
and the market is measured on a "transaction basis,"
IBM's share of the market, according to Prof. Almarin
Phillips, who testified for IBM as an expert economist,
drops to 34.4 percent. Prof. Phillips testified that
such a share would not reflect "overwhelming" activity
in the market on IBM's part.
Allen-Myland, 693 F. Supp. at 273-74 (footnote and record
citations omitted). We cannot affirm the district court's
finding that leasing companies form a part of the relevant
market.
First, the district court relied on the testimony of
Professor Levin, AMI's own expert, as an admission that IBM's
market share would have to be reduced if leasing companies were
added to the relevant market. This reliance is misplaced.
Although Professor Levin did affirmatively answer the
tautological question whether "leasing companies are competitors
of IBM when they market IBM manufactured equipment in competition
with IBM," this and our review of the trial transcript indicate
that he neither addressed the issue of market share reduction nor
made an admission about it.
More importantly, we think that the opinion reveals an
analytical flaw. Leasing companies lease both new and used
computers. They purchase new mainframes from IBM and lease them
to end users; when the lease term is up, if the mainframe is not
obsolete and can be leased again, the leasing company will place
it with another end user. In addition, leasing companies deal in
both IBM and non-IBM computers. There are important legal and
competitive distinctions between the various types of equipment
in which the leasing companies deal, so they cannot be lumped
together.
New computers are, of course, already in the relevant market
as defined by AMI. It was therefore incorrect to add them in
again when end users lease new computers rather than purchase
them outright. In this situation, leasing companies provide
nothing more than an alternate way of financing a new computer,
but do nothing to increase the supply of new machines. See
Transamerica Computer Co. v. IBM Corp. (In re IBM Peripheral EDP
Devices Antitrust Litig.),
481 F. Supp. 965, 979 (N.D. Cal.
1979), aff'd,
698 F.2d 1377 (9th Cir.), cert. denied,
464 U.S.
955,
104 S. Ct. 370 (1983). They do not increase the number of
new mainframes, as leasing companies still must purchase them
from their manufacturers. Thus, to the extent that IBM had the
power to set prices, that power would not be diminished, or at
most would only be slightly diminished,9 by its sales to leasing
companies rather than end users. Since these purchases are
already in the relevant market, it was double counting to also
include them as part of the leasing market. Cf.
id.
With respect to leases of used computers, there is a
significant difference whether those machines were made by IBM or
by some other manufacturer. Where used IBM computers are leased,
we think that United States v. Aluminum Co. of America ("Alcoa"),
148 F.2d 416 (2d Cir. 1945)10 is apposite. There, Alcoa
controlled 90 percent of the market for virgin aluminum ingot.
It sought to reduce its market share for antitrust purposes by
arguing that secondary ingot derived from scrap competed with
virgin ingot for sales. The court held that because all
secondary ingot was ultimately derived from virgin ingot, Alcoa,
by properly exercising its power over the supply of virgin, could
indirectly control the supply of secondary as well.
Id. at 425.
9
Conceivably, a few large, sophisticated buyers could place
certain limits on even a dominant seller's power to set prices.
There is no evidence that such pressure was applied here.
10
Although Alcoa was decided by the United States Court of
Appeals for the Second Circuit, the procedural circumstances
under which it reached that court give it added weight as
precedent. Under the then-existing version of 15 U.S.C. § 29,
appeals from the decrees of district courts in antitrust cases
where the United States was a complainant would lie only to the
Supreme Court. In Alcoa, however, a sufficient number of
justices were recused that a quorum could not be obtained;
accordingly, the Supreme Court, pursuant to the above statute,
remanded the case to the three most senior judges of the Second
Circuit: Learned Hand (the author of Alcoa), Augustus N. Hand,
and Swan. The Supreme Court itself has recognized the special
weight of the Alcoa opinion. See American Tobacco Co. v. United
States,
328 U.S. 781, 811-13 & n.10,
66 S. Ct. 1125, 1140 & n.10
(1946).
Alcoa's analysis is persuasive. Indeed, we think the case
is even stronger here for excluding the secondary market.
Refined aluminum can be melted down and reused repeatedly, and in
any event, products made with it may last for decades before they
are scrapped and the aluminum is recycled. It therefore may have
been quite difficult for Alcoa to estimate future supply and
demand for aluminum ingot over a long period of time with
sufficient accuracy to maximize its profits by manipulating the
supply of virgin ingot it produced. See 2 Phillip Areeda &
Donald F. Turner, Antitrust Law § 530c (1978).
Computers, however, have considerably more limited lives
than aluminum ingot. Technology and price/performance ratios
have been advancing so rapidly in the computer industry that used
machines cannot be re-leased indefinitely.11 Accordingly, a
powerful manufacturer like IBM was in a position to maximize its
profits by carefully controlling the number of mainframes that
would later appear on the used leasing market. This is
particularly true when, as here, that control was enhanced by
IBM's policy of recapturing old parts that could otherwise have
11
Moreover, IBM's net pricing and parts recapture policies
further reduced whatever control the leasing companies might have
had over the prices of used equipment. By recapturing old parts
from upgraded mainframes, IBM effectively curtailed the leasing
companies' ability to reconfigure their used machines into
different models that could have competed against IBM's offerings
over the medium term. This effect is similar to that caused by
IBM's past practices of offering tabulating and computer
equipment only for lease and not for sale. These practices also
spawned antitrust litigation, resulting in a 1935 injunction and
a 1956 consent decree. See Control Data Corp. v. IBM Corp.,
306
F. Supp. 839 (D. Minn. 1969), aff'd,
430 F.2d 1277 (8th Cir.
1970).
been used to extend the useful service lives of existing used
mainframes by allowing them to be upgraded and placed with new
customers. We therefore conclude that the district court erred
when it added leases of used IBM mainframes into the relevant
market.12
On the other hand, to the extent that leasing companies deal
in used, non-IBM mainframes that have not already been counted in
the sales market, these machines belong in the relevant market
for large-scale mainframe computers. Unlike IBM, there is no
allegation that the manufacturers of these computers possess the
market power to control prices, much less that they would do so
in concert with IBM.13 When these computers are placed in
service by leasing companies, they provide an alternative that
limits IBM's power in the market.14
12
We also disagree with the district court's view that AMI
admitted that leasing companies "compete with IBM and constrain
IBM's ability to set prices or exclude competition in the market
for new large scale main frame computers." Allen-Myland, 693 F.
Supp. at 274. The district court cited AMI's proposed finding of
fact 29 in support of its conclusion, but AMI asserted only that
IBM and lessors compete in the placement of mainframes with end
users; in other words, IBM installs computers, and so do Comdisco
and CMI. This does not constitute an admission on market cross-
elasticity or the scope of the relevant market.
13
Indeed, the so-called "plug-compatible manufacturers" have
built their businesses around providing mainframes and
peripherals compatible with, but in competition with those of
IBM.
14
This holds most true for plug-compatible mainframes.
There is actually a considerable question to what extent non-
compatible computers are a realistic short-run alternative for a
customer whose computer software and data are tailored to IBM
mainframes. We do not reach the issue, however, as Allen-Myland
is constrained by its own definition of the market as "large
scale mainframe computers," regardless of manufacturer or
Accordingly, we conclude that the district court erred when
it included all leasing company transactions in the relevant
market. On remand, the court should include only leases of used,
non-IBM mainframes and determine the extent to which those leases
reduce IBM's market share.
C. Box Swaps
The district court also added "box swaps" -- replacing an
existing computer with a more powerful, new or used computer --
into the relevant market, although it did not calculate the
degree to which these box swaps eroded IBM's market share.
The analytical problem with this finding is similar to the
error with respect to leasing companies. To the extent that a
box swap involves purchasing a new IBM or a new or used non-IBM
mainframe computer, it constitutes double counting to add box
swaps to the market because those sales are already included in
the market definition. On the other hand, if a used IBM computer
is used in the swap, then to include that machine in the market
is incorrect under Alcoa for the same reason it was error to
include them in the leasing market.
D. Used Parts Upgrades
Including "used parts upgrades" in the relevant market was
also error. A used parts upgrade is an upgrade performed with
parts obtained from another computer, either one belonging to the
compatibility. See Edward J. Sweeney & Sons, Inc. v. Texaco,
Inc.,
637 F.2d 105, 117 (3d Cir. 1980) (antitrust plaintiff held
to theory advanced in district court), cert. denied,
451 U.S.
911,
101 S. Ct. 1981 (1981).
organization needing the upgrade or one belonging to a leasing
company. See
Allen-Myland, 693 F. Supp. at 277.
The district court correctly recognized that the viability
of used parts upgrades could be limited by the scarcity of the
necessary parts. It then relied on the many memory and channel
upgrades and downgrades that had been performed with used parts
not acquired from IBM. The record indicates, however, that most
memory and channel upgrade parts are not based on TCM technology
and were thus not subject to IBM's net pricing and parts
recapture policies. The parts required for MIPS upgrades,
however, were mostly TCM-based and subject to net pricing and
recapture. Thus, that other non-net priced parts were readily
available does not support the implicit conclusion that there was
no scarcity of MIPS upgrade parts.
Even if used parts were available to perform MIPS upgrades,
the record does not suggest any manufacturer of those parts other
than IBM. Hence, the reasoning of Alcoa is as controlling here
as it was for used IBM computers. To the extent that IBM
controls the supply and price of the new mainframes from which
upgrade parts must be salvaged, it has the power to indirectly
control those upgrades as well. Accordingly, it would have been
error to include used parts upgrades in the relevant market even
if parts had been available.
E. Smaller Capacity Computers
The district court considered AMI's proposed market
definition to be too narrow because it failed to include "smaller
capacity computers" -- computers below the size and
sophistication of a large-scale mainframe that nevertheless would
be reasonable substitutes, either singly or in combination. See
Allen-Myland, 693 F. Supp. at 274-75. AMI argues that it was
error for the district court to include these smaller machines
because there was not sufficient evidence of substitutability
between these two types of computers. The district court
rejected AMI's argument, citing evidence that smaller computers
had effectively displaced mainframes in certain applications and
noting a trend toward the replacement of large, centralized
systems with "distributed" systems consisting of greater numbers
of smaller capacity computers.
Id.
AMI argues on appeal that this reasoning was flawed because
it failed to consider the rapid development of technology over
the life cycle of a typical computer. It agrees that some
installations that initially required older generation mainframes
might be satisfied with "smaller" machines when it came time to
replace their mainframes, because the smaller machines would by
then have all the power of the earlier mainframes. Nevertheless,
AMI contends, the fact that some users of older mainframe
computers might switch to smaller capacity machines proves
nothing about whether those smaller machines effectively compete
against IBM's current, more powerful mainframes, which are the
focus of this litigation. AMI's argument is sound, but
unavailing. There was testimony admitted at trial indicating that
at least one smaller capacity computer, the Hewlett-Packard HP
3000 series, competed against the IBM 308X series "in many
applications." The district court was entitled to, and did,
credit this evidence.
Allen-Myland, 693 F. Supp. at 275.
The amici argue that the district court failed to consider
the problem of "lock-in." Although mainframes and smaller
capacity computers may be substitutable when a new computer
application is being developed or when an existing application is
no longer useful and must be rewritten anyway, they argue that
there are significant switching costs that prevent this from
happening in the short run. For example, to "port" an existing
application from a mainframe to a smaller computer, the
applications software may have to be rewritten, the data files
may have to be converted to new formats, and personnel may have
to be extensively trained on the new system. The costs of doing
so and the delay involved could well cause the computer user to
remain with a mainframe-based system rather than convert to a
smaller computer; indeed, one court has noted that, for
compatibility reasons, over 80 percent of users remain loyal to
the manufacturer of their original systems. See
Transamerica,
481 F. Supp. at 980 & n.32.
Ordinarily, we would not consider this argument because it
was not raised in the district court. This case, however, is
unusual in that the district court reached its decision in 1988,
but the antitrust issues did not become final and appealable
until 1993. During that hiatus, the Supreme Court issued its
decision in Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs., Inc.,
504 U.S. ____,
112 S. Ct. 2072 (1992). Because Kodak is directly
relevant to the lock-in argument and the district court never had
the opportunity to consider the effect of that case, we would be
remiss if we did not analyze the issue now.
Eastman Kodak manufactured photocopying equipment that it
sold in a competitive market. According to the plaintiffs, who
provided service and repair to those copiers, Kodak sought to
maintain control over service by restricting the availability of
necessary repair parts. Although Kodak argued that it did not
have sufficient market power to restrain trade because the market
for new copiers was competitive, the Supreme Court held that,
under certain circumstances, the fact that the buyer of such
equipment was locked into a single supplier could give rise to a
finding of market power:
If the cost of switching is high, consumers who already
have purchased the equipment, and are thus "locked-in,"
will tolerate some level of service-price increases
before changing equipment brands. Under this scenario,
a seller profitably could maintain supracompetitive
prices in the aftermarket if the switching costs were
high relative to the increase in service prices, and
the number of locked-in customers were high relative to
the number of new purchasers.
Id. at 2087.
The situation may be analogous here. If it is prohibitively
expensive to switch to a smaller capacity computer before the
normal end of an application system's life cycle, then IBM, at
least for those locked-in customers, would not face any realistic
competition from smaller machines and would thus possess market
power as if they did not exist.
The district court cited several anecdotes in the record
suggesting that smaller machines are vigorously competing with
large-scale mainframes and are often winning out over them. Our
review of the record, however, shows that in none of the
incidents mentioned was there a mainframe user with a significant
base of applications software and data that would have to be
rewritten and converted before the application could be moved to
a smaller computer. Indeed, in the vast majority of cases, the
customer was developing a new application and had an unfettered
choice of which type of computer to purchase. In a few others,
the system was approaching the end of its useful life and was
slated for replacement. This evidence, then, does not support
the conclusion that there was not a significant lock-in problem.
Nevertheless, this remains an issue of fact for the district
court to resolve in the first instance. However, whether to
consider new issues on remand is not for us to determine, but is
properly a matter for the district court's discretion as presider
over subsequent proceedings. Therefore, we express no view on
whether the district court should permit a new argument to be
pursued at this stage of the litigation. The district court may
conclude, for example, that allowing AMI to pursue a new theory
not raised until after discovery and the completion of an entire
trial would result in undue prejudice to IBM. See Habecker v.
Clark Equipment Co.,
942 F.2d 210, 218 (3d Cir. 1991). We hold
only that the determination whether to consider the lock-in
argument, to permit further discovery on the issue, and to hear
additional evidence are all within the district court's sound
discretion.15 See
id.
F. Peripheral Devices and Software
AMI also argues that the district court erred when it added
peripheral devices and software into the relevant market. The
court found that these items, which provide data input, storage
and output capabilities and direct the computer in its processing
of information, "provided significant and reasonable alternatives
to a wide variety of upgrades and modifications of large scale
mainframes."
Allen-Myland, 693 F. Supp. at 276.
Similar or substitute products are those that "have the
ability -- actual or potential -- to take significant amounts of
business away from each other." SmithKline Corp. v. Eli Lilly &
Co.,
575 F.2d 1056, 1063 (3d Cir.), cert. denied,
439 U.S. 838,
99 S. Ct. 123 (1978). Thus, the relevant product market "is
composed of products that have reasonable interchangeability for
15
If it does so, the district court should then proceed to
determine the percentage of the mainframe market occupied by
existing mainframe users who are locked in to that type of
computer by prohibitively high switching costs; the greater that
percentage is, the more power IBM has to maintain
supracompetitive prices in the mainframe market. See Phillip E.
Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 521.1a, at 604-05
(1993 Supp.). The court can then determine if IBM's power in the
large-scale mainframe market is constrained by the existence of
smaller capacity computers, and if so, whether such computers
should be included in the relevant market. It may be that the
district court will conclude that, while smaller capacity
computers cannot be fully excluded from the market, neither can
they be fully included. The court may, after considering the
evidence and the nature of the market, exercise its discretion
and reduce IBM's market share by a number greater than zero
percent but less that the full extent of the market for smaller
capacity computers.
the purposes for which they are produced -- price, use and
qualities considered."
Id. at 1062-63 (quoting United States v.
E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co.,
351 U.S. 377, 404,
76 S. Ct. 994,
1012 (1956) (The Cellophane Case)); Tunis Bros. Co. v. Ford Motor
Co.,
952 F.2d 715, 722 (3d Cir. 1991), cert. denied,
112 S. Ct.
3034 (1992).
"Interchangeability" implies that one product is roughly
equivalent to another for the use to which it is put; while there
might be some degree of preference for the one over the other,
either would work effectively. A person needing transportation
to work could accordingly buy a Ford or a Chevrolet automobile,
or could elect to ride a horse or bicycle, assuming those options
were feasible. The key test for determining whether one product
is a substitute for another is whether there is a cross-
elasticity of demand between them: in other words, whether the
demand for the second good would respond to changes in the price
of the first. Tunis
Bros., 952 F.2d at 722.
In the six years since the district court issued its
opinion, the personal computer has consolidated its position in
modern life, and what once seemed mired in impenetrable technical
jargon is now within the vocabulary of the general public.
Moreover, technology changes rapidly and if one has an older
computer and wishes to use the latest software applications, one
often must either upgrade the central processor -- the equivalent
of a MIPS upgrade -- or buy a new computer. Increasing the size
of the disk drive, buying more memory or installing the latest
version of the operating system may help in some cases but in
many others will be ineffective. It thus may be argued that the
same situation obtains in the case of larger computers; that is,
peripherals and software are complementary goods but are not
substitutes for mainframe computers.
The issue, nevertheless, remains a factual one for the
district court to resolve. Here, if peripherals and software are
reasonable substitutes for mainframes, we should expect to see an
increased demand for them as the price of mainframes rises, but
the district court cited no evidence of this type. Instead, it
relied on the fact that IBM considers peripheral products and
software when pricing its computer systems. Allen-Myland, 693 F.
Supp. at 276. Pricing a large mainframe system on the basis of
peripherals included with it against competitive offerings by
other manufacturers, however, is simply not evidence that
peripherals and mainframes are substitutes for one another.
The district court relied even more heavily on several
anecdotes in which large mainframe users had upgraded memory,
disks, software or other peripherals rather than perform a MIPS
upgrade.
Id. at 276-77. This testimony fell into two
categories. First, some users testified that it was possible to
delay a MIPS upgrade for a while by upgrading peripherals or
software: akin perhaps to saying that installing new brakes may
delay the necessity of purchasing a new car, but it is not
sufficient evidence on which to conclude that the products are
reasonably interchangeable in use. See Kaiser Aluminum &
Chemical Corp. v. Federal Trade Comm'n,
652 F.2d 1324, 1331-32
(7th Cir. 1981) ("specialties," which delayed the necessity of
replacing refractory bricks in furnaces, did not belong in the
same relevant market).
Second, there was testimony to the effect that there are
many ways to enhance the performance of a computer system,
including MIPS upgrades and peripheral/software upgrades.
Although it is doubtless true that improvements to peripherals or
software will improve a computer's performance somewhat under
certain circumstances, we find no evidence on how much or under
what conditions improvement could be expected. There was thus no
evidence from which to conclude whether peripheral and software
upgrades were reasonably interchangeable with either a MIPS
upgrade or a different mainframe computer in enough cases that
those alternate upgrades could properly be termed substitutes.
Nor was there evidence that, because of a price change in
mainframes, there was a greater or lesser demand for
peripheral/software upgrades. In sum, the evidence was
insufficient to support the wholesale inclusion of peripherals
and software into the relevant market for large-scale mainframes.
We emphasize, however, that we are not holding that
peripheral and software must be excluded from the relevant
market, only that, upon review, the evidence cited in the
district court's opinion is insufficient to warrant including
them. On remand, the district court will of course determine
whether there is some degree of interchangeability or other
evidence of cross-elasticity of demand. If there is, then the
court is free to adjust IBM's share of the market by its best
estimate of the true competition from peripherals and software.
G. AMI's Proposed Submarkets
As a separate ground for reversal, AMI argues that the
district court erred by rejecting its two alternate submarkets:
the parts and services required for the upgrade and conversion of
all large-scale mainframes, and an even narrower submarket
confined to parts for upgrading IBM mainframes. The district
court rejected the larger submarket based on evidence that
upgrades to large-scale mainframes competed with various
alternatives, including large-scale mainframes themselves.
Allen-Myland, 693 F. Supp. at 282-83. It rejected the narrow
submarket because "[c]ourts have generally rejected market
definitions limited to a defendant's products."
Id. at 282 n.43.
In Brown Shoe Co. v. United States,
370 U.S. 294, 325, 82 S.
Ct. 1502, 1524 (1962), the Supreme Court stated that within a
broader product market "well-defined submarkets may exist which,
in themselves, constitute product markets for antitrust
purposes."16 Thus, if upgrades and mainframes are not reasonably
interchangeable with each other, a valid submarket would exist
here. The district court, however, found that replacing the
16
The use of the term "submarket" is somewhat confusing, and
tends to obscure the true inquiry: whether IBM is constrained by
the prices of large scale mainframe computers when pricing its
upgrades. If it is so constrained, then the relevant market
consists of both mainframes and upgrades. If not, then it is
simpler and more accurate to say that the relevant market itself,
not some submarket of it, contains only upgrades. See Areeda &
Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 581.1c, at 535-36 (1993 Supp.).
Nevertheless, because the term has been commonly used in the
reported cases over the years, we will also continue to use it,
being nonetheless mindful that it is inaccurate and of the true
question before us.
computer itself is an alternative to an upgrade. Moreover, it
found that IBM priced upgrades and mainframes so that buyers
would be indifferent whether to purchase an upgrade or install a
more powerful computer. These factual findings are not disputed
on appeal, and so the district court's conclusion on the larger
submarket must stand. By implication, if the broader submarket
fails, the narrower one would appear to fail as well.
Instead of arguing that the district court's factfinding was
clearly erroneous, AMI attempts to revive its narrow submarket by
relying on the testimony of its expert, Professor Levin, that
certain IBM mainframe users were locked into upgrading their
computers and lacked the alternative of replacing the whole
machine. By so arguing, it attempts to bring this issue within
the ambit of Kodak, which was decided four years after the
district court's opinion in this case.
In Kodak, as we have already discussed, the Supreme Court
held that when users are locked into a particular vendor by the
sunk cost of the product, market power may exist in the
aftermarket for parts even though the equipment market is
competitive. Here, while the district court found that large-
scale mainframes were generally reasonable substitutes for
upgrades, its opinion did not address whether there was a
subpopulation of IBM mainframe users who for economic reasons
were locked into MIPS upgrades when they needed increased
computing power. AMI's argument appears to be that if a
sufficient number of users actually were locked into using
upgrades rather than replacing their computers, then IBM may have
had the power to set prices for MIPS upgrades, wholly separate
from whether it possessed that power over the large-scale
mainframe market, including upgrades. Under this reasoning, we
should remand and allow the district court to determine the
extent, if any, to which this was the case.
Such a remand would be futile, however, since if IBM had
market power over upgrades with respect to a large number of
mainframe users, we would expect it to charge supracompetitive
prices for upgrades. Yet, the district court found that IBM
prices its upgrades such that the user pays the same amount for
an upgrade as the price differential between the prices of the
more powerful and the existing computers if purchased new.
Allen-Myland, 693 F. Supp. at 282. This belies any special power
over an upgrade submarket; IBM's power is limited to whatever
control it is able to maintain over the larger relevant market.
Hence, we will affirm the district court's finding that a valid
IBM-only parts submarket did not exist.
H. The "Significant Win/Loss Reports"
Additionally, AMI argues that the district court improperly
rejected one of its strongest pieces of evidence in support of
its proposed market definition, the "Significant Win/Loss
Reports," also known as the SWLRs. These reports were prepared
monthly for the top management of IBM and showed, for each
competitive situation IBM faced, IBM's product offering, the
offering of its competitors, and whether IBM won or lost the
sale. See
Allen-Myland, 693 F. Supp. at 272. According to the
testimony of AMI's expert who reviewed the SWLRs (Professor
Levin), in 97.6 percent of the reported cases in which the IBM
offering was a large-scale mainframe, the competitor's offering
was also a large-scale mainframe or an upgrade. AMI asserts that
these reports proved that a distinct product market for large-
scale mainframe computers exists.
The district court rejected this evidence for several
reasons. First, it noted that IBM itself viewed the SWLRs as
"poor and unrepresentative indicators of actual market activity"
and eventually stopped using them.
Id. at 273. In the
alternative, it relied on the SWLRs themselves, which contained
many examples in which non-IBM mainframes competed against IBM
computers smaller than IBM mainframes. The district court
believed that this additional competition undermined AMI's
definition of the relevant market.
Reports such as the SWLRs, which are used by IBM's
management, can be powerful evidence in an antitrust case. In
United States v. United Shoe Machinery Corp.,
110 F. Supp. 295,
304 (D. Mass. 1953), aff'd per curiam
347 U.S. 521,
74 S. Ct. 699
(1954), the court stated:
When a business allows its own important judgments
constantly to be affected by a statistical survey
unflaggingly made, diligently kept current, and
repeatedly consulted at least by subordinate advisers
to the officers, then the statistical material may be
used by a court to some degree as reliable evidence
against the business.
Nevertheless, notwithstanding the potentially probative value of
this type of evidence, there is nothing that requires courts to
credit such evidence. Here, as the district court pointed out,
the record shows that IBM itself found the SWLRs were unreliable.
As the trier of fact, the district court was entitled to credit
that testimony and reject the SWLRs.17 Based on our conclusions
about the relevant market and the various additions to it,
however, it is possible that the district court may wish to
reconsider the probative value, if any, of the SWLRs. On remand,
of course, it is free to do so.
IV. OTHER FACTORS BEARING ON MARKET POWER
Market share, of course, is only one type of evidence that
may prove the defendant has sufficient market power to impose per
se antitrust liability. "Market share is just a way of
estimating market power, which is the ultimate consideration.
When there are better ways to estimate market power, the court
should use them." Ball Memorial Hosp., Inc. v. Mutual Hosp.
Ins., Inc.,
784 F.2d 1325, 1336 (7th Cir. 1986). The district
court, in addition to its findings on market share, also held
that the lack of entry barriers and the rapid technological
change of the computer industry independently precluded any
finding of market power.
17
We do not accept the district court's alternative reason
for discrediting the SWLRs. Although it may well be true that in
some circumstances non-IBM mainframes competed with smaller IBM
computers, we must be aware of the true market inquiry in an
antitrust tying case: can the defendant exercise market power
over the tying product to restrain trade in the tied product
market? Although the above evidence could lead to the conclusion
that the relevant market here is somewhat broader than mainframes
only, a user seeking to avoid IBM's tie needs an alternative to
an upgrade or a computer of the type it currently has installed.
To the extent that the user needs more computing power, a smaller
IBM computer would not appear to be much of a substitute.
A. Ease of Entry Into the Relevant Market
Notwithstanding the extent of an antitrust defendant's
market share, the ease or difficulty with which competitors enter
the market is an important factor in determining whether the
defendant has true market power -- the power to raise prices.
In many cases a firm's share of current sales does
indicate power. . . . In other cases, however, a
firm's share of current sales does not reflect an
ability to reduce the total output in the market, and
therefore it does not convey power over price. . . .
[T]he lower the barriers to entry, and the shorter the
lags of new entry, the less power existing firms have.
When the supply is highly elastic, existing market
share does not signify power.
Id. at 1335.
The district court relied on three pieces of evidence that
purportedly showed that competitors were relatively free to enter
the relevant market. First, it noted:
A number of companies other than IBM manufacture a wide
range of computers having the processing power of IBM
large-scale mainframe computers. Several of these
(including Digital Equipment Corporation, Data General,
Hewlett Packard, Tandem, and NCR) were admittedly
excluded from the report upon which Prof. Levin relied
to determine what constitute large-scale mainframes.
Allen-Myland, 693 F. Supp. at 278.
This statement is somewhat ambiguous. First, we have
already noted that the district court may wish to reconsider the
issue of whether the relevant market includes the smaller
capacity computers these manufacturers produce in light of the
Supreme Court's opinion in Kodak. Thus, to the extent the court
finds on remand that these computers do not belong in the
relevant market, its conclusion will have to be re-evaluated.
More importantly, the district court's reasoning conflates
ease of entry into the market with what belongs in the relevant
market in the first instance. Even if all the computers made by
these manufacturers were properly included in the market, that
would say nothing about how easy or difficult it currently is to
enter the market. It is conceivable that all these firms have
been in the market for many years and that there has been very
little recent entry. To use an example from another industry,
just because there may be a sizable number of steelmakers of
various sizes and specialties, that does not necessarily make it
easy to build a steel mill and enter the business today.
Accordingly, the district court's finding of ease of market entry
is not supported by the mere presence of these manufacturers of
smaller capacity computers.
Second, the district court relied on the recent growth of
leasing companies as evidence that the market was easy to enter.
Again, we have already held that, except for certain leases of
used, non-IBM computers, leasing companies do not belong in the
relevant market. Because of this, the ease of entry into the
leasing market is legally irrelevant; if IBM has market power
over the supply of large-scale mainframes, the immediate entry
into the market of these essentially financial intermediaries can
do nothing to increase the supply of such computers.
Accordingly, leasing companies prove nothing about ease of entry
into the relevant market here.
Finally, the district court cited the relative ease of entry
into the computer reconfiguration business itself as evidence of
a lack of barriers to market entry. The question, however, in an
antitrust tying case is whether the defendant can use its power
over the tying product market to control the tied product market
as well. If IBM has market power over large-scale mainframes
(including upgrade parts), that power could not be curtailed even
to the slightest degree by the fact that it is easy to enter the
tied market of installing upgrades. Indeed, it seems likely that
in most if not all tying cases, the tied product market will be
competitive, otherwise the defendant would have no reason to
impose the tie and restrain competition in the first place.
Accordingly, because the district court's reasons for
finding ease of entry into the relevant market were erroneous,
its finding that ease of entry vitiated IBM's market power cannot
stand.
B. Technological Innovation and Declining Prices
The district court also believed that market power was
inconsistent with the fact that technology in the computer
industry was rapidly advancing.
Although the performance of computers has been rapidly
increasing as costs for performance have plummeted, it proves too
much to say that this improvement is inconsistent with market
power. Indeed, in Greyhound Computer Corp. v. IBM Corp.,
559
F.2d 488, 497 (9th Cir. 1977), cert. denied,
434 U.S. 1040, 98 S.
Ct. 782 (1978), another antitrust action brought against IBM and
relied upon by the district court, the court stated:
IBM also contends that price reduction and product
improvement are characteristics of the industry and are
inconsistent with the existence of monopoly power. But
rapid technological progress may provide a climate
favorable to increased concentration of market power
rather than the opposite. Moreover, a decline in
prices does not necessarily imply an absence of
monopoly power; a fair profit might have been made at
even lower cost to
users.
559 F.2d at 497 (footnote omitted) (citing
Alcoa, 148 F.2d at
427). Indeed, were we to accept the district court's reasoning,
a great many defendants with market power, such as Alcoa in the
1920s and perhaps even the former AT&T telephone monopoly, could
be insulated from antitrust attack. Here, technology was
improving and prices were steadily falling, but the district
court cited no evidence that these changes had any connection
with a decrease in IBM's market power. We hold that the district
court erred when it ruled that innovation and price reductions
precluded a finding of market power.18
C. Conclusion
Accordingly, we will vacate the district court's finding
that IBM lacked sufficient market power for per se antitrust
liability and remand for further proceedings, during which the
district court should re-examine the issue de novo.
V. "VIABLE BUSINESS OPPORTUNITY"
In addition to finding that IBM lacked sufficient market
power for per se liability to be imposed on it, the district
court also found that AMI had not been foreclosed from a "viable
business opportunity" by IBM's net pricing policy. Allen-Myland,
18
We do not, however, hold as a matter of law that price
reductions and technological improvements can never evidence a
lack of market power. Each case must be decided on its own
facts, and facts must be found on the evidence
presented.
693 F. Supp. at 283. The court found that the labor-saving
advantages of TCM technology changed what had once been a
lucrative reconfiguration business involving a great deal of
added value into one whose labor content had become de minimis,
averaging only 1.2 percent of the net upgrade price.
Id.
According to the district court, because AMI would be required to
inventory a supply of upgrade parts in order to compete with IBM,
its carrying costs would be so high in comparison to its
projected revenues from performing upgrades that AMI would have
actually lost over $35 million if IBM had provided upgrades on
non-net priced (SWRPQ) terms.
Id. at 288. Accordingly, because
the antitrust laws protect competition rather than competitors,
the court held that net pricing was not worthy of condemnation
under the antitrust laws.
There is no requirement that one be deprived of a "viable
business opportunity" to recover under section 1 of the Sherman
Act. We instead interpret the district court as holding that AMI
failed to prove the following two prongs of the orthodox
framework for a section 1 tying case: first, that two separate
markets existed for the tying and tied products; second, that a
substantial volume of interstate commerce was affected by the
tie. Additionally, the district court's analysis appears to bear
on the "fact of damage" issue of whether AMI has standing to
bring a private antitrust suit against IBM.
A. Separate Product Markets
In Jefferson Parish, the Supreme Court said that, in a tying
case, "the answer to the question whether one or two products are
involved turns not on the functional relation between them, but
rather on the character of the demand for the two
items." 466
U.S. at 19, 104 S. Ct. at 1562. It then went on to hold that a
tying arrangement cannot exist unless there is a sufficient
demand for the purchase of the tied product separate from the
purchase of the tying product so as to identify a market
structure in which it is efficient to offer the tied product
separately from the tying product.
Id. at 21-22, 104 S. Ct. at
1563. There, the tying product was hospital services and the
tied product was anesthesiological services; because on the facts
presented, there was evidence of separate patient demands for
specific anesthesiologists, the Court held that separate markets
existed.
Id. at 22, 24, 104 S. Ct. at 1564-65.
At least at one time, there was a demand for third-party
installations of upgrades separate from the demand for parts; the
successful operation of AMI's business before IBM imposed its net
pricing policy is conclusive evidence of that. The district
court, however, believed that TCM technology, not net pricing,
destroyed the separate market for AMI's labor, finding: (1) that
customers would not be willing to have upgrades installed by AMI
at any price higher than what IBM would charge if forced to
provide the service; and (2) that, at the IBM price, AMI would
lose massive amounts of money if it attempted to install upgrades
in the same way as before net pricing. Allen-Myland, 693 F.
Supp. at 283-91.
1. Customer Willingness to Pay Premium Prices
The district court credited the testimony of end-user
witnesses who said they had no interest in having upgrades
installed by a third party such as AMI. It then went on to
acknowledge that representatives of leasing companies did
indicate an interest in third-party installation, but only at
prices competitive with IBM's net price.
Id. at 290.
The court properly found that, with a few adjustments, IBM
would charge $165 per hour for installing upgrades.
Id. at 287.
AMI takes strong exception to the next logical step in the
court's reasoning: that AMI would not be able to charge its
customers any more than IBM for its services. We are convinced
by AMI's argument.
At trial, two leasing company witnesses testified that they
would not be interested in paying AMI significantly more than
IBM's effective hourly rate for installation of upgrades.
Comdisco's Mr. Lewis said that he would use AMI installation
service only if it were, at most, slightly more expensive than
IBM's price.
Id. at 291. On cross examination, however, he
admitted that AMI had performed an "E to B" upgrade at an
effective hourly rate of $2,400 and admitted that such an amount
(thought by counsel to be $1,500 per hour) was more than slightly
greater than IBM's price. See
id. at 291 & n.75. The district
court, irrespective of this contradiction, opined:
Mr. Lewis of Comdisco explained that he would use AMI
installation service only if it were "lesser than, the
same as, or in rare exceptions, only a slight premium
above the prevailing IBM list price." Using an E to B
upgrade as an example, Mr. Lewis testified that he
would not regard an AMI hourly rate of $1500 for
installation service as only slightly greater than an
IBM hourly rate of $180 or $200.
Id. at 291 (record citation omitted). In a footnote, the court
continued:
Using customer-owned parts, AMI charged Comdisco
between $25,000 and $30,000 for installing an E to B
upgrade, requiring approximately 20 man hours. Based
on Mr. Ross's calculations, the value of IBM
installation service for an E to B upgrade, requiring
about 13 man hours of labor, is $2,400. Based on these
facts and Mr. Lewis' assertions, it is fair to conclude
that Comdisco would not select AMI over IBM to install
a new E to B upgrade if it had the choice. In view of
this evidence, I do not accept AMI's assertion at
closing argument that leasing companies "don't care
whether the service costs $2400 or $20,000."
Id. at 291 n.75 (record citations omitted). We conclude that
this finding, at least as supported by the district court's
opinion, is clearly erroneous. The court did not adequately
address why, if Comdisco was unwilling to pay anything more than
a slight premium over IBM's rate, it paid not $165 per hour, but
a full $2,400 hourly rate. Its statement, that Comdisco would
never pay the $2,400 rate if it "had the choice," is true enough,
but explains nothing; we would all like to pay the lowest
possible price whenever we purchase goods and services. On the
other hand, AMI's explanation for its ability to charge a higher
price is supported: IBM commonly took so long to price and
perform upgrades that the leasing companies' losses from having
their machines idle exceeded the premium charged by AMI -- which
was often able to complete the job within a few days.19
19
We again stress, however, that we cannot and will not
substitute our view of the facts for that of the district court.
We hold only that the district court's finding of fact is not
In a similar vein, "Mr. Smith of CMI testified that, other
things being equal, he did not wish to pay 10, 20 or 30 times
more than necessary to obtain installation service."
Id. at 291.
For the reasons stated above, this does not show that CMI, under
certain special circumstances such as the need for fast
turnaround, would be unwilling to pay a considerable premium,
even if under normal conditions it would pay only the IBM rate.
This finding too cannot stand as presently supported.
2. Alleged Lack of Demand for Third-Party Installation
The district court additionally supported its finding of
lack of demand for AMI-installed upgrades by referring to
evidence that, in the few occasions in which IBM had made SWRPQ
pricing available for MIPS upgrades, there were few such upgrades
sold without IBM labor. The court reasoned as follows:
There is insufficient evidence of demand for
upgrade labor at prices AMI would have to charge to
support a conclusion that a competitive market for 308X
upgrade labor does or could exist. Leasing companies
have purchased virtually no 308X model, memory, or
channel upgrades without IBM labor included (in order,
for instance, to have AMI install the upgrade) when
such upgrades were available on an SWRPQ basis (which
roughly equals the price IBM would be entitled to
charge for its parts). Every J to K upgrade purchased
by CMI and Comdisco was bought with IBM installation
service included even though IBM also sold the feature
on an SWRPQ basis.
Id. at 290-91 (footnotes and record citations omitted). In a
footnote, the court responded to AMI's argument that the reason
adequately supported by the elaboration contained in its opinion.
On remand, the court may of course re-examine this issue and
again reach the same conclusion, if it is supported by sufficient
evidence and findings of fact.
there were so few SWRPQ orders was that the unbundled prices were
not well-publicized:
Witnesses from CMI and Comdisco testified that neither
company knew that IBM sold upgrades (including the J to
K) without IBM labor included. I do not credit such
testimony, as there was documentary evidence (requests
for IBM "SW" prices) to the contrary. Further, the
SWRPQ procedure has existed since 1975. SWRPQ prices
are readily available from IBM. AMI acknowledged that
SWRPQ prices are made available from IBM when
specifically requested.
Id. at 291 n.74. (record cites omitted) AMI argues that this
determination was based on insupportable impeachments of
witnesses and was clearly erroneous.
Mr. Lewis, Vice-President of Comdisco, the largest leasing
company, admitted that, as of the trial date, he knew that IBM
installation was not mandatory. He was then cross-examined on
the issue of one particular 308X MIPS upgrade, the J to K model
conversion. He then stated that he acquired nine such upgrades
in the past, all with IBM labor included. But when asked whether
he knew that IBM installation was optional at the time he
purchased the J to K upgrades, he said he did not. Quite simply,
Lewis' admission does not impeach his testimony that he was
unaware of SWRPQ pricing during the relevant time period.
The district court then used certain documentary evidence to
impeach Lewis. DX 2260 is a request from Lewis for SWRPQ pricing
on three upgrades, J16-J24, K16-K24 and G16-G24. None of these
are the J-K upgrade that Lewis testified about at trial.
Moreover, their designations are consistent with memory upgrades,
not MIPS upgrades.20 DX 2266 is more explicit, specifically
stating that memory upgrades are involved. 308X memory was
usually neither TCM-based nor subject to net pricing and is thus
not at issue. Accordingly, the conclusion to be drawn from this
evidence is that Lewis was unaware that MIPS upgrades were SWRPQ-
priced, although he had purchased some unrelated memory upgrades
without IBM installation in the past. Lewis' testimony that he
was unaware of SWRPQ pricing for 308X MIPS upgrades was not
impeached. Therefore, nothing can be concluded from Comdisco's
failure to purchase MIPS upgrades under SWRPQ terms other than it
was unaware they were available.
The district court also noted the testimony of Mr. Loria, a
CMI Vice-President. He testified that, to his knowledge, IBM
would not sell upgrades without a labor charge. Much of this
testimony centered on the year 1976, years before IBM introduced
the 308X series of computers. He also stated that he thought
that SWRPQ terms meant simply that IBM did not retain the old
parts. Except for the J-K upgrade, the only SWRPQ upgrades he
testified about were not MIPS upgrades.
The district court believed that this testimony was
impeached by three exhibits, DX 2261, DX 2262 and DX 2263. DX
2261, however, is just a 1986 request for SWRPQ pricing on a 96
20
308X model numbers appear to be classified as follows:
308X-YMM; where X is the CPU family, e.g., 3081, 3083, 3084; Y is
the CPU power indicator within the family, e.g., 3081-J, 3081-K;
and MM is the main memory in megabytes, e.g., 3081-J16, 3081-J24.
This is consistent with the numbering scheme for memory upgrades
in DX 2266.
to 128 megabyte memory upgrade; Loria never testified that non-
net priced memory upgrades did not exist. DX 2262 and DX 2263
are IBM's responses to CMI requests for SWRPQ-priced memory
upgrades. None of these documents tend to show that Loria knew
that a few MIPS upgrades were available without IBM installation;
accordingly, his testimony to the contrary was not impeached by
this evidence.
Another Vice-President of CMI, a Mr. Smith, testified
similarly to Loria, stating that he was not aware that the J to K
MIPS upgrade was available without IBM installation. The
district court found that DX 2265 impeached Smith's testimony.
That document is a computer printout of requests for price
quotations ("RPQs") with the name "Gary Smith" handwritten at the
top. Some of these RPQs were for SWRPQ terms, but none were for
MIPS upgrades. Once again, this evidence does not impeach
Smith's testimony.
In short, that to which the district court refers does not
bear out its conclusion that these witnesses were untruthful when
they claimed not to know of a few MIPS upgrades without IBM
installation.21 Thus, the fact that a few MIPS upgrades were
21
In addition, the district court relied on the fact that
the SWRPQ procedure has existed since 1975, that "SWRPQ prices
are readily available from IBM," and that AMI acknowledged this
fact. This all appears to be true, in general, but there is no
indication in the portions of the record cited by the court below
that these facts impeached the testimony of the Comdisco and CMI
witnesses that they were unaware of SWRPQ-priced MIPS upgrades
for 308X series computers. That these prices were available for
memory upgrades and for earlier series of computers could not
have reasonably put these witnesses on notice that a very small
number of SWRPQ-priced MIPS upgrades were made available for the
308X series, given IBM's well-publicized policy of net pricing.
sold under SWRPQ terms does not prove that there was no separate
demand for installation services, particularly considering that
IBM had every economic incentive to protect its revenues and
avoid widely publicizing the existence of such upgrades.
3. AMI's "Massive Losses" From Inventory Costs
In addition to finding that AMI would attract no customers
at the price the court believed it would have to charge for its
service, the district court also found that AMI would suffer
massive losses at the IBM hourly rate. It based this conclusion
on its belief that AMI would have to maintain an inventory of
expensive upgrade parts to provide adequate turnaround time.
Because IBM's revenues would average only 1.2 percent of the net
price for the upgrade and its carrying costs for the parts
inventory would average 3 percent, the district court concluded
that AMI stood to lose over $35 million by competing with IBM.
Id. at 288. Although the court acknowledged that AMI's principal
argument was that leasing companies inventoried their own parts
and thus saved AMI the costs of doing so, it nevertheless
included these carrying costs when calculating AMI's ability to
make a profit, based on a purported admission by AMI.
It is, of course, true that AMI would have to carry an
inventory of parts to give its customers fast turnaround on
upgrade installations. This is exactly what AMI did for the
earlier 303X series of computers. The exception would be if the
customer itself maintained an inventory of parts. Thus, to the
extent AMI intended to compete for the business of end-users, who
typically do not inventory parts, AMI would have to maintain an
inventory, which would be presumably unprofitable given the
revenue generated by the installation. Leasing companies, on the
other hand, constituted over 90 percent of AMI's business and
were known to inventory their own parts. So, while the
relatively minuscule end-user business may have been foreclosed
from AMI by the low margins generated by TCM-based upgrades, the
business from leasing companies was not.
It would be both a non-sequitur and clearly erroneous on its
face to find that AMI's argument that leasing companies would
inventory their own parts and relieve AMI of that cost is invalid
solely because AMI admitted it will incur such costs on its own
inventory. The district court, however, relied on its belief
that Mr. Allen admitted that AMI would incur inventory costs if
it were permitted to compete in the market of 308X net priced
upgrades.
Id. at 288-89. The record contains the following
exchange:
Q. And according to Mr. Hamilton's report on damages,
he indicates that you have told him that AMI must
maintain a certain worth of inventory of upgrades and
parts, and that a fair estimate of AMI's carrying costs
for that inventory, just for the carrying costs of the
interest involved is approximately three percent of
IBM's price, whatever you happen to pay for those
parts.
Did you tell Professor Hamilton that, sir?
A. I identified for Professor Hamilton, when he was
doing a damage study, he asked me, if you were
permitted to compete in this market of net priced MESs,
what would be your costs?
I identified it would be AMI's intent, similar to
the volume procurement agreement, to order many parts
from IBM.
There was a question whether these parts would
come from the parts center on a very rapid response or
whether AMI would have to inventory, virtually millions
of dollars of inventory.
From going on prior experience with the VPA, where
we ordered large quantities for inventory and were not
using the parts center, he said, wouldn't you have some
type of carrying charges?
Now, that number that he picked of three percent
was if the prime rate were 12 percent. . . .
I don't know further the -- all the economic data
in regard to what -- Mr. Hamilton went further from
that, but the question was asked.
On the next page of the transcript, Allen then stated that
as long as upgrade parts could arrive quickly from the IBM Parts
Center, there would be no need for AMI to maintain an inventory.
This "admission," (Allen stated only that the question was
asked), does not admit that AMI would be required to carry an
inventory for all of its customers. It was therefore
insufficient grounds upon which to conclude that inventory costs
must be included in every situation in which AMI does business.22
22
Earlier in its opinion, the district court found that
Allen had admitted that AMI could not make a profit on a labor
value of 1.2 percent of the net upgrade price.
Allen-Myland, 693
F. Supp. at 284. The trial testimony shows that counsel for IBM
asked Allen whether he would take on an upgrade for $25,500 labor
charge when the net price was $2,090,000, a 1.2% margin. Allen
replied that he would, and that he thought it was a viable
business opportunity. Counsel then tried to impeach him with a
letter he wrote to IBM in the context of settlement negotiations.
On the witness stand, Allen admitted the existence of this letter
but claimed that counsel was taking it out of context. We do not
think this letter can be fairly read to concede that AMI could
never make a profit on a 1.2 percent margin. Like the statement
4. Low Margins and Separate Markets
The district court also found that the value of the labor
content of 308X MIPS upgrades was de minimis for antitrust
purposes.
Id. at 283. Later, it referred to another purported
admission by AMI's counsel, to the effect that, if the labor
content of upgrades was de minimis, then parts and labor would
have to be considered a single market.
Id. at 289 n.71.
To the extent it might be argued that AMI admitted that a
1.2 percent margin caused parts and installation to fold into one
market, as a matter of law we cannot agree. The record indicates
that the total value of all 308X MIPS upgrades performed between
1981 and 1985 was over $2 billion. 1.2 percent of a $2 billion
market amounts to over $20 million. See Allen-Myland, 693 F.
Supp. at 292. This amount is not de minimis within the meaning
of the antitrust laws. See Fortner
I, 394 U.S. at 501-02, 89 S.
Ct. at 1257-58 ($190,000 not considered de minimis by the Supreme
Court).
5. Conclusion
The district court's finding that no separate market existed
for installations of upgrades cannot stand. We will accordingly
vacate it and remand for further proceedings. On remand, the
district should re-examine the issue de novo.
B. Substantial Volume of Commerce
discussed in the above text, it admits no more than that, to the
extent AMI must buy and inventory the parts, it cannot earn a
profit on that margin.
As part of its "viable business opportunity" inquiry, the
district court also found that AMI had not proved that IBM's
tying arrangement foreclosed a substantial volume of commerce.
Allen-Myland, 693 F. Supp. at 292-93. Although the court
acknowledged that the $20 million market for upgrade
installations was quantitatively more than sufficient, it found
that AMI had not shown "that it engaged in an activity foreclosed
by IBM's net pricing."
Id. The district court believed that it
was the changes brought about by the 308X's TCM technology, not
net pricing, that foreclosed AMI from the upgrade business.
Thus, according to the court, competition with IBM in the
installation of upgrades had become unprofitable because of
advancing technology, quite apart from any anticompetitive
effects of the tie.
First of all, to the extent the district court based this
conclusion on its findings that AMI lacked a viable business
opportunity, it necessarily erred. We have already pointed out
the factual and analytical errors behind those conclusions.
Although we do not decide those factual issues ourselves, it
appears likely from this record on appeal that AMI could have
successfully performed upgrades and made a profit in the absence
of net pricing; at least, the district court's findings that no
one would pay AMI any more than IBM and that AMI would be
burdened with across-the-board inventory costs were not supported
by the evidence it cited.
Second, and more importantly, there is no requirement that
an antitrust plaintiff show profitability in addition to showing
some foreclosure of commerce. If the competition foreclosed by a
tying arrangement had to be profitable, then many anticompetitive
tying arrangements would be immunized from antitrust attack. For
example, a new competitor attempting to break into a dominated
market might well lose money for a time, either because of
aggressive introductory pricing or because its sales had not yet
grown to the point where economies of scale made its production
operations sufficiently inexpensive to turn a profit. Yet, the
defendant could exploit its market power with impunity on the
ground that the plaintiff could not profitably compete against
it, and continue using that power to keep all new competitors out
of the tied market. Such a result would be contrary to the
purpose of the antitrust laws. Accordingly, we hold that the
district court erred when it found that a substantial amount of
commerce was not foreclosed.
C. Fact of Damage
An antitrust plaintiff must also prove what is known as
"fact of damage," defined as harm of a type which the antitrust
laws were designed to prevent.
See supra typescript at 10. The
district court declined to rule on this issue, but noted that its
earlier findings that AMI was not deprived of a viable business
opportunity seemed to preclude any finding that AMI suffered the
requisite damage.
Allen-Myland, 693 F. Supp. at 298. We, of
course, make no finding, but observe that the district court's
errors on what it termed the business opportunity issue call its
tentative conclusion on fact of damage into question as well.
The matter remains, however, an issue for that court to resolve
in the first instance.
VI. CONCLUSION
We will accordingly vacate the district court's judgment in
favor of IBM and remand for further proceedings consistent with
this opinion.